EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Similar documents
Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Noncooperative Oligopoly

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Chapter 10: Price Competition Learning Objectives Suggested Lecture Outline: Lecture 1: Lecture 2: Suggestions for the Instructor:

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

I. Introduction and definitions

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

MICROECONOMICS II. Author: Gergely K hegyi. Supervised by Gergely K hegyi. February 2011

Introduction to Game Theory

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Solution Problem Set 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

Solutions to Homework 3

Module 3: "Dynamic games of complete information" Lecture 23: "Bertrand Paradox in an Infinitely repeated game" The Lecture Contains:

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

Chapter 9. Noncompetitive Markets and Inefficiency. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

SOLVING COURNOT, STACKELBERG AND COLLUSION GAMES USING R

Economics 171: Final Exam

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium

Antoine Augustine Cournot was a French mathematician who, in 1838, wrote a book entitled Researches

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z),

HE+ Economics Nash Equilibrium

Dynamic Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Dynamic Games 1 / 18

Advanced Microeconomics

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should:

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Oligopoly. Johan Stennek

Endogenous choice of decision variables

LECTURE 17: STRATEGIC INTERACTION

Lecture Notes on Anticommons T. Bergstrom, April 2010 These notes illustrate the problem of the anticommons for one particular example.

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 26, Lecture 28. Oligopoly

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Strategy -1- Strategy

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

Horizontal Mergers. Chapter 11: Horizontal Mergers 1

Prof. Ergin Bayrak Spring Homework 2

TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

Monopolistic competition models

pq A q A = (6.01q A.01q C )q A q A = 6q A.01q 2 A.01q C q A q A.

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Transcription:

EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis

Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored. Each firm recognises that its decisions influence the decisions of other firms in the market and are in turn influenced by them. So a firm s decisions depend on what its rivals do or might do. There is no single model of oligopoly we will discuss several. But one method of analysis: Game theory.

Oligopoly: Assumptions Few sellers, or a small number of sellers with high market shares Price-making sellers Sellers behave strategically Many small, price-taking buyers Perfectly informed or not well informed buyers Homogeneous or differentiated product Conditions of entry can vary from completely blocked to perfectly free

A Simple Duopoly Game Two firms, 1 and 2. Each firm sells its own version of a product Each firm chooses the price of its product When choosing its price, a firm does not know the price the other firm has chosen There are only two pricing strategies, price high and price low All strategies and payoffs are known to both firms Firms interact only once

A Simple Duopoly Game Player 2 High Low Player 1 High 15, 15 0, 25 Low 25, 0 5, 5

A Simple Duopoly Game Player 2 High Low Player 1 High 15, 15 0, 25 Low 25, 0 5, 5

Duopoly The Nash equilibrium of this one-shot game is that both firms set a low price. We will see later that this result can change if the firms interact more than once. More generally and realistically, firms can choose between more than two prices (or quantities).

Cournot Duopoly Two firms, 1 and 2, selling the same product Each firm chooses the quantity that it sells Firms choose their respective quantities independently and simultaneously and interact only once Each firm has a cost function C i (q i ) No capacity constraints After the output decisions, the price adjusts according to the demand function p = p(q), where Q = q 1 + q 2 is the total output sold in the market Cost functions and demand are known to both firms

Cournot Duopoly We are looking for the Nash equilibrium of this game: a pair of quantities such that each firm is maximising its profit given the quantity of the other firm. The optimal output of firm 1 depends on firm 2 s output. Suppose firm 1 believes that firm 2 will produce q 20. What is the level of output that would maximise firm 1 s profit? More generally, what is the level of output that would maximise firm 1 s profit for any given level of output produced by firm 2? To find this, we must first obtain firm 1 s residual demand function.

Residual Demand Function for q 2 = q 20 P q 20 Market Demand (assumed to be linear) Firm 1 s residual demand 0 Q

Firm 1 s Best Response to q 2 = q 20 P q 20 MC1 The point where (residual) marginal revenue equals marginal cost gives the best response of firm 1 to q2 = q20. MR 1 0 q Q 1 (q 20 )

Firm 1 s Best Response Function For every possible output of firm 2, we can determine firm 1's best response. The sum of all these points is the best response function of firm 1. Firm 1 s best response function is also called firm 1 s reaction function: q 1 = R 1 (q 2 ). Firm 1 s reaction function gives us the level of output that maximises firm 1 s profit for any possible value of firm 2 s output.

Firm 1 s Reaction Function q 20 q 2 MC 1 Firm 1 s Reaction Function 0 R 1 (q 20 ) q 21 q 20 q 21 MC 1 0 R R 1 (q 20 ) 1 (q 21 ) q 1 0 R 1 (q 21 )

Slope of Firm 1 s Reaction Function The reaction function is downward sloping: the more firm 2 produces (or is expected to produce), the lower the chosen output of firm 1. In other words, the more aggressive firm 2 is, the less aggressive firm 1 is in response: we say that the firms actions, q 1 and q 2, are strategic substitutes.

