How Does The Employer Contribution For The Federal Employees Health Benefits Program Influence Plan Selection?

Similar documents
The Health Benefits Simulation Model (HBSM): Methodology and Assumptions

M E D I C A R E I S S U E B R I E F

Gr ow th in health care costs and insurance

Value of Medicare Advantage to Low-Income and Minority Medicare Beneficiaries. By: Adam Atherly, Ph.D. and Kenneth E. Thorpe, Ph.D.

Medicare Policy ISSUE BRIEF. A 2012 Update APRIL 2012 INTRODUCTION

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

State of California. Financial Feasibility of a. Basic Health Program. June 28, Prepared with funding from the California HealthCare Foundation

VARIABLE CONTRIBUTION VS. DEFINED CONTRIBUTION SYSTEMS

Summary of Actuarial Results Valuation Methodology and Assumptions Calculation of Net OPEB Obligation... 16

In the coming months Congress will consider a number of proposals for

Medicare Program Structure

Employer Health Benefits

E x h i b i t A * *

Projected Cost Analysis of Potential Medicare Pharmacy Plan Designs. For The Society of Actuaries. July 9, Prepared by

KEY WORDS: Microsimulation, Validation, Health Care Reform, Expenditures

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

RISING HEALTH INSURANCE PREMIUMS IN TEXAS REINFORCE NEED FOR NATIONAL HEALTH REFORM

The Price Sensitivity of Medicare Beneficiaries: A Regression Discontinuity Approach

Reforming Beneficiary Cost Sharing to Improve Medicare Performance. Appendix 1: Data and Simulation Methods. Stephen Zuckerman, Ph.D.

Factors Affecting Individual Premium Rates in 2014 for California

Online Appendix to Bundorf, Levin and Mahoney Pricing and Welfare in Health Plan Choice

Committee on Ways and Means U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing on Expanding Coverage of Prescription Drugs in Medicare.

MinnesotaCare: Key Trends & Challenges

WHO BENEFITS FROM MEDICARE ADVANTAGE?

Scenario Simulation Model: Data Sources and Database Construction

Price Sensitivity in Health Care: Implications for Health Care Policy

CHAPPAQUA CENTRAL SCHOOL DISTRICT OTHER POSTEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS (OPEB) REPORTING IN ACCORDANCE WITH GASB 45 FISCAL YEAR JULY 1, 2012 TO JUNE 30, 2013

Aprimary reason for the relatively low level of health insurance

$6,438 $4,819 $1, Employer Contribution. Source: Kaiser/HRET Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Benefits,

Aquarius. C o m p a n i e s. w w w. aq u a r i u s l i f e. c o m

FACT SHEET Federal Benefits Open Season for Health Benefits, Dental and Vision Insurance and Flexible Spending Accounts

Consumer Driven Health Plans:

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Under current tax law, health insurance premiums are largely taxexempt

Designing and Regulating Health Insurance Exchanges: Lessons from Massachusetts

Employer Contribution and Premium Growth in Health Insurance

Modifying Medicare s Benefit Design:

Incremental Approaches To Covering Uninsured Children: Design And Policy Issues

Consumer-Driven Health Plans:

Nongroup insurance, also referred to as individual insurance, covers

ACA impact illustrations Individual and group medical New Jersey

Optimal Risk Adjustment. Jacob Glazer Professor Tel Aviv University. Thomas G. McGuire Professor Harvard University. Contact information:

Modeling Health Reform without the Mandate to Have Coverage. Staff Working Paper #14. John Sheils and Randall Haught

State of Maryland. Individual Market Stabilization Reinsurance Analysis. Prepared by: March 15, Wakely Consulting Group

Health Insurance (Chapters 15 and 16) Part-2

Aetna Federal Plans. Retiree Health Care Options video transcript. Your Guide to Retiree Health Care Options

CHANGING MEDICARE'S BENEFIT DESIGN: IMPLICATIONS FOR BENEFICIARIES

WebMemo22. State-Based Health Reform: A Comparison of Health Insurance Exchanges and the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program

