Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 3: Markowitz Portfolios

Similar documents
Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Portfolio Models 3. Markowitz Portfolios

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward II: Markowitz Portfolios

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 10: Limited Portfolios with Risk-Free Assets

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Portfolio Models 9. Long Portfolios with a Safe Investment

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Return I: Introduction

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Portfolio Models 1. Risk and Reward

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 1: Risk and Reward

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Optimization II: Model-Based Portfolio Management

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Stochastic Models I: One Risky Asset

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward I: Introduction

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Portfolio Models 1. Risk and Reward

Modeling Portfolios Containing Risky Assets

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 12 Growth Rate Mean and Variance Estimators

Mathematics in Finance

The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization

Markowitz portfolio theory

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is:

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions, Modern Portfolio Theory

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 00: Course Logistics Introduction to Finance Optimization Problems

Portfolio Sharpening

Session 8: The Markowitz problem p. 1

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

SDMR Finance (2) Olivier Brandouy. University of Paris 1, Panthéon-Sorbonne, IAE (Sorbonne Graduate Business School)

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory

Quantitative Portfolio Theory & Performance Analysis

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

P2.T8. Risk Management & Investment Management