Profitable Mergers. in Cournot and Stackelberg Markets:

Similar documents
Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Increased Uncertainty Drives Firms to Merge

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly Revisited: An Extension of Stackelberg Competition

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Cournot with N rms (revisited)

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Technological Asymmetry, Externality, and Merger: The Case of a Three-Firm Industry

Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

HORIZONTAL MERGERS, FIRM HETEROGENEITY, AND R&D INVESTMENTS

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Lecture: Mergers. Some facts about mergers from Andrade, Mitchell, and Stafford (2001) Often occur in waves, concentrated by industry

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

A Note on the Welfare Effects of Horizontal Mergers in Asymmetric Linear Oligopolies

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Export performance requirements under international duopoly*

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Altruism and the Transfer Paradox

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Follower Payoffs in Symmetric Duopoly Games

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Cross-border Mergers and Hollowing-out

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry

Horizontal Mergers. Chapter 11: Horizontal Mergers 1

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

A new model of mergers and innovation

Games and Economic Behavior

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Price Leadership in a Homogeneous Product Market

Environmental Tax Burden in a Vertical Relationship with Pollution-Abatement R&D

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. Quota bonuses as localized sales bonuses. by Barna Bakó, András Kálecz-Simon CEWP 1/2016

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Capacity precommitment and price competition yield the Cournot outcome

Market Structure and the Demand for Free Trade* Orlando I. Balboa** Andrew F. Daughety** Jennifer F. Reinganum** July 2001 Revised: December 2002

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. International Trade, Crowding Out, and Market Structure: Cournot Approach. James P.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory Fall 2003

Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly

Effect of Import Tariffs on Foreign Export Subsidies and Countervailing Duties

Endogenous formation of joint ventures with efficiency gains

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Product Differentiation, Asymmetric Information and International Mergers

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Overview Basic analysis Strategic trade policy Further topics. Overview

Mixed Duopoly with Price Competition

research paper series

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

Player 2 H T T -1,1 1, -1

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly under Uncertainty

Oligopoly Price Discrimination: The Role of Inventory Controls

Transcription:

Working Paper Series No.79, Faculty of Economics, Niigata University Profitable Mergers in Cournot and Stackelberg Markets: 80 Percent Share Rule Revisited Kojun Hamada and Yasuhiro Takarada Series No.79 Corresponding author. Address: 8050 Ikarashi 2-no-cho, Niigata City, 950-2181 Japan Tel. and fax: +81-25-262-6538 E-mail address: khamada@econ.niigata-u.ac.jp

Profitable Mergers in Cournot and Stackelberg Markets: 80 Percent Share Rule Revisited Kojun Hamada Yasuhiro Takarada Abstract In this paper, we examine the share rule for profitable mergers in the standard Cournot and Stackelberg models. We show that mergers are unprofitable unless they involve at least 80% of the firms with the same output choice timing in the industry. JEL classification: D43; L13 Keywords: Cournot competition; Stackelberg competition; 80 % share rule Corresponding author: Faculty of Economics, Niigata University, 8050, Ikarashi 2-no-cho, Niigata City 950-2181, Japan. Tel. and fax: +81-25-262-6538. E-mail address: khamada@econ.niigata-u.ac.jp Faculty of Policy Studies, Nanzan University, 27 Seirei-cho, Seto, Aichi 489-0863, Japan. Tel.: +81-561-89-2010 (Ext. 3541). Fax: +81-561-89-2012. E-mail address: ytakara@ps.nanzan-u.ac.jp 1

1 Introduction In a Cournot model, some exogenous mergers reduce the joint profits of the firms that are assumed to collude. Such unexpected result was initially observed by Salant, Switzer, and Reynolds (1983) (hereafter SSR). In the Cournot oligopoly with linear demand and cost functions, SSR (1983) showed that mergers among firms that produce homogeneous goods are unprofitable unless they involve at least 80% of the firms in the industry. The robustness of their conclusion was analyzed in various frameworks. Daughety (1990) investigated the issue of profitable horizontal mergers in a Stackelberg market with homogeneous goods and complemented the conclusion of SSR (1983) in the Cournot case. Recently, in the same framework, Huck, Konrad, and Müller (2001) studied that mergers between two leaders (two followers) are profitable only if there are two leaders (two followers). 1 In this paper, we examine the share rule for profitable mergers in the Stackelberg market as well as in the Cournot market with homogeneous goods. In spite of the recent development in the studies on mergers, comparison of such share rule in different market structures was not undertaken. Our study extends and complements the analysis of SSR (1983). We show that mergers are unprofitable unless they involve at least 80% of the firms with the same timing to choose output in the industry. Thus, the 80% share rule for profitable mergers in the Cournot case remains valid in the Stackelberg equilibrium in the sense that the mergers should include at least 80% of the leaders or the followers. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we re-present the result of SSR (1983). Section 3 analyzes profitable mergers in the Stackelberg market. Final section 1 Concerning papers on the profit of mergers in other settings, see also, Deneckere and Davidson (1985), Perry and Porter (1985), Kwoka (1989), and Farrell and Shapiro (1990). 2