Cournot Equilibrium We can derive firm 2 s reaction function in a similar manner. At a Nash Equilibrium, firm 1 s output must be a best response to firm 2 s output; and conversely, firm 2 s output must be a best response to firm 1 s output: q 1C = R 1 (q 2C ) and q 2C = R 2 (q 1C ). In other words, none of the firms has an incentive to change its output given the rival s output.

Cournot Equilibrium q 2 q 2 M R 1 The Cournot-Nash equilibrium is given by the intersection of the two reaction functions q 2 C R 2 0 q 1 C q 1 M q 1

Cournot : A Numerical Example Suppose the inverse demand is given by P = 100 Q P = 100 (q1 + q2) and that MC = AC = 10. What is firm 1's profit-maximising output when firm 2 produces, say, 50? Firm 1's residual demand is given by: P = 100 (q1 + 50) = 100 q1 50 = 50 q1. Therefore: MR1,50 = P + q1 (ΔP/Δq1) = 50 q1 + q1 (-1) = 50 2q1. Finally, MR1,50 = MC 50 2q1 = 10 q1,50 = 20.

Cournot : A Numerical Example More generally, when firm 2 produces any given level of output q2, what is firm 1's profit-maximising output? Firm 1's residual demand is given by: P = 100 (q1 + q2) = 100 q1 q2, where q2 is taken as given. Therefore MR1 = P + q1 (ΔP/Δq1) = 100 q1 q2 + q1 (-1) = 100 2q1 q2. Finally, MR1 = MC 100 2q1 q2 = 10 q1 = 45 q2/2. This is firm 1's reaction function. Similarly, one can compute firm 2's reaction function: MR2 = MC 100 q1 2q2 = 10 q2 = 45 q1/2.

Cournot : A Numerical Example At the Cournot equilibrium the two reaction functions intersect. In other words, both equations are satisfied. So to find the Cournot equilibrium we solve the system We get q1* = q2* = 30. q1 = 45 q2/2 q2 = 45 q1/2. Then from the demand curve we obtain P* = 40. Note that P* > MC. Finally, the profit of each firm i is: (P MC) qi = 900.

Cournot Equilibrium: Comparative Statics q 2 R 1 The effect of a reduction in firm 2 s marginal cost At the new Cournot-Nash equilibrium firm 1 produces less (and makes less profit) and firm 2 more (and makes more profit) R 2 R 2 0 q 1

Joint Profit Maximisation If the two firms could agree to choose q 1 and q 2 to maximise the sum of their profits, would they produce more or less than the Cournot output? In the Cournot model, expanding q 1 hurts firm 2 s profits and expanding q 2 hurts firm 1 s profits. When the firms act independently (as in the Cournot model), they do not take these negative externalities into account. But when they maximise joint profits, they do. So they produce less and the market price is higher than the Cournot price. In fact the total output produced is the monopoly output and the price is the monopoly price.

Joint Profit Maximisation q 2 R 1 Isoprofit curves For any output pair in this region both firms make a higher profit than the Cournot equilibrium profit R 2 0 q 1

Incentives to Deviate from Joint Profit Maximisation q 2 R 1 R 2 (q 1J ) q 2 J R 2 0 q 1J R 1 (q 2J ) q 1

Incentives to Deviate from Joint Profit Maximisation The graph also illustrates why firms cannot maximise joint profits when they interact only once. When the other member(s) of a cartel stick to the collusive ouput/price, each individual firm has an incentive to cheat : increase its quantity and hence increase its profit. Collusion is illegal in most countries, so firms cannot sign binding agreements. Does this mean cartels cannot exist? We will see later that collusion can be sustainable under repeated interaction.

Price Competition with Homogenous Product Two firms sell the same product The firms choose the price of their product independently and simultaneously, and they serve the demand that arises at this price The firms interact only once Both firms have the same constant average and marginal cost c No capacity constraints Cost functions and demand known to both firms

Bertrand (Price) Competition We are looking for a Nash equilibrium of this game, i.e. a pair of prices such that each firm is maximising its profit given the price of the other firm. Assumptions about demand: If p i > p j, firm i makes no sales and has zero profit, while firm j covers the entire market at price p j and makes profit of (p j c) D(p j ) If p i = p j, each firm obtains half of the overall demand at that price and makes profit of (p i c) D(p i )/2

Bertrand Competition: Equilibrium To find the Nash equilibrium, we consider cases: pi > pj > c: No, because firm i will want to reduce its price below pj and make a positive profit rather zero pi = pj > c: No, because either firm will want to reduce its price slightly and almost double its profit pi > pj = c: No, because firm j will want to increase its price slightly and make some profit rather zero pi < c and/or pj < c: No, because one or both firms will want to set price equal to c and stop making losses pi = pj = c: YES. This is a Nash equilibrium as none of the firms can increase its profit by deviating.

