Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Homework 4

Similar documents
Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

Lecture 23: April 10

4.2 Therapeutic Concentration Levels (BC)

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

Random Walk for Stock Price

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

The Simple Random Walk

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Homework 5

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Answers to Problem Set #8

Economics 307: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory A Brief Mathematical Primer

Developmental Math An Open Program Unit 12 Factoring First Edition

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

Part 10: The Binomial Distribution

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Math Analysis Midterm Review. Directions: This assignment is due at the beginning of class on Friday, January 9th

Financial Economics. Runs Test

Sampling; Random Walk

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance. A Stochastic Process Model of Cash Management

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

GEK1544 The Mathematics of Games Suggested Solutions to Tutorial 3

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Prentice Hall Connected Mathematics, Grade 7 Unit 2004 Correlated to: Maine Learning Results for Mathematics (Grades 5-8)

Measuring Interest Rates

Characterization of the Optimum

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

MATH1215: Mathematical Thinking Sec. 08 Spring Worksheet 9: Solution. x P(x)

18. Forwards and Futures

Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis. David Klein Statistics 157

Sequences, Series, and Limits; the Economics of Finance

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

1 The continuous time limit

Definition 4.1. In a stochastic process T is called a stopping time if you can tell when it happens.

Foreign Trade and the Exchange Rate

Sandringham School Sixth Form. AS Maths. Bridging the gap

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Discrete Mathematics for CS Spring 2008 David Wagner Final Exam

The Kelly Criterion. How To Manage Your Money When You Have an Edge

X i = 124 MARTINGALES

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Chapter 14 : Statistical Inference 1. Note : Here the 4-th and 5-th editions of the text have different chapters, but the material is the same.

Quadrant marked mesh patterns in 123-avoiding permutations

P (X = x) = x=25

Geometric Brownian Motion (Stochastic Population Growth)

Factoring Quadratic Expressions VOCABULARY

Math 180A. Lecture 5 Wednesday April 7 th. Geometric distribution. The geometric distribution function is

An Introduction to the Mathematics of Finance. Basu, Goodman, Stampfli

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Randomness and Fractals

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Chapter 11. Data Descriptions and Probability Distributions. Section 4 Bernoulli Trials and Binomial Distribution

The Mathematics of Normality

7-4. Compound Interest. Vocabulary. Interest Compounded Annually. Lesson. Mental Math

Y t )+υ t. +φ ( Y t. Y t ) Y t. α ( r t. + ρ +θ π ( π t. + ρ

Mathematics of Finance

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Time Value of Money Toolbox CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION CASH FLOWS

Math 227 Elementary Statistics. Bluman 5 th edition

ST. DAVID S MARIST INANDA

, the nominal money supply M is. M = m B = = 2400

Name For those going into. Algebra 1 Honors. School years that begin with an ODD year: do the odds

Lecture 9: Prediction markets, fair games and martingales..

Convergence. Any submartingale or supermartingale (Y, F) converges almost surely if it satisfies E Y n <. STAT2004 Martingale Convergence

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Finance 651: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 2012

The Normal Distribution

Symmetric Game. In animal behaviour a typical realization involves two parents balancing their individual investment in the common

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

Maximum Likelihood Estimation

Applications of Exponential Functions Group Activity 7 Business Project Week #10

Problem Set 2: Answers

Resistance to support

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Martingales. Will Perkins. March 18, 2013

Chapter 6 Probability

6. Martingales. = Zn. Think of Z n+1 as being a gambler s earnings after n+1 games. If the game if fair, then E [ Z n+1 Z n

ACCUPLACER Elementary Algebra Assessment Preparation Guide

17 MAKING COMPLEX DECISIONS

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

6.041SC Probabilistic Systems Analysis and Applied Probability, Fall 2013 Transcript Lecture 23

Rational Infinitely-Lived Asset Prices Must be Non-Stationary

CS 798: Homework Assignment 4 (Game Theory)

Continuous-Time Pension-Fund Modelling

III. Solving Applications: Systems of Two Equations

Engineering Economy Chapter 4 More Interest Formulas

******************************* The multi-period binomial model generalizes the single-period binomial model we considered in Section 2.

