Chapter 7 Pricing with Market Power SOLUTIONS TO EXERCISES

Similar documents
Chapter 2 Supply, Demand, and Markets SOLUTIONS TO EXERCISES

Economics 335 Problem Set 6 Spring 1998

Economics II - Exercise Session, December 3, Suggested Solution

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Problem Set #8

Final Exam - Solutions

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Derivations: LR and SR Profit Maximization

Econ 110: Introduction to Economic Theory. 11th Class 2/14/11

Chapter 6 Analyzing Accumulated Change: Integrals in Action

Market demand is therefore given by the following equation:

Economics 101 Fall 2013 Homework 5 Due Thursday, November 21, 2013

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Label the section where the total demand is the same as one demand and where total demand is different from both individual demand curves.

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Chapter 14: Firms in Competitive Markets

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Economics 101 Spring 2000 Section 4 - Hallam Final Exam Version E - Blue

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Prof. Ergin Bayrak Spring Homework 2

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

Monopoly Chapter 24 (cont.)

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

INSTITUTE OF MANAGEMENT, NIRMA UNIVERSITY MBA (FT)- I (Batch ) : Term III (End Term Exam)

Commerce and Economics

Chapter 11 Online Appendix:

*** Your grade is based on your on-line answers. ***

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Homework 1 Solutions

Answer ALL questions from Section A and ONE question from Section B. Section A weighs 60% of the total mark and Section B 40% of the total mark.

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Second Quiz Review: Solutions Managerial Economics: Eco 685

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

log(q i ) pq i + w i, max pq j c 2 q2 j.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

Econ 110: Introduction to Economic Theory. 10th Class 2/11/11

b) The first secret of happiness is consuming on the Budget line, that is the condition That is

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

Microeconomic Analysis PROBLEM SET 6

Assignment 2 (part 1) Deadline: September 30, 2004

PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM Welfare Analysis

Economics 222 Exercise A due Thursday 27 September in class

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Consumer surplus is zero and the outcome is Pareto efficient since there is no deadweight loss.

Econ 210, Final, Fall 2015.

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Unit 3: Production and Cost

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Chapter 17: Vertical and Conglomerate Mergers

Honors General Exam PART 1: MICROECONOMICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2013

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

Recall the conditions for a perfectly competitive market. Firms are price takers in both input and output markets.

Competitive Firms in the Long-Run

0 $50 $0 $5 $-5 $50 $35 1 $50 $50 $40 $10 $50 $15 2 $50 $100 $55 $45 $50 $35 3 $50 $150 $90 $60 $50 $55 4 $50 $200 $145 $55 $65

Lecture # 6 Elasticity/Taxes

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

Assignment 5. Intermediate Micro, Spring Due: Thursday, April 10 th

On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule

Solution to Sample Quiz 2

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Economics Honors Exam 2008 Solutions Question 1

U(x 1. ; x 2 ) = 4 ln x 1

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Lecture 7-9 2/8-15/2016

1. Suppose the demand and supply curves for goose-down winter jackets in 2014 were as given below:

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand

max x + y s.t. y + px = m

The table below shows the prices of the only three commodities traded in Shire.

TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

Econ 815 Dominant Firm Analysis and Limit Pricing

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Lecture 3: Tax incidence

File: ch08, Chapter 8: Cost Curves. Multiple Choice

The objectives of the producer

ECON-140 Midterm 2 Spring, 2011

Percentage Change and Elasticity

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Cable TV

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Solutions to Extra Business Problems

This is Toolkit, chapter 31 from the book Theory and Applications of Economics (index.html) (v. 1.0).

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Chapter 9. The Instruments of Trade Policy

Transcription:

