Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal Keynesian multiplier

Similar documents
IS-LM and the multiplier: A dynamic general equilibrium model

Inequalities in Life Expectancy and the Global Welfare Convergence

Strategic complementarity of information acquisition in a financial market with discrete demand shocks

Equivalence in the internal and external public debt burden

Money in the Production Function : A New Keynesian DSGE Perspective

The National Minimum Wage in France

Photovoltaic deployment: from subsidies to a market-driven growth: A panel econometrics approach

A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard

Equilibrium payoffs in finite games

Parameter sensitivity of CIR process

Optimal Tax Base with Administrative fixed Costs

Networks Performance and Contractual Design: Empirical Evidence from Franchising

The Quantity Theory of Money Revisited: The Improved Short-Term Predictive Power of of Household Money Holdings with Regard to prices

Rôle de la protéine Gas6 et des cellules précurseurs dans la stéatohépatite et la fibrose hépatique

Motivations and Performance of Public to Private operations : an international study

About the reinterpretation of the Ghosh model as a price model

The German unemployment since the Hartz reforms: Permanent or transitory fall?

Modèles DSGE Nouveaux Keynésiens, Monnaie et Aversion au Risque.

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

The Hierarchical Agglomerative Clustering with Gower index: a methodology for automatic design of OLAP cube in ecological data processing context

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

European Debt Crisis: How a Public debt Restructuring Can Solve a Private Debt issue

Financial fragility in emerging market countries: Firm balance sheets and the productive structure

Dynamics of the exchange rate in Tunisia

Theoretical considerations on the retirement consumption puzzle and the optimal age of retirement

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Bubbles and self-fulfilling crises

Carbon Prices during the EU ETS Phase II: Dynamics and Volume Analysis

Rôle de la régulation génique dans l adaptation : approche par analyse comparative du transcriptome de drosophile

Drug launch timing and international reference pricing

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

BDHI: a French national database on historical floods

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

The Riskiness of Risk Models

Macroeconomics and finance

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

The impact of commitment on nonrenewable resources management with asymmetric information on costs

French German flood risk geohistory in the Rhine Graben

Endogenous interest rate with accommodative money supply and liquidity preference

The Sustainability and Outreach of Microfinance Institutions

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

Insider Trading with Different Market Structures

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Macroeconomic Theory I Professor George Alogoskoufis Winter Semester Course Structure

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Wage bargaining with non-stationary preferences under strike decision

Monetary/Fiscal Interactions: Cash in Advance

The distortionary effect of monetary policy: credit expansion vs. lump-sum transfers in the lab

Administering Systemic Risk vs. Administering Justice: What Can We Do Now that We Have Agreed to Pay Differences?

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

SMS Financing by banks in East Africa: Taking stock of regional developments

Bargaining Foundation for Ratio Equilibrium in Public Good Economies

Control-theoretic framework for a quasi-newton local volatility surface inversion

Yield to maturity modelling and a Monte Carlo Technique for pricing Derivatives on Constant Maturity Treasury (CMT) and Derivatives on forward Bonds

Macroeconomics: Fluctuations and Growth

INTERTEMPORAL SUBSTITUTION IN CONSUMPTION, LABOR SUPPLY ELASTICITY AND SUNSPOT FLUCTUATIONS IN CONTINUOUS-TIME MODELS

Is an Increase in the Minimum Retirement Age Always Desirable? The Case of Notional Defined Contribution Systems

Inefficient Lock-in with Sophisticated and Myopic Players

Patinkin on IS-LM: an Alternative to Modigliani

Who pays for the consumption of young and old?

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Money in an RBC framework

Do Professional Economists Forecasts Reflect Okun s Law? Some Evidence for the G7 Countries

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

A Note on fair Value and Illiquid Markets

Who compares to whom? The anatomy of income comparisons in Europe

Cash-in-Advance Model

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Commentary. Olivier Blanchard. 1. Should We Expect Automatic Stabilizers to Work, That Is, to Stabilize?

FALLACY OF THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT: CORRECTING THE INCOME ANALYSIS

On some key research issues in Enterprise Risk Management related to economic capital and diversification effect at group level

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

A Fast Algorithm for Computing Binomial Coefficients Modulo Powers of Two

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Macroeconomic effects of consumer debt: three theoretical essays

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Decomposing wage inequality: Public and private sectors in Vietnam

A revisit of the Borch rule for the Principal-Agent Risk-Sharing problem

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. International Trade, Crowding Out, and Market Structure: Cournot Approach. James P.