Spending in retirement may be different than the default assumption

ASSESSING THE RESULTS

Portfolio Rebalancing:

Dual-eligible beneficiaries S E C T I O N

Abstract. Department of Economics. employer-sponsored health insurance market as a differentiated-product oligopoly

Ohio Police & Fire Pension Fund Jan. 1, 2015 Actuarial Valuation of Retiree Health Care Benefits Under GASB 43

The united states experienced an unprecedented slowdown. Trends In Out-Of-Pocket Spending By Insured American Workers,

Strategic Health Plan Options for the State of Florida. September 29, 2011

summary of benefits Blue Shield of California Medicare Rx Plan (PDP)

Public sector employers already face growing financial. How Public Sector Employers Can Manage Retiree Health Liabilities. Retirement Strategies

Alt h ough p olicyma ker s have advocated varying approaches

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

Economic Perspectives on the Advance Market Commitment for Pneumococcal Vaccines

Planning for Health Care in Retirement

Retiree Health Benefits Design Working Group

OHIO POLICE & FIRE PENSION FUND January 1, 2011 Actuarial Valuation of Retiree Health Care Benefits Under GASB 43

MetLife Retirement Income. A Survey of Pre-Retiree Knowledge of Financial Retirement Issues

Introduction Summary of Actuarial Results Change from Prior Valuation Valuation Methodology and Assumptions Data...

Raising The Medicare Eligibility Age: Effects On The Young Elderly

Retired Steelworkers and Their Health Benefits: RESULTS FROM A 2004 SURVEY

Managed care has become the dominant mode of care delivery

2018 ACA Marketplace Premiums Jonathan Keisling December 20, 2017

Postemployment Health Insurance -- Sensitivity Tests Sensitivity Analysis RETIREE PREMIUM RATE DEVELOPMENT

Health-Related Revenue Provisions in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA)

California Employer Health Benefits Survey

ISSUE BRIEF. poverty threshold ($18,769) and deep poverty if their income falls below 50 percent of the poverty threshold ($9,385).

Over the past few years numerous studies and reports

Exchanges year 2: New findings and ongoing trends

An Overview of the Medicare Part D Prescription Drug Benefit

TALKING POINTS ON HOW THE NEW HEALTH CARE REFORM LAWS AFFECT FEDERAL WORKERS AND ANNUITANTS

Substantial Premium Increases Prevalent: 2017 Health Insurance Marketplace Jonathan Keisling November 15, 2016

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

Retiree Health Benefits Now and in the Future

QUALIFIED HEALTH PLAN SELECTION: CONSIDERATIONS FOR CONSUMERS

Planning for Income to Last

20 th Annual Report on the Cost of Health Insurance in Ohio s Public Sector

THE SCHOOL DISTRICT OF WALTON COUNTY, FLORIDA

AGENDA ITEM 1 I Consent Item. California Employer s Retiree Benefit Trust Program (CERBT) funding for Other Post-Employment Benefits Funding (OPEB)

OHIO POLICE & FIRE PENSION FUND January 1, 2010 Actuarial Valuation of Retiree Health Care Benefits Under GASB 43

About two-thirds of americans who become uninsured do so when

TRANSITION GUIDE Health Insurance, Second Edition Michael A. Morrisey, PhD

Market Competition Works: Proposed Silver Premiums in the 2014 Individual and Small Group Markets Are Nearly 20% Lower than Expected

Subcommittee on Health and Human Services Government Efficiency Task Force 401 Senate Office Building April 3, :00 a.m. 11:00 a.m.

INFORMING THE DEBATE ABOUT HEALTH SAVINGS ACCOUNTS: An Examination of Some Misunderstood Issues By Edwin Park

Out-of-Pocket Health Spending by Medicare Beneficiaries Age 65 and Older: 1997 Projections

Employer Health Benefits

Any Willing Provider Legislation: A Cost Driver?