THE UNIVERSITY OF TEXAS AT AUSTIN Department of Information, Risk, and Operations Management

The Binomial and Geometric Distributions. Chapter 8

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

HARVEST MODELS INTRODUCTION. Objectives

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

Lesson Exponential Models & Logarithms

Transcription:

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Homework 4 Steve Dunbar Due Mon, October 5, 2009 1. (a) For T 0 = 10 and a = 20, draw a graph of the probability of ruin as a function of the probability q. (b) For a = 20 and q = 0.55 draw a graph of the probability ruin as a function of T 0. (c) For a = 20 and q = 0.45 draw a graph of the probability of ruin as a function of T 0. See the graphs in the accompanying Maple Worksheet. 2. In a random walk starting at the origin find the probability that the point a > 0 will be reached before the point b < 0. Solution: Let the probability that X i = +1 be p, that is, a step to the right occurs with probability p. The stated random walk problem is equivalent to the ruin probability for a gambler starting with initial fortune b who succeeds by reaching increasing his fortune by a to reach the level a + b before being ruined by losing b reaching 0. This is the complementary probability to the ruin probability and so may be expressed as p b = 1 q b = 1 (q/p)a+b (q/p) b (q/p) a+b 1 1

This can be simplified to (q/p) b 1 (q/p) a+b 1. Alternatively, we can view this as the ruin of the gambler s adversary, and using the idea in the first corollary, express this as: ((p/q) a+b (p/q) a )/((p/q) a+b 1). One can verify with a little algebra that these expressions are equivalent. 3. Show that in a random walk starting at the origin the probability to reach a > 0 before returning to the origin equals p(1 q 1 ) Solution: If the walker starts at the origin and goes to 1 at the first step, then the walk must return to the origin again before possibly reaching a > 0. Hence we need only consider the possibility of the walk starting from the point 1 at the first step, and then reaching the value a > 0 before returning to the origin. The probability of going to 1 is p, and then from 1 the subsequent independent probability of reaching a before returning to the origin is the same as the probability of the gambler achieving success at a before reaching the origin, which is 1 q 1. Therefore the joint probability of the two independent events in succession is p(1 q 1 ). Consider a special case just to check the results. Consider p = 1/2 = q. Then it is easy to compute that p(1 q 1 ) = (1/2)(1 (1 1/a)) = 1/(2a). Now take a = 2, and start from the origin. It is easy to see that the only way to go from the origin to the point a = 2 before returning to the origin is to go from 0 to 1, and then 1 to 2 in sequence. Anything whatsoever can then happen, so long as the walk ultimately returns to the origin, which we know it must. So from direct computation, the probability of such a path is 1/4. The formula gives the probability 1/(2a) = 1/(2 2) = 1/4, so the formula agrees with direct calculation in this special case, and we are reassured! 4. (a) Draw a sample path of a random walk (with p = 1/2 = q) starting from the origin where the walk visits the position 5 twice before returning to the origin. 2

(b) Using the result from questions 2, it can be shown with careful but elementary reasoning that the number of times N that a random walk (p = 1/2 = q) reaches the value a a total of n times before returning to the origin is a random variable with probability and Pr[N = 0] = 1 1/(2a) Pr[N = n] = ( ) ( 1 1 1 ) n 1. 4a 2 2a for n 1. Compute the expected number of visits E[N] to level a. (c) Compare the expected number of visits of a random walk (p = 1/2 = q) to the value 1 million before returning to the origin and to the level 10 before returning to the origin. Solution: for part b: This problem is adapted from W. Feller, in Introduction to Probability Theory and Applications, Volume I, Chapter XIV, Section 9, problem 3, page 367. If q p, conclude from the preceding problem: In a random walk starting at the origin, the number of visits to the point a > 0 that take place before the first return to the geometric distribution with ratio 1 qq a 1. (Explain why the condition q p is necessary) This problem is conceptually and computationally simpler if p = q = 1/2 so I will work only that case. It is convenient to first calculate and record some probabilities, then solve the problem. Starting from the origin, the probability to reach a > 0 before returning to the origin is p(1 q 1 ) = p(1 (1 1/a)) = p(1/a) = 1/(2a). Starting at a, the probability to reach the origin before returning to the starting point is qq a 1 = q(1 (a 1)/a) = q(1/a) = 1/(2a). This makes sense, since this situation is symmetric with the previous situation and so should have the same probability. The ratio for the geometric probability is supposed to be 1 qq a 1 = 1 q(1 (a 1)/a) = 1 q(1/a) = 1 1/(2a) = (2a 1)/(2a). 3