Bertrand Competition With a homogenous good and equal and constant marginal costs, price competition leads to marginal cost pricing just like perfect competition. Both firms make zero profit. So having control over price is not a guarantee to earn positive profits. This result is independent of the number of firms. How can the Bertrand paradox be resolved? 1. Capacity constraints 2. Product differentiation 3. Repeated interaction

Prices or Quantities? Quantity competition and price competition have very different implications. Quantity competition is less tough than price competition: prices and profits are higher. But do firms compete by setting quantities? Maybe in some markets There is a more general and useful interpretation of quantity competition: competition between firms with capacity constraints.

Prices or Quantities? Capacity-constrained firms have no incentive to reduce price a lot since they cannot produce a lot of extra output competition is less tough. In fact, Cournot outcomes can emerge from a twostage process where firms first choose their capacities and then, given these capacities, they choose prices. The Cournot model is appropriate when firms are capacity-constrained, the Bertrand model when they are not.

Commitment By committing to an action, a party limits its own freedom of action Paradoxically, in a strategic situation, commitment can help a player achieve higher payoffs relative to no commitment provided it is observed by its rivals On the other hand, observing the action of an opponent can make a player worse-off compared to not being able to observe

Stackelberg Duopoly In a Stackelberg duopoly game one of the two firms can credibly commit to moving first and the other can observe this commitment. Let s reconsider our quantity-setting duopoly game assuming that firm 1 commits to choosing its quantity first. Firm 2 will observe q 1 and then choose q 2 and firm 1 knows that.

Stackelberg Equilibrium Firm 1 knows that for each q 1 that it could choose, firm 2 will respond with the corresponding q 2 on its reaction function, i.e. firm 1 knows that choosing q 1 will trigger a response q 2 = R 2 (q 1 ). Firm 1 can therefore choose any point on firm 2 s reaction function as an equilibrium of the duopoly game. Firm 1 will choose the point on R 2 where its own profit is largest.

Stackelberg Equilibrium q 2 R 1 Cournot Equilibrium Stackelberg Equilibrium R 2 0 q 1

Stackelberg : A Numerical Example Inverse demand is given by P = 100 (q1 + q2). MC = AC = 10. First firm 1 (the leader ) chooses a level of output q1. Then firm 2 (the follower ) observes q1 and chooses its level of output q2. Recall that the reaction function of firm 2 is q2 = 45 q1/2. When firm 1 chooses q1 it anticipates the reaction function of firm 2. So it chooses q1 to maximise its profit subject to q2 = 45 q1/2.

Stackelberg : A Numerical Example Formally, the residual demand for firm 1 is given by: P = 100 (q1 + q2) = 100 (q1 + 45 q1/2) = 55 q1/2. So MR1 = P + q1 (ΔP/Δq1) = P + q1 (-1/2) = 55 q1. MR1 = MC 55 q1 = 10 q1* = 45. The reaction function of firm 2 then gives q2* = 22.5. P* = 32.5. Profit of firm 1 = (32.5 10) 45 = 1012.50. Profit of firm 2 = (32.5 10) 22.5 = 506.25.

Stackelberg versus Cournot Cournot price > Stackelberg price > Marginal cost. Why is P > MC? Because both firms have some market power (each acts as a monopolist on its residual demand curve). Profit of Stackelberg leader > Cournot profit. Profit of Stackelberg follower < Cournot profit (but positive). Why? The leader can commit to a level of output before the follower. Since the quantities are strategic substitutes, the higher the output of one firm, the lower that of the other. The leader exploits its firstmover advantage to grab the bulk of the market.

Quiz Question 1 Which of the following is correct for an equilibrium in the Cournot model of oligopoly? (a) Each firm sets own MR = MC (b) Each firm s choice of output depends on the other firms choices of output (c) Each firm makes positive profit at equilibrium (d) All of the above (e) Statements (b) and (c) are correct

Quiz Question 2 A firm s reaction function in a Cournot duopoly model shows: (a) The firm s profit maximising level of output as a function of the rival s marginal cost (b) The firm s profit maximising price as a function of the rival s price (c) The firm s demand as a function of the rival s output (d) The firm s profit maximising price as a function of its marginal cost (e) None of the above

Quiz Question 3 In the Stackelberg (leader-follower) quantity-setting model of duopoly: (a) Each firm produces less than the Cournot level and makes higher profit than the Cournot profit (b) Both firms produce less than the Cournot level and the leader makes more profit than the follower (c) The leader produces more and the follower less than the Cournot level and the leader makes more profit than the follower (d) The leader produces more and the follower less than the Cournot level and both firms make higher profit than the Cournot profit