Comparison of House & Senate Health Reform Bills

Medicare Policy RAISING THE AGE OF MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY. A Fresh Look Following Implementation of Health Reform JULY 2011

Po l i c y m a k e r s a t both the federal

Transforming Medicare into a Premium Support System: Implications for Beneficiary Premiums 1

Consumer Driven Health Plans:

Transcription:

MarketWatch MarketWatch How Does The Employer Contribution For The Federal Employees Health Benefits Program Influence Plan Selection? The design of competitive health reforms involves a trade-off between controlling costs and reducing risk segmentation. by Curtis S. Florence and Kenneth E. Thorpe ABSTRACT: Market reform of health insurance is proposed to increase coverage and reduce growth in spending by providing an incentive to choose low-cost plans. However, having a choice of plans could result in risk segmentation. Risk-adjusted payments have been proposed to address risk segmentation but are criticized as ineffective. An alternative to risk adjustment is to subsidize premiums, as in the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP). Subsidizing premiums may also increase total premium spending. We find that there is little risk segmentation in the FEHBP and that reducing the premium subsidy would lower government premium spending and slightly increase risk segmentation. Competitive-market reforms have been suggested for Medicare as well as for private insurance. 1 In such proposals, people would have a choice of several competing health plans. Enrollees would pay at least part of the plan premium, so that they would have an incentive to control spending. These proposals usually involve a government subsidy of premiums, at least for low-income people. One model for such reform is the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP). This system has several features of a competitive market, since there are many health plans competing for enrollees, and the employees have the incentive to make cost-conscious choices, since they must pay more out of pocket for higher-price plans. Unlike most competitive reform proposals, however, payments to health plans are not established through competitive bids. The advantages of competitive markets are well known. The goal of market-based health insurance reform is to provide a choice of plans while holding down premium spending, through both competition among plans and cost-conscious choices by consumers. However, while the economic argument for competitive markets is straightforward and compelling for most goods and services, the effect of competition in insurance markets is sometimes ambiguous. Danger of risk segmentation. One common criticism of competitive reform is that higher-risk people will enroll in the higher-benefit, higher-premium plans, and lower-risk people will enroll in the cheaper, lower-benefit plans. Such risk segmentation Curtis Florence is an assistant professor in the Department of Health Policy and Management at the Rollins School of Public Health, Emory University, in Atlanta. Kenneth Thorpe is the Robert W. Woodruff Professor there and chair of the department. HEALTH AFFAIRS ~ Volume 22, Number 2 211 2003 Project HOPE The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.

Health Tracking is not necessarily a negative outcome, in theory, but simply means that an enrollee will be charged a premium consistent with his or her expected spending. 2 However, it can cause problems for choice-based systems when combined with certain other system characteristics. For example, in the FEHBP, plans charge the same premiums to all enrollees in a given market area (and the same premium nationwide for the national plans), there are no enrollment exclusions during the open enrollment period, and the plans have very few limitations on preexisting conditions. Under such conditions, higher-cost, higher-benefit plans may attract enrollees with higher-thanexpected spending. 3 The use of community rating can therefore result in an inefficient distribution of enrollees across plans. In addition, risk segmentation could lead to premium increases that may drive higher-benefit plans from the market, which would conflict with the increased choice goal of market-based reform. The potential for such problems has been called the possibly fatal flaw in multiple choice s potential to contain costs. 4 Controlling risk segmentation. One potential method for controlling risk segmentation is to risk-adjust a plan s premiums by the predicted cost of its enrollment pool, based on enrollees observed characteristics. Subsidizing premiums in this way can limit risk segmentation because the percent-ofpremium subsidy raises the incentive to choose higher-benefit, higher-premium plans, particularly for relatively low-risk people who would be likely not to choose those plans under a low defined-contribution subsidy. 5 Because the development of other forms of risk adjustment has been problematic, this approach may be appealing to proponents of competitive reforms. Establishing the sponsor s premium contribution to competing health plans is a key design issue. Some suggest tying the premium subsidy to the lowest-cost plan in the market. On the one hand, limiting the (defined-contribution) subsidy in this way will encourage cost-conscious plan choice and avoid the economic efficiency problems associated with moral hazard. On the other hand, in combination with community rating, it may result in risk segmentation. Absent some form of risk adjustment, selection could drive higher-cost plans out of the market and limit plans ability to compete on price. Our analysis examines this trade-off between total premium spending and risk segmentation associated with the use of premium subsidies to risk-adjust in competitive reform proposals. We examine plan selection in the FEHBP system to measure the extent of risk segmentation. We use our results to estimate how changes in the subsidy for FEHBP plans would change plan choices and the characteristics of enrollees in different plans. We address the following questions: How responsive are enrollees to differences in premiums and benefits? How do enrollees characteristics affect plan selection? Do higher-premium, higher-benefit plans experience risk segmentation? And, if so, to what extent? Structure Of The FEHBP There are ten national health plans in the FEHBP. 6 These plans charge the same premium nationwide, with the premium set by actuarial projections using claims in the prior year. The Office of Personnel Management (OPM) does not directly negotiate with the 285 (as of 1999) participating local managed care plans. Instead, these plans are allowed to participate with few restrictions, as long as the premiums they charge federal employees are not greater than those charged to other area employers with a similar number of enrollees (adjusted for demographic and benefit differences in the plans), and they offer benefits that meet the OPM s minimum standards. Employees can choose freely among the plans available in their area. Total FEHBP spending depends on the premiums charged and employees choices among plans. Each plan must provide a statutory set of benefits. Above these minimum standards, plans vary benefits in several areas, such as mental health coverage and the generosity of drug benefits. 7 Since there are no enrollment restrictions during the open enrollment period, this raises 212 March/April 2003