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt

Why ruin theory should be of interest for insurance practitioners and risk managers nowadays

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy

Micro foundations, part 1. Modern theories of consumption

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

The impact of the catering theory and financial firms characteristics on dividend decisions: the case of the French market

Trying to Measure Sunk Capital

Macroeconomic equilibrium in a monetary economy 1 2

The political economy of job protection and income redistribution

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

Solving the Yitzhaki Paradox: Income Tax Evasion and Reference Dependence under Prospect Theory

Transcription:

Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal Keynesian multiplier Jean-Pascal Bénassy To cite this version: Jean-Pascal Bénassy. Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal Keynesian multiplier. PSE Working Papers n 2006-15. 2006. <halshs-00590509> HAL Id: halshs-00590509 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00590509 Submitted on 3 May 2011 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access archive for the deposit and dissemination of scientific research documents, whether they are published or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers. L archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés.

PARIS-JOURDAN SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES 48, BD JOURDAN E.N.S. 75014 PARIS TEL. : 33(0) 1 43 13 63 00 FAX : 33 (0) 1 43 13 63 10 www.pse.ens.fr WORKING PAPER N 2006-15 Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal Keynesian multiplier Jean-Pascal Bénassy JEL Codes : E62, E63, E12 Keywords : multiplier, Ricardian equivalence, non-ricardian economies, price rigidities, Keynesian multiplier. CENTRE NATIONAL DE LA RECHERCHE SCIENTIFIQUE ÉCOLE DES HAUTES ÉTUDES EN SCIENCES SOCIALES ÉCOLE NATIONALE DES PONTS ET CHAUSSÉES ÉCOLE NORMALE SUPÉRIEURE

Ricardian Equivalence and the Intertemporal Keynesian Multiplier Jean-Pascal Bénassy December 2005 Revised February 2006 Abstract We show that Keynesian multiplier effects can be obtained in dynamic optimizing models if one combines both price rigidities and a non Ricardian framework where, due for example to the birth of new agents, Ricardian equivalence does not hold. JEL Codes: E62, E63, E12 Keywords: Multiplier, Ricardian equivalence, Non Ricardian economies, Price rigidities, Keynesian multiplier. Address: CEPREMAP-ENS, 48 Boulevard Jourdan, Bâtiment E, 75014, Paris, France. Telephone: 33-1-43136338. Fax: 33-1-43136232. E-mail: benassy@pse.ens.fr I wish to thank Fabrice Collard and Harris Dellas, but retain responsibility for all remaining deficiencies. 1

1 Introduction One of the most intriguing features of traditional Keynesian theory (Keynes, 1936, Hicks, 1937) is the so called multiplier effect by which an increase in governement spending can create an increase in consumption, whereas in Walrasian models it leads to a decrease, via the usual crowding out effect. This multiplier effect is customarily attributed to price or wage rigidities. Now in the recent evolution of macroeconomic modelling most macroeconomic issues are reexamined within the rigorous framework of dynamic intertemporal maximizing models à la Ramsey (1928). The typical model depicts consumers as one single dynasty of infinitely lived agents. This model has notably the property of Ricardian equivalence (Barro, 1974), according to which, in a nutshell, the distribution of taxes across time is irrelevant as long as the government balances its budget intertemporally. The model has been extended to a monetary framework (Sidrauski, 1969, Brock, 1975), where Ricardian equivalence also holds. In line with this recent evolution, a natural question to ask is whether a multiplier effect will arise in these dynamic models. The result has been actually disappointing: crowding out occurs in the usual DSGE model (see forexamplefatasandmihov,2001),andeveninmodelswithpricerigidities under standard parameterizations (see for example Collard and Dellas, 2005). What we want to show in this paper is that, in order to obtain a strong enough multiplier effect, another ingredient, in addition to price rigidities, has to be introduced in dynamic models. Namely one should not only have price rigidities, but also model the economy as non Ricardian. By non Ricardian economies we mean, as in Barro (1974), economies like overlapping generations (OLG) economies à la Samuelson (1958), where Ricardian equivalence does not hold. The non Ricardian economy we shall work with is due to Weil (1987, 1991). It is a monetary economy where, as in the Ricardian model, agents have an infinite life but, as in the OLG model, new agents arrive over time. We shall call n the rate of growth of the population. In a nutshell the results are: If n>0, there is a multiplier 1, and government spending leads to an increase in private consumption. This multiplier is larger, the higher n is, i.e. the more non Ricardian the economy is. 1 By this we mean more precisely that the income multiplier is greater than one, so that thereisnocrowdingout. 2