concludes the paper with some remarks. 2 The result of SSR (1983): 80% share rule We briefly re-present the result of SSR (1983) under Cournot oligopoly. Consider a market for homogeneous product with N firms. Costs are assumed to be linear and the marginal cost is denoted by c. Inverse demand function is given by p(q) =a bq with Q = N i=1 q i denoting total supply and q i firm i s individual quantity. a>cis assumed. Firm i s profit is π i (q i )=(p(q) c)q i. Under N homogeneous Cournot quantity competition, the Cournot-Nash equilibrium implies that q i = a c N(a c) b(n+1). This gives a total supply of Q = b(n+1) marginal cost of p c = a c N+1. The profit of each firm can be written as π C (N) = and a price minus (a c)2 b(n +1) 2. (1) The firms have an incentive to merge if the profit of the post-merged firm exceeds the sum of the pre-merged firms profit. Then, the following inequality must be satisfied if the merger of k + 1 firms is profitable under Cournot oligopoly (k 0, N k + 1). π C (N k) (k +1)π C (N) (N +1) 2 (k + 1)(N k +1) 2. (2) From (2), SSR (1983) showed that no merger involving less than 80% of the firms in the industry would be privately profitable. 3 The share rule in the Stackelberg equilibrium In this section, we consider the two-stage homogenous Stackelberg oligopoly. The cost and demand conditions are the same as those under the Cournot oligopoly. There are n L <N 3

Stackelberg leaders who independently and simultaneously decide about their individual quantity. The n F (= N n L ) Stackelberg followers decide upon their quantity after learning about the total quantity supplied by the n L leaders. Let q L be the quantity of the identical typical leader and q F be the quantity of the identical typical follower. The subgame-perfect Stackelberg equilibrium implies that (q L,q F )=( a c b(n L +1), a c b(n L +1)(n F +1) ). This gives the sum of leaders and followers quantities denoted by Q L = nl (a c) b(n L +1) and QF = n F (a c) b(n L +1)(n F +1). The total supply is Q = (nl n F +n L +n F )(a c) b(n L +1)(n F +1) and subtracting marginal cost from the price, we have p c = a c. Then, the profits of a leader and a follower can be written as (n L +1)(n F +1) π L (n L,n F )= (a c) 2 b(n L +1) 2 (n F +1) and πf (n L,n F )= (a c) 2 b(n L +1) 2 (n F +1) 2. (3) To provide an incentive for k +1 leader firms to merge, the following inequality must be satisfied. π L (n L k, n F ) (k +1)π L (n L,n F ) (n L +1) 2 (k + 1)(n L k +1) 2. (4) A special feature to be noted in (4) is that the inequality does not depend on the number of the followers, n F. Likewise, to provide an incentive for k + 1 follower firms to merge, the following inequality must be satisfied. π F (n L,n F k) (k +1)π F (n L,n F ) (n F +1) 2 (k + 1)(n F k +1) 2. (5) Note that (5) does not depend on the number of the leaders, n L. 2 It is important to note that the above three equations (2), (4), and (5) represent the same 2 The share rule for profitable mergers between a leader and a follower is not examined in this paper since it was already analyzed in Huck et al. (2001). In this case, the result of profitable merger is attributed to the decrease in the number of followers after the merger. 4