MarketWatch the question of how the FEHBP controls risk segmentation. Although there is no explicit system of risk adjustment, the employer contribution can act as an indirect risk adjuster. The FEHBP contributes 75 percent of the premium plan premium up to a dollar cap. Plans priced above the cap face a level-dollar premium contribution. 8 We next examine the selection effect of lowering the subsidy cap to the lowest-price plan in the market. Enrollees Plan Choices Our model of health plan choice is based on the model originally developed by Michael Spence. 9 In this model the enrollee chooses a plan that will maximize the difference between the value of insurance benefits expected and the enrollee s premium. Expected benefit payments are simply the average coinsurance rate multiplied by the expected enrollee cost. For the FEHBP, the price to the enrollee is the premium paid out of pocket. 10 Plan selection depends not only on this premium but also on expected plan payments. Enrollees choose the plan that generates the highest expected value to them. In this context, risk segmentation means that the expected cost of enrollees in different plans, controlling for benefits and plan design, is not equal. Data And Study Design Health plan choices and enrollee characteristics. Our data come from several sources. First, we use administrative data compiled by the OPM on the health plan choices of all federal employees and retirees. This file records the health plan and type of coverage (individual or family) that each employee selects. In addition, the OPM file records the employee s age, place of residence (by county, metropolitan statistical area, and state), and annual salary. Since federal retirees who are eligible for Medicare choose FEHBP plans as Medigap coverage, we excluded them from our study and focus only on active employees under age sixty-five. Since we have limited information on family size and the availability of employer coverage for the spouse, we analyze plan choices only for employees who chose individual coverage. 11 Given the large number of data records, we conducted our analysis on a 10 percent random sample of all such enrollees. Premiums and benefits. We collected data on FEHBP premiums via the OPM s Web site, www.opm.gov. Our data on plan benefits come from the Checkbook Guide, an independent publication that provides information about the different health plans in the FEHBP to assist government employees in choosing a plan during the annual open enrollment. Individual coverage. For 1996, the OPM administrative file contains records on more than 500,000 employees who selected individual coverage only. The range of possible local managed care plan choices is from one to twenty-one plans. An average of five local plans are available to FEHBP participants. About 10 percent of enrollees live in an area with no local managed care plan available. Therefore, the total number of plan choices available to FEHBP enrollees ranges from ten to thirty-one. Approximately 52 percent of individual enrollees chose a plan whose premium was above the government s subsidy cap (primarily because the most popular plan, the Blue Cross/Blue Shield standard option plan, was slightly above the cap and was the choice of 34 percent of individual enrollees). The mean difference in out-of-pocket premiums between the least and most expensive plans was approximately $1,965. Simulations of enrollment changes. We used these data to estimate a logit planchoice model, where the probability that a plan is selected is a function of the employee s premium, plan benefits, age, sex, and income. 12 We include the interaction of the premium paid by enrollees with age to examine how price-responsiveness varies with age. Absent other measures, we use age as a proxy for expected health spending and health status among government workers. Health plans experience risk segmentation if older enrollees are less sensitive to premiums than younger enrollees are, since older enrollees should have higher expected health care expenses and would be less likely to leave a plan if the premium rose relative to other plans premiums. HEALTH AFFAIRS ~ Volume 22, Number 2 213