2 The model We shall thus use the model of Weil (1987, 1991), which has the great advantage of having the Ricardian model as a particular case. Each household lives forever, but new generations are born every period. Denote as N t the number of households alive at time t. We will work below with a constantrateofgrowthofthepopulationn 0, sothatn t =(1+n) t N 0.The Ricardian model corresponds to the special limit case n =0. 2.1 Households Considerahouseholdborninperiodj. Wedenotebyc jt, y jt and m jt his consumption, endowment and money holdings at time t j. This household maximizes the following utility function: U jt = β s t Log c js (1) and is submitted in period t to a cash in advance constraint: P t c jt m jt (2) Household j begins period t with a financial wealth ω jt. First the bond market opens, and the household lends an amount b jt at the nominal interest rate i t. The rest is kept under the form of money m jt,sothat: ω jt = m jt + b jt (3) Then the goods market opens, and the household sells his endowment y jt, pays taxes τ jt in real terms and consumes c jt, subject to the cash constraint (2). Consequently, the budget constraint for household j is: ω jt+1 =(1+i t ) ω jt i t m jt + P t y jt P t τ jt P t c jt (4) 2.2 Aggregation, endowments and taxes Aggregate quantities are obtained by summing the various individual variables. There are N j N j 1 agents in generation j, so for example aggregate taxes T t are given by: T t = X (N j N j 1 ) τ jt (5) j t 3

The other aggregate quantities, Y t,c t, Ω t,m t and B t, are deduced through similar formulas from the individual variables, y jt,c jt,ω jt,m jt and b jt. We now have to describe the distribution of endowments and taxes among households. We assume that all households have the same income and taxes: y jt = y t = Y t N t τ jt = τ t = T t N t (6) 3 The dynamic equations 3.1 Taxes and government budget constraint The dynamics of government liabilities Ω t is: Ω t+1 =(1+i t ) Ω t i t M t + P t G t P t T t (7) Government budget balance corresponds to Ω t+1 = Ω t, i.e. since Ω t = M t + B t : P t G t = P t T t i t B t (8) WewouldliketohaveataxindexT t such that budget balance is achieved under the traditional condition: This will be the case if we define T t through: G t = T t (9) P t T t = P t T t i t B t (10) Budget balance now corresponds to (9), and the government budget constraint (7) is rewritten as: 3.2 Consumption dynamics Ω t+1 = Ω t + P t G t P t T t (11) The dynamics of consumption is given by (see the appendix): P t+1 C t+1 = β (1 + n)(1+i t ) P t C t (1 β) nω t+1 (12) The dynamic system consists of equations (11) and (12). 4

4 The multiplier We shall assume that nominal prices are fully rigid, now and in the future. Besides simplifying the algebra this assumption, which is clearly the most favourable situation for a multiplier effect to arise, will allow to make crystalclear that a non Ricardian environment plays a central role in addition to price rigidities. We also assume that the nominal interest rate is pegged (i t = i). Now equation (12) is rewritten: P t C t = γp t+1 C t+1 + γ (1 β) nω t+1 with: = γp t+1 C t+1 + γ (1 β) n (Ω t + P t G t P t T t ) (13) 1 γ = (14) β (1 + n)(1+i) We shall assume γ<1 2. Integrating forward equation (13) we obtain: P t C t = γ (1 β) n Now from (11): so that: γ j Ω t+j = j=0 γ j (Ω t+j + P t+j G t+j P t+j T t+j ) (15) j=0 j 1 X Ω t+j = Ω t + P t+k (G t+k T t+k ) (16) k=0 j 1 X γ "Ω j t + P t+k (G t+k T t+k ) j=0 i=0 = Ω t 1 γ + X P t+k (G t+k T t+k ) k=0 j=k+1 = Ω t 1 γ + X γ k+1 1 γ P t+k (G t+k T t+k ) (17) k=0 and finally, inserting (17) into (15): 2 This condition also plays a role for price determinacy in models with market clearing. See Bénassy (2005) for a formal analysis and economic discussion. γ j 5

" γ (1 β) n P t C t = Ω t + 1 γ γ j P t+j (G t+j T t+j ) j=0 (18) So with n>0 consumption reacts positively to government spending, and from formula (18) the multiplier is greater, the higher n is. 5 Conclusion We have thus seen that in order to obtain a multiplier, price rigidities are not the only decisive ingredient, but it is also important to have a non Ricardian economy, corresponding here to n>0. We shall now give a brief intuition for this. Let us start with the limit case n =0. Asweshallnowseetheargument is quite reminiscent of the famous balanced budget multiplier of Haavelmo (1945). Consider indeed an increase in government spending, say G t,all other spending variables being held constant. Because of the government s intertemporal budget constraint, G t will have to be compensated by taxes, either now or in the future, and the total discounted value of these taxes must be exactly equal to G t. As a result we have a balanced budget formula, as in Haavelmo. Now if n>0, new generations arrive over time, and the future, but yet unborn, generations will bear some of the future taxes. So there is part of government spending that will not be paid by currently alive generations, and as a result the traditional multiplier mechanism comes into play. 6 Appendix: derivation of equation (12) We shall derive in this appendix the dynamic equation (12). Consider the household s budget equation (4). We assume that i t is strictly positive, so households always want to satisfy the cash in advance equation (2) exactly. We thus have m jt = P t c jt and equation (4) is rewritten: ω jt+1 =(1+i t ) ω jt + P t y t P t τ t (1 + i t ) P t c jt (19) Define the intertemporal discount factors: R t = Yt 1 s=0 1 1+i s R 0 =1 (20) 6