The probability of 0 visits to a before hitting the origin is the complement of the probability of one (or more) visits to a before hitting the origin. Since the random walk is recurrent (that is, will hit every point eventually from any starting point, this is where the necessity of p = q = 1/2 comes in!) the probability of hitting the origin again from a (perhaps after more visits to a) is certain, so the probability of one (or more) visits to a before hitting the origin is the same as the probability of a first visit to a before returning to the origin, namely p(1 q 1 ) = 1/(2a). Then the desired probability of 0 visits is (1 1/(2a)) = (2a 1)/(2 a). The probability of exactly one visit to a before returning to the origin is the probability of passing from the origin to a without first returning to the origin, followed by passing from a to the origin without first returning to a. This is p(1 q 1 )qq a 1 = (1/(2a))(1/(2a)) = 1/(4a 2 ). The probability of exactly two visits to a before returning to the origin is the probability of passing from the origin to a without first returning to the origin, followed by a bridge from to a to a without touching the origin, followed by passing from a to the origin without first returning to a. The middle probability is the same as the already computed probability of passing exactly 0 visits to a from the origin, by the symmetry of the situation. This is p(1 q 1 )((2a 1)/(2a))qq a 1 = (1/(2a))(1/(2a)) = 1/(4a 2 )(2a 1)/(2a). Now the pattern is clear, and we see that the number of visits to a with out first returning to the origin is a deficient geometric random variable with ratio (2a 1)/(2a). That is, the probability distribution is Pr[N = 0] = (2a 1)/(2a) Pr[N = 1] = 1/(4a 2 ) Pr[N = 2] = (1/(4a 2 ))(2a 1)/(2a) Pr[N = 3] = (1/(4a 2 ))((2a 1)/(2a)) 2 and so on The expected value of N is then E[N] = i 1 ( ) i 1 2a 1 = 1 4a 2 2a i=1 4

This is astonishing, the expected number of visits to a before returning to the origin, regardless of the value of a is 1, the same for 1 million as for 10!. 5. 6. (20 points) A gambler starts with $2 and wants to win $2 more to get to a total of $4 before being ruined by losing all his money. He plays a coin-flipping game, with a coin that changes with his fortune. (a) If the gambler has $2 he plays with a coin that gives probability p = 1/2 of winning a dollar and probability q = 1/2 of losing a dollar. (b) If the gambler has $3 he plays with a coin that gives probability p = 1/4 of winning a dollar and probability q = 3/4 of losing a dollar. (c) If the gambler has $1 he plays with a coin that gives probability p = 3/4 of winning a dollar and probability q = 1/4 of losing a dollar. Use first step analysis to write three equations in three unknowns (with two additional boundary conditions) that give the expected duration of the game that the gambler plays. Solve the equations to find the expected duration. Solution: The equations are: D 4 = 0 D 3 = 1 4 D 4 + 3 4 D 2 + 1 D 2 = 1 2 D 3 + 1 2 D 1 + 1 D 1 = 3 4 D 2 + 1 4 D 0 + 1 D 0 = 0 The solution is D 1 = 7, D 2 = 8 and D 3 = 7. 7. This problem is adapted from Stochastic Calculus and Financial Applications by J. Michael Steele, Springer, New York, 2001, Chapter 1, 5

Section 1.6, page 9. Information on buy-backs is adapted from investorwords.com. This problem suggests how results on biased random walks can be worked into more realistic models. Consider a naive model for a stock that has a support level of $20/share because of a corporate buy-back program. (This means the company will buy back stock if shares dip below $20 per share. In the case of stocks, this reduces the number of shares outstanding, giving each remaining shareholder a larger percentage ownership of the company. This is usually considered a sign that the company s management is optimistic about the future and believes that the current share price is undervalued. Reasons for buy-backs include putting unused cash to use, raising earnings per share, increasing internal control of the company, and obtaining stock for employee stock option plans or pension plans.) Suppose also that the stock price moves randomly with a downward bias when the price is above $20, and randomly with an upward bias when the price is below $20. To make the problem concrete, we let Y n denote the stock price at time n, and we express our stock support hypothesis by the assumptions that Pr[Y n+1 = 21 Y n = 20] = 9/10 Pr[Y n+1 = 19 Y n = 20] = 1/10 We then reflect the downward bias at price levels above $20 by requiring that for k > 20: Pr[Y n+1 = k + 1 Y n = k] = 1/3 Pr[Y n+1 = k 1 Y n = k] = 2/3. We then reflect the upward bias at price levels below $20 by requiring that for k < 20: Pr[Y n+1 = k + 1 Y n = k] = 2/3 Pr[Y n+1 = k 1 Y n = k] = 1/3 Using the methods of single-step analysis calculate the expected time for the stock to fall from $25 through the support level all the way down to $18. (I don t believe that there is any way to solve this problem 6