Health Tracking We then simulated the enrollment changes that would result from changes in the employer contribution. We did this by calculating the change in the enrollee s premium paid if the employer contribution changed, and then using the parameter estimates from the plan-choice model to simulate changes in enrollment for the given out-of-pocket premium change. Our analysis does not simulate any change in overall plan premiums attributable to the reduction in the subsidy cap. This may be a realistic assumption for the local managed care plans, since the FEHBP will constitute a small percentage of their overall enrollment. However, premiums for the national plans would rise if the reduction in the premium subsidy induced risk segmentation, and their premiums would fall if the reduction in the premium subsidy increased the competitiveness of the insurance market. Therefore, our estimates of risk segmentation should be interpreted as a lower bound of the risk segmentation induced by the subsidy reduction. In presenting our simulations of changes in plan enrollment, we categorize plans based on premiums within each person s set of choices. We define a choice set as all plans that operate in the metropolitan statistical area (MSA) where the person resides. 13 If a person lives outside of an MSA, their choice set consists only of the national plans. For each person s set of choices, we report the percentage of enrollees choosing a plan in the bottom, middle, or top third of the premium distribution. We calculate government, individual, and total spending on plan premiums. Risk segmentation. We predict the mean age of persons choosing plans in each category by calculating the mean age of the enrollees in each category, weighted by the predicted probability that the plan is chosen. 14 If the FEHBP plans experience risk segmentation, we would expect the average age of enrollees to differ across plans. Specifically, if higher-benefit, higher-premium plans attract higher-risk enrollees, we would expect the predicted mean age of these enrollees to be higher than for lower-premium plans. If a reduction in the subsidy cap induces risk segmentation, we would expect the predicted average age of enrollees in the more expensive plans to rise. Data limitations. Several limitations of the data we use should be noted. First, we do not have controls for overall family structure or for the availability of coverage through a spouse. For this reason, we limit our analysis to those who chose self-only coverage. While this eliminates those who explicitly chose to cover dependents, we cannot be sure that all people in our data set faced the same choice problem. This could lead to the misspecification of our regression equation if people have access to non-fehbp coverage and the independence of irrelevant alternatives does not hold for the insurance choices they may have had through a spouse. 15 However, the FEHBP has high participation rates (approximately 89 percent of eligible employees), which suggests that non-fehbp spousal coverage is not a viable alternative for most federal employees. Second, we do not have direct control variables for the health status of the enrollee, so we cannot directly measure enrollees risk profile. However, we do include age and sex in our estimates as a proxy for health status. Study Results Sensitivity to premium changes. The premium elasticity estimates from our model are presented in Exhibit 1. 16 Results from our model of FEHBP plan choice show that enrollees are quite sensitive to changes in outof-pocket premiums. Premium elasticity for all age categories is larger than 2 (in absolute value). This indicates that for a 10 percent change in premium, there is more than a 20 percent change in plan market share, on average. This means that a plan that enrolled 30 percent of employees in a given MSA would have its market share decline below 24 percent if its premium increased by 10 percent. We also find that sensitivity to premium changes declines with age. This suggests that there is the potential for some risk segmentation in the FEHBP, since older enrollees would be less likely to change plans if their premium increased relative to other premiums. The dif- 214 March/April 2003