Applyingthediscountfactors(20)tothebudgetconstraint(19),itbecomes: R s+1 ω js+1 = R s ω js + R s+1 P s (y s τ s ) R s P s c js (21) If we aggregate all discounted budget constraints (21) from time t to infinity, and assume that R s ω js goes to zero as s goes to infinity (the usual transversality condition), we obtain the intertemporal budget constraint of the household: R s P s c js = R t ω jt + R s+1 P s (y s τ s ) (22) Now maximizing utility function (1) subject to the intertemporal budget constraint (22) yields the following consumption function for a household j: " R t P t c jt =(1 β) R t ω jt + R s+1 P s (y s τ s ) (23) Summing this across the N t agents alive in period t, we obtain the aggregate consumption C t : " X R t P t C t =(1 β) R t Ω t + N t R s+1 P s (y s τ s ) (24) In equilibrium Y t = C t + G t, so the equilibrium equation is: " X R t P t (Y t G t )=(1 β) R t Ω t + N t R s+1 P s (y s τ s ) Divide both sides by N t and use Y t = N t y t, G t = N t g t : " R t Ω t R t P t (y t g t )=(1 β) + R s+1 P s (y s τ s ) N t (25) (26) Let us rewrite this equation for t+1 and subtract it from (26). We obtain: R t P t (y t g t ) R t+1 P t+1 (y t+1 g t+1 )= Rt Ω t (1 β) R t+1ω t+1 + R t+1 P t (y t τ t ) N t N t+1 Now multiply the government s budget equation (7) by R t+1 /N t : (27) 7

R t Ω t N t = R t+1ω t+1 N t +(R t R t+1 ) P t (y t g t ) R t+1 P t g t + R t+1 P t τ t (28) Insert this into equation (27): µ 1 R t+1 P t+1 (y t+1 g t+1 )=βr t P t (y t g t ) (1 β) 1 R t+1 Ω t+1 N t N t+1 (29) and multiply by N t+1 /R t+1 : P t+1 (Y t+1 G t+1 )=β N µ t+1 Nt+1 (1 + i t ) P t (Y t G t ) (1 β) 1 Ω t+1 N t N t Taking finally N t+1 /N t =1+n, andusingc t = Y t G t we obtain: which is equation (12). References (30) P t+1 C t+1 = β (1 + n)(1+i t ) P t C t (1 β) nω t+1 (31) [1] Barro, Robert J. (1974), Are government bonds net wealth?, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 82, pp 1095-1117. [2] Bénassy, Jean-Pascal (2005), Interest rate rules, price determinacy and the value of money in a non-ricardian world, Review of Economic Dynamics, vol.8,pp651-667. [3] Brock, William A. (1975) A simple perfect foresight monetary model, J ournal of Monetary Economics, vol.1,pp133-150. [4] Collard, Fabrice and Harris Dellas (2005), Poole in the new Keynesian model, Europen Economic Review, vol. 49, pp 887-907. [5] Fatas, Antonio and Ilian Mihov (2001), The effects of fiscal policy on consumption and employment: theory and evidence, working paper, INSEAD. [6] Haavelmo, Trygve (1945), Multiplier effects of a balanced budget, Econometrica, vol. 11, pp 1-12. 8

[7] Hicks, John R. (1937), Mr. Keynes and the classics : a suggested interpretation, Econometrica, vol. 5, pp 147-159. [8] Keynes, John Maynard (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt Brace. [9] Ramsey, Frank P. (1928), A mathematical theory of saving, Economic Journal, vol. 38, pp 543-559. [10] Samuelson, Paul A. (1958), An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 66, pp 467-482. [11] Sidrauski, Miguel (1967), Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy, American Economic Review, vol. 57, supplement, pp 534-544. [12] Weil, Philippe (1987), Permanent budget deficits and inflation, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 20, pp 393-410. [13] Weil, Philippe (1991), Is money net wealth?, International Economic Review, vol. 32, 37-53. 9