Firms, Prices & Markets Timothy Van Zandt August 2012 Chapter 7 Pricing with Market Power SOLUTIONS TO EXERCISES Exercise 7.1. Suppose you produce minivans at a constant marginal cost of $15K and your demand curve is d(p ) = 16 0.6P. (Price is measured in 1000s of dollars and quantity is measured in 100,000s of minivans.) Find your optimal price and quantity. Solution: The choke price is 16/0.6 = 80/3; hence your optimal monopoly price is ((80/3) + 15)/2 = 125/6. Exercise 7.2. What happens if a per-unit tax is imposed on a monopolist s product? One answer might be: Since the monopolist can charge whatever it wants, it will pass the tax on to the consumer. But this does not say much, since any firm can charge whatever price it wants. The question is: What price does it want to charge? Let s see if we can provide a more informative answer. When faced with a question like this, one strategy is to start by working out a few simple examples. This at least illustrates some possibilities. Find out how a per-unit tax changes the price of (a) a firm with constant marginal cost and linear demand and (b) a firm with constant marginal cost and log-linear demand. You can use the formulas we just presented. You should treat the tax like a per-unit cost borne by the firm. If the firm s marginal cost is MC and the tax is Τ, then the firm s marginal cost after the tax is MC + Τ. For the case of log-linear demand, use a particular value of B>1such as 2 or 3. Solution: Let P Π be the price before the tax and let P Τ be the price after the tax. Linear demand: Q = A BP. Let P be the choke price. Then P Π = (MC + P )/2 and the price after the tax is P Τ = MC + Τ + P 2 = MC + P 2 + Τ 2 = P Π + Τ 2. Therefore, the price goes up by exactly half the tax. The firm does not choose to pass the entire tax on to the consumer. Log-linear demand: Q = AP B.Then P Π = B B 1 MC and P Τ = B B 1 (MC + Τ) = P Π + B B 1 Τ Since B>1, B/(B 1) > 1. That is, the price goes up by more than the tax. For example, if B = 3,thenB/(B 1) = 3/2. The price goes up by (3/2)Τ. This tells us that the price may go up by either more or less than the tax not very conclusive, but at least we have learned that it is wrong to think that the firm will simply raise its price by the tax. Instead, the way the tax is passed on depends on the details of the demand. Exercise 7.3. Suppose your firm produces a water purification system that you sell to small businesses. The demand for this indivisible good is shown in the first two columns of Table E7.1 (money values are in 1000s). Revenue is calculated for you in the third column. The fourth column shows your cost, and the profit is calculated in the fifth column. Figure E7.1 is a graph of the demand curve.

Firms, Prices & Markets Solutions for Chapter 7 (Pricing with Market Power) 2 Table E7.1 Output Price Revenue Cost Profit 0 60 0 0 0 1 57 57 25 32 2 54 108 50 58 3 51 153 75 78 4 48 192 100 92 5 45 225 125 100 6 42 252 150 102 7 39 273 175 98 8 36 288 200 88 9 33 297 225 72 10 30 300 250 50 11 27 297 275 22 12 24 288 300 12 13 21 273 325 52 Figure E7.1 P ( 1000) 57 54 51 48 45 42 39 36 33 30 27 24 21 18 15 12 9 6 3 Consumer surplus Producer surplus Cost of production Demand Deadweight loss 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 Q a. What would your price and quantity be if you maximized total surplus? (Choose the quantity that roughly equates marginal valuation to marginal cost, remembering that price at a given quantity is the marginal valuation.) How much is the total surplus? Solution: You set the price to your constant marginal cost of 25 and supply the demand at this price. Hence, P = 25 and Q = 11. The total consumer valuation is the sum of the prices for each of the first 11 points on the demand curve, starting at the highest price and lowest quantity: 57 + 54 + 51 + 48 + 45 + 42 + 39 + 36 + 33 + 30 + 27 = 462. The total cost is 11 25 = 275. Hence, total surplus is 462 275 = 187.

Firms, Prices & Markets Solutions for Chapter 7 (Pricing with Market Power) 3 b. What is the profit-maximizing price? What is your profit? How much is the consumer surplus? How much is the deadweight loss? Illustrate the profit, consumer surplus, and deadweight loss in Figure E7.1. (Your diagram should look similar to Figure 7.5.) Solution: The maximum profit is 102, achieved by P = 42. The total valuation of the 6 units sold is 57 + 54 + 51 + 48 + 45 + 42 = 297. The total amount paid by customers for the six units is 6 42 = 252. Hence, consumer surplus is 45. Totalsurplusis 102 + 45 = 147. Deadweight loss is 187 147 = 40. Exercise 7.4. You manage a firm and must make the following decision. There is a good that could be developed with an R&D investment of 250, after which a patent would be obtained and the good could be produced at a constant marginal cost of 10. The potential market for this good has the following demand curve: d(p ) = 25 (1/2)P. The purpose of this exercise is to formulate a business plan before making the investment. a. If you were to develop the product, what price would you charge and how much would you sell? Solution: We have (a) linear demand with a choke price of P = 50 and (b) constant MC = 10. Thus, using the midpoint pricing rule, I would charge P = (50 + 10)/2 = 30. I can then calculate Q by plugging P into the demand curve: d(30) = 25 (1/2)30 = 10. b. Calculate your variable profit that is, your profit ignoring the up-front R&D cost. Solution: My profit ignoring the fixed cost is (P MC)Q, or VΠ= (30 10)10 = 200. c. Should you make the investment? Solution: I check whether variable profit (200) exceeds the fixed cost (250). It does not. I should not make the investment. d. Suppose instead the R&D cost is only 100. How would your answers change? Solution: My price, quantity, and variable profit if I develop the product do not change. However, I now find that the variable profit exceeds the R&D cost. Hence, I choose to develop the product.