MarketWatch EXHIBIT 1 Premium Elasticity For Individual Enrollees In The Federal Employees Health Benefits Program, By Age Elasticity 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 20 25 26 35 36 45 46 55 56 64 SOURCE: Authors' regression estimates using FEHBP administrative data and plan benefit data from the Checkbook Guide. ferences in these effects are statistically significant, but the magnitude of the differences across age categories is small. Enrollment, cost, and age distribution. Our simulations of enrollment, cost, and age distribution under the current subsidy structure are presented in Exhibit 2. 17 In 1996 approximately 80 percent of individual-only plans received the full 75 percent premium subsidy. Therefore, the baseline case shows how a market-based system works with most of the plans being highly subsidized. The greatest share of enrollees chose a plan that was in the cheapest third of plans they had to choose from (50.8 percent), and almost 40 percent chose a plan in the middle third. An interesting result of this simulation is that the average age of enrollees across the different cost categories is similar. People who chose the most costly plans are only a little over one year older, on average, than those who chose the least expensive plans. 18 This suggests that under the current subsidy cap, the magnitude of risk segmentation in the self-only FEHBP plans is small. 19 Overall, spending on premiums for individual-only enrollees was approximately $1 billion. Of this, almost 29 percent is enrollee payments. Enrollment, cost, and age with reduced subsidy cap. Next, we simulated the change in enrollment, cost, and mean age for plans if the cap on the premium subsidy were set so that only the cheapest plan in each market received the 75 percent subsidy. Enrollees then would pay the difference between this amount and the premium for any other plan they had to choose from. This change represents an average increase in annual out-ofpocket premiums of $395. Our model predicts that the share of enrollees that chose plans in the cheapest third of their choices would increase by almost sixteen percentage points. Most of this increase is attributable to a drop in the enrollment share of the middle category (a drop of 11.4 percentage points), while a smaller proportion comes from the top third of cost (4.2 percentage points). Assuming that overall premiums remained constant, this reduction in the subsidy cap would lead to a large reduction in government premium payments, an increase in enrollees out-of-pocket premium payments, and a reduction in overall premium payments. Under the new subsidy cap, employees would pay slightly more than 44 percent of premium spending, a thirteenpercentage-point increase in the share of expenses paid by enrollees. 20 Overall premium payments (the combination of payments by the government and enrollees) would decrease by approximately 4 percent. HEALTH AFFAIRS ~ Volume 22, Number 2 215

Health Tracking EXHIBIT 2 Simulated Plan Enrollment, Premium Costs, And Age Distribution For Self-Only FEHBP Plans With Current Premium Subsidy And Subsidy Set At Least Costly Plan Current premium subsidy Premium Plan enrollment Government payments (millions) Individual payments (millions) Total (millions) Mean age Low Middle High Total 50.8% 38.3 11.0 $347 299 88 734 $119 109 68 296 $466 408 156 1,030 42.7 43.7 43.9 Subsidy set at least costly plan in market Low Middle High Total 66.3% 26.9 6.8 $366 148 37 551 $238 139 60 438 $604 287 97 988 42.7 44.3 44.7 SOURCE: Authors regression estimates using Federal Employees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP) administrative enrollment data and plan benefit data from the Checkbook Guide. Change in risk segmentation. While the reduced subsidy cap would decrease premium payments for the government, there would also be an increase in risk segmentation for plans in the middle- and high-cost categories. For plans in the high-cost category, the age of the average enrollee would increase by almost one year; for plans in the middle-cost category, it would increase slightly more than a half-year. The average age of enrollees in the low-cost categories would be essentially unchanged (because the age of people who enter this category at the margin is approximately the average age of the low-cost category). This small increase in risk segmentation demonstrates how a proportional subsidy acts as an indirect risk-adjustment mechanism. When the share of the plan premium paid by the enrollee (relative to the lowest-premium plan) is increased, risk segmentation increases. However, given the small difference in premium-sensitivity across age groups, the magnitude of the risk segmentation is small. This also shows that the cost simulations may slightly overstate the reduction in total premium payments if this segmentation leads to an increase in overall premiums for the plans in the middle- and high-cost categories. Implications For Policy One of the goals of developing a choicebased system to reform Medicare or private insurance is to hold down overall health care spending while minimizing risk segmentation for health plans. In general, premium subsidies that cover a higher percentage of the plan premium help to induce lower-risk people to select more expensive plans. However, higher premium subsidies conflict with the goal of reduced total premium spending. The trade-off between subsidy levels and plan selection is an important factor in developing effective programs to encourage health insurance coverage. In our simulations of the selection and enrollment effects of different subsidy caps, we find that, overall, there is not a great deal of risk segmentation in the FEHBP under the current subsidy cap. The current cap is set at approximately the eightieth percentile of all self-only plan premiums, so most plans in the program receive the full 75 percent premium subsidy. Our policy simulations show that the government could greatly reduce its FEHBP premium spending if it lowered the cap to cover only the least costly plan in each market. However, such a subsidy change would raise the age of the enrollee pool for the more costly plans. We estimate only a small increase in av- 216 March/April 2003