condition except the variables on the number of the firms N,n L, and n F. Thus, we obtain the following proposition. Proposition 1. Suppose that firms face the two-stage Stackelberg quantity competition. Then, (i) the Stackelberg leaders have an incentive to merge if the market share of the merged firm with respect to the leaders exceeds 80%. Likewise, (ii) the Stackelberg followers have an incentive to merge if the market share of the merged firm with respect to the followers exceeds 80%. Proof. Rewriting (2) ((4),(5)), we have the necessary and sufficient condition under which the merger is profitable, i.e., k +1 n k + k +1;n = {N,n L,n F }. Let us denote by α k+1 n the merged firm s share with respect to the number of firms with the same timing. Thus, the share for the profitable merger is given as follows: k +1 k + k +1 α 1. (6) The least share for a profitable merger is α(k) k+1 k+. This first and second derivatives are k+1 α (k) = 1/2 k+1 1 (k+ and k+1) 2 α (k) = 3k(k+1) 1/2 +7 4(k+. Solving the first-order condition on α(k) with k+1) 3 respect to k, α ( k) = 0, we obtain k = 3. Because the second-order condition, α (k) > 0, is satisfied under any k in the neighborhood of k, k is a local minumum value. Moreover, α(k) is strictly decreasing when 0 k< k (α (k) < 0) and it is strictly increasing when k > k (α (k) > 0 respectively). Thus, k = 3 is the unique global minimum value. The minimum of the share is α( k) = b k+1 =0.8. bk+ b k+1 The minimum of the least share for a profitable merger is 80%. When there exist N =5 firms in the industry and k + 1 = 4 firms merge, the profitable merger occurs under the least market share. The least share function, α(k),k 0 is graphed out by Figure 1. 5

α(k) 1 0.98 0.96 0.94 0.92 0.9 0.88 0.86 0.84 0.82 0.8 3 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 k Figure 1: the least share for the profitable merger (α(k)) 4 Concluding remarks In the Stackelberg market as well as in the Cournot market, we showed that mergers are unprofitable unless they involve at least 80% of the firms with the same output choice timing in the industry. Note that the share rule for profitable mergers in the Stackelberg case is less than 80% if it is calculated with respect to the total number of the firms (both the leaders and the followers) in the industry. This implies that a merger between firms producing homogeneous goods is likely to be profitable in the Stackelberg market. The total output is reduced and so is the welfare by mergers in both the Stackelberg and the Cournot cases. This result can be explained as follows. Let us consider the merger of the followers. In the 6

Stackelberg market, the followers decide their quantities after having already looked at the sum of the quantity of the leaders. The merger between the followers takes place if the profit of the post-merged firm exceeds the sum of the pre-merged firm under the residual demand after the leaders output choice. This decision of the second-stage Stackelberg follower is the same as that of the Cournot case except that the demand considered is the residual one. Next, considering the merger of the leaders, the leaders decide on the merger, taking into consideration the best response on the effect that the leaders quantities choice has on the quantities of the followers. The similar logic explains the 80% share rule among the leaders in the first-stage under the reduced demand which incorporates the effect of the best response. From this logic, we can conjecture that the 80% share rule will hold in the n-stage Stackelberg market. We discussed the case in which the firms in the industry are identical. One of the remaining issues is the analysis of the share rule for profitable mergers when there exist asymmetric firms. The case of profitable mergers between the asymmetric firms should be examined using more general frameworks. Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge financial support by Japan Securities Scholarship Foundation. This study was partially supported by Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (No.16730095 (Kojun Hamada) and No.18730177 (Yasuhiro Takarada)) from JSPS and MEXT of the Japanese Government. This study is also supported by the Pache Research Subsidy I A 2 (Nanzan University, 2006). The usual disclaimer applies. 7

References [1] Daughety, Andrew F. Beneficial Concentration. American Economic Review 80 (December 1990): 1231 37. [2] Deneckere, Raymond and Davidson, Carl. Incentives to Form Coalitions with Bertrand Competition. Rand Journal of Economics 16 (Winter 1985): 473 86. [3] Farrell, Joseph and Shapiro, Carl. Horizontal Mergers: An Equilibrium Analysis. American Economic Review 80 (March 1990): 107 26. [4] Huck, Steffen, Konrad, Kai A. and Müller, Wieland. Big Fish Eat Small Fish: On Merger in Stackelberg Markets. Economics Letters 73 (November 2001): 213 17. [5] Kwoka, John E. Jr. The Private Profitability of Horizontal Mergers with Non-Cournot and Maverick Behavior. International Journal of Industrial Organization 7 (1989): 403 11. [6] Perry, Martin K. and Porter, Robert H. Oligopoly and the Investment for Horizontal Merger. American Economic Review 75 (March 1985): 219 27. [7] Salant, Stephen W., Switzer, Sheldon and Reynolds, Robert J. Losses from Horizontal Merger: The Effects of an Exogenous Change in Industry Structure on Cournot-Nash Equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (May 1983): 185 99. 8