Firms, Prices & Markets Solutions for Chapter 7 (Pricing with Market Power) 4 e. Suppose you initially estimate the R&D cost to be 100 and that you go ahead and develop the product. However, the R&D cost ends up being 250. How does this affect your pricing when you launch the product or your decision of whether to actually launch the product? Solution: This cost is now sunk and it has no effect on my pricing or decision of whether to launch the product. I charge 30 as planned. Taking into account the sunk cost, I end up losing 50, but abandoning the project now would be worse I would lose the entire 250 R&D expense. Exercise 7.5. For the demand curve in Exercise 7.4, the total valuation curve for the consumers is v(q) = 50Q Q 2. a. If the R&D expense is 250, what is your profit? What is the consumer surplus? What are the total gains from trade? Solution: Since I do not develop the product, I have zero revenue, zero cost, and zero profit. Similarly, the consumers get no surplus from the good. b. If the R&D expense is 100, what is your profit? What is the consumer surplus? What are the total gains from trade? Solution: My profit is the variable profit (200) minus the R&D expense (100), which equals 100. I produce 10 units and so the consumers total valuation is v(10) = (50 10) 10 2 = 500 100 = 400. Their total expenditure is 30 10 = 300. Hence, their surplus is 100. Total surplus is therefore 200. Exercise 7.6. You are the CEO of Benevolent Dictators Ltd. There is a good that could be developed with an R&D investment of 250, after which the good could be produced at a constant marginal cost of 10. The potential market for this good has the following demand curve: d(p ) = 25 (1/2)P. This implies the following total valuation curve for the consumers: v(q) = 50Q Q 2. The purpose of this exercise is to formulate a plan before making the investment, given your objective to maximize total surplus (whether or not you can break even doing so). a. If you were to develop the product, how much would you produce? Solution: I choose Q to equate MV = MC. I can find the marginal valuation curve either by differentiating the total valuation curve or by calculating the inverse of the demand curve (solving Q = 25 (1/2)P for P as a function of Q). Either way, I obtain mv(q) = 50 2Q. Then I solve mv(q) = mc(q), or50 2Q = 10. This yields Q = 20.

Firms, Prices & Markets Solutions for Chapter 7 (Pricing with Market Power) 5 Shortcut: Given that the marginal cost is constant, I can also produce the amount that would be demanded if I charged the marginal cost. This yields d(10) = 25 (1/2)10 = 20. (Of course, same answer, different method.) b. Calculate the variable surplus that is, the surplus not taking into account the fixed cost. Solution: The variable surplus is the total valuation of the 20 units minus the variable cost of the 20 units. The total valuation is v(20) = (50 20) 20 2 = 1000 400 = 600. The variable cost is MC Q = 10 20 = 200. Therefore, variable surplus is 600 200 = 400. c. Should you make the investment? Solution: I check whether variable surplus (400) exceeds the fixed cost (250). It does hence, I make the investment. d. Suppose instead the R&D cost is only 100. How would your answers change? Solution: No changes. Since the fixed cost does not affect the marginal conditions, its amount does not affect how much I produce if I choose to develop the product. Since the fixed cost is lower, I still want to develop the product. Exercise 7.7. This problem refers back to Exercise 7.6. a. What are the total gains from trade if the R&D expense is 250? Solution: Total gains from trade equal total valuation minus total cost or, equivalently, the variable surplus minus the fixed cost. Either way, the answer is 150. b. What are the total gains from trade if the R&D expense is 100? Solution: 400 100 = 300. Exercise 7.8. Combine the results from Exercises 7.4 7.7 to fill in the following table for the demand curve and marginal cost in those exercises. FC Possible surplus Actual surplus Deadweight loss 250 100 What is the difference between the sources of the deadweight loss in the two cases?

Firms, Prices & Markets Solutions for Chapter 7 (Pricing with Market Power) 6 Solution: FC Possible surplus Actual surplus Deadweight loss 250 150 0 150 100 300 200 100 In the first case (FC = 250), the deadweight loss occurs because the patent system does not provide full incentives for innovation, and hence the investment does not take place even though it should. In the second case, the deadweight loss occurs because the patent monopoly allows the firm to keep the price above the marginal cost. Thus, the amount of production is less than socially optimal.