MarketWatch erage enrollee age for these plans. This suggests that the government could greatly decrease the cap of the premium subsidy without inducing severe risk segmentation. However, our results must be understood with the caveat that we are not modeling the change in overall plan premiums that would occur as the plan risk pool or the competitiveness of the market changes. If the decrease in the cap leaves some plans with higher average risk in their enrollment pool, their premiums will increase, and this could lead to a further shift in enrollment toward higher risk and more risk segmentation than we are simulating. An increase in the competitiveness of the health insurance market would lower the total premium charged by all plans. One recent area of market-based reform based on the FEHBP model is proposals for tax credits that would subsidize the purchase of health plans by the uninsured who do not have access to employer-sponsored coverage. Our results suggest that a tax credit that covers a substantial share (or in some cases all) of the plan premium would likely lead to limited risk segmentation for health plans in a system managed as the FEHBP is. Since a large subsidy would be required to induce eligible people to participate, risk segmentation by health plans may not be a major concern where a large number of plans of various types compete for enrollees, given the FEHBP experience. 21 However, we did not estimate the effects of premium subsidies on the uninsured population. If the plan selection of people in that population is different from that of FEHBP participants, our results may not accurately predict the risk segmentation that could occur. The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the Heritage Foundation and the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation under its Changes in Health Care Financing and Organization (HCFO) initiative. They thank Walton Francis for providing the information on plan benefits and acknowledge the thoughtful comments of two anonymous reviewers. NOTES 1. For a discussion of plan choice in Medicare, see G. Wilensky and J. Newhouse, Medicare: What s Right? What s Wrong? What s Next? Health Affairs (Jan/Feb 1999): 92 106; for private insurance, see S.M. Butler, The Conservative Agenda for Incremental Reform, Health Affairs (Spring 1995): 150 160. 2. R. Feldman and B. Dowd, Risk Segmentation: Goal or Problem? Journal of Health Economics (July 2000): 499 512. 3. M. Rothschild and J. Stiglitz, Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay in the Economics of Imperfect Information, Quarterly Journal of Economics (November 1976): 629 649. Even if plans had perfect information concerning potential enrollees, community rating would still generate some risk segmentation. 4. S. Jones, Can Multiple Choice Be Managed to Constrain Health Care Costs? Health Affairs (Fall 1989): 51 59; and J. Robinson et al., A Method for Risk-Adjusting Employer Contributions to Competing Health Plans, Inquiry (Summer 1991): 107 116. 5. See T. Selden, Premium Subsidies for Health Insurance: Excessive Coverage versus Adverse Selection, Journal of Health Economics (December 1999): 709 725. 6. Five other nationally available plans are open only to certain groups, such as the Secret Service plan. We do not include these plans here. 7. Of course, one approach for managing selection within the FEHBP is to limit the variation in plan benefits (generosity). While the OPM does indeed try to compress the variation in plan generosity, the plans do differ greatly with respect to copayments and coverage of mental health and dental services and prescription drugs. 8. The 75 percent government premium payment applies to nonpostal, general service employees. Postal employees receive a higher premium subsidy with a higher maximum. Since we simulate the effect of changes in the subsidy cap, we focus on only general service employees. 9. M. Spence, Product Differentiation and Performance in Insurance Markets, Journal of Public Economics (December 1978): 427 447. The Spence model takes each enrollee s health spending as given. 10. While the overall cost of insurance in the long run will theoretically be borne by the enrollee in the form of reduced wages, the marginal cost of the plan choice to the enrollee is the annual outof-pocket premium. 11. Individual-coverage enrollees are slightly younger than family-coverage enrollees are (43.5 years HEALTH AFFAIRS ~ Volume 22, Number 2 217