using formulas. Instead you will have to go back to basic principles of single-step or first-step analysis to solve the problem.) Solution: Here is one way to solve the problem. There are several other ways to solve the problem. The first thing to notice is that there is no natural upper boundary for this problem. In effect, the stock situation is like playing against an infinitely rich adversary. Therefore, we will set a temporary artificial boundary at 25+M, where M is some positive integer, and then at the end of the problem, we will let M go to infinity. Let D z be the duration of the game, that is, the expected number of moves until the stock goes from price 25 to price 18. Second, we note that the conditioning by expectation, or one-step analysis, give the following set of equations: D 25 = (1/3)D 26 + (2/3)D 24 + 1 D 24 = (1/3)D 25 + (2/3)D 23 + 1 D 23 = (1/3)D 24 + (2/3)D 22 + 1 D 22 = (1/3)D 23 + (2/3)D 21 + 1 D 21 = (1/3)D 22 + (2/3)D 20 + 1 D 20 = (1/10)D 19 + (9/10)D 21 + 1 D 19 = (2/3)D 20 + (1/3)D 18 + 1 D 18 = 0 The lower boundary condition says that the walk will have no duration if the walk starts at the absorbing barrier D 18. Likewise, there is another boundary condition that says that the walk will have no duration if it starts at the other artificial absorbing barrier, D 25+M = 0. Third, note that the equations have a nice sameness about them for all n > 20. This would make the equations with indices greater than 20 easy to solve with well-understood techniques if we had corresponding boundary conditions. Unfortunately the pattern does not hold for the equations for D 20, D 19 and boundary condition D 18. So what we must do is back-solve, starting at D 18, and successively eliminate D 18, and then D 19, leaving a relation between D 20 and D 21. That relation will become the new boundary condition for the regular set of equations for n > 20. Actually doing the back-solving, the new boundary condition is easily seen to be: 27D 21 + 33 = 28D 20. 7

Fourth, the general solution to the difference equation D n = (1/3)D n+1 + (2/3)D n 1 + 1 is D n = K 1 + K 2 2 n + 3n. Now substitute in the boundary conditions D 25+M = 0, and 27D 21 + 33 = 28D 20 to get two equations in the two constants K 1 and K 2. The solutions are: K 1 = 6 ( 340787200 13631488 M + 9 2 25+M )/(27262976 + 2 25+M ) K 2 = 3 (43 + M)/(27262976 + 2 25+M ). (This solution was done with Maple which accounts for the large integers in the exact solution, instead of floating point approximations.) Therefore the general solution at n = 25 is: 13631488 M + 9 225+M 43 + M 6 340787200 100663296 27262976 + 2 25+M 27262976 + 2 Finally let M go infinity, and the limiting value is: 129. So, the expected time for the stock to go from 25 through the support level and down to 18 is 129 steps. Another way to solve the problem is to let D(a, b) be the expected time to go from value a to value b. Then D(25, 18) = D(25, 20) + D(20, 19) + D(19, 18) We already have a corollary (combined with the same ideas as in Problem 1 above) that D(25, 20) = 5/(q p) = 15. Likewise, we can see that D(21, 20) = 3. Now, by a slightly different kind of first-step analysis, D(20, 19) = (1/10) 1 + (9/10)(1 + D(21, 20) + D(20, 19)). Solving, D(20, 19) = 37. In a similar fashion, D(19, 18) = (1/3) + (2/3)(1 + D(20, 19) + D(19, 18)). Solving, D(19, 18) = 77. Hence D(25, 18) = 15 + 37 + 77 = 129. 25+M +75 8

Here s yet another way to solve the problem. Set up the first-step set of equations, with some boundary conditions: D 18 = 0 D 19 = (1/3)D 18 + (2/3)D 20 + 1 D 20 = (1/3)D 19 + (2/3)D 21 + 1 D 21 = (1/3)D 20 + (2/3)D 22 + 1 D 22 = (1/3)D 21 + (2/3)D 23 + 1 D 23 = (1/3)D 22 + (2/3)D 24 + 1 D 24 = (1/3)D 23 + (2/3)D 25 + 1 D 25 = (1/3)D 24 + (2/3)D 26 + 1 D 26 = D 25 + 3 The last equation comes from the same ideas as in the previous solution. Now solve to find D 25 = 129. 9