Health Tracking versus 44.7 years) and are less likely to be male (44.9 percent for individual, compared with 66.8 percent for family enrollees). 12. A well-known feature of the conditional logit model is that it assumes the independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). That is, plans are assumed to be perfect substitutes, conditional on the plan characteristics controlled for in the model. We conducted a specification test on our model and found that it violated the IIA assumption. A typical way to relax this assumption is to estimate a nested logit model, where the nests are defined by the ability of enrollees to choose their own physician. See R. Feldman et al., The Demand for Employment-Based Health Insurance, Journal of Human Resources (Winter 1989): 115 142. We attempted a similar approach here but found that the nested logit model did not meet the IIA criteria within nests. Given the large number of choices in the model, other alternatives such as the multinomial probit are not computationally feasible. However, the effect of violating the IIA assumption is that the model underestimates the probability that a given choice will be made relative to any alternative. T. Amemiya, Advanced Econometrics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1985), 298. Therefore, our estimates can be interpreted as being a lower-bound measure of premium-sensitivity in the FEHBP. 13. In the FEHBP, employees can enroll in the local plans if they either live or work in a list of counties that are provided in the plan brochure. These lists typically comprise the counties that are included in the Census Bureau s definition of an MSA. 14. Expected spending and age means are calculated by using the predicted probability of choosing each plan as a weight in calculated a weighted average of the statistic in question. 15. Feldman et al., The Demand for Employment- Based Health Insurance. 16. Full regression results are available from the authors. Contact Ken Thorpe, Kthorpe@sph. emory.edu. 17. We report the predicted enrollment, cost, and age distribution from the model in order to have a consistent comparison for the simulated subsidy cap changes. The regression model predicts a slightly higher percentage of people choosing plans in the low- and high-premium categories than is observed in the raw data. However, the age distributions by category are very close to the same as those predicted by the model. 18. Our simulations slightly overestimate the share of enrollees that chose a plan in the top and bottom tier of premiums and understate the share in the middle. In the raw data, 48.2 percent chose a plan in the lowest third of premiums; 43.4 percent, in the middle third; and 8.3 percent in the top third. Our simulated average ages are similar to those in the raw data for the bottom and middle tiers (42.9 and 43.8 years, respectively). The simulations slightly understate the average age in the highest premium tier (44.4 years in the raw data). 19. To verify our simulated enrollment changes, we also performed the same analysis on people who chose family plans in the FEHBP. The subsidy cap for such plans is considerably lower in the distribution of plan premiums than it is for selfonly plans (approximately the twentieth percentile of the distribution of all premiums). We found that even with a subsidy cap that is much lower in the distribution of premiums, there is little selection by age in family plans as well. The mean age of family plan enrollees in the low-cost category is 45 years; the middle category, 44.2 years; and the high-cost category, 44.2 years. 20. In a competitive labor market, such an increase in employee health insurance premiums would need to be offset by an increase in wages. 21. Estimates of the size of tax subsidy that would be required for purchasing insurance can be found in J. Gruber, Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance: Evaluating Costs and Benefits, NBER Working Paper no. w7553 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, February 2000); and K. Thorpe, Incremental Approaches to Covering Uninsured Children: Design and Policy Issues, Health Affairs (July/Aug 1997): 64 78. 218 March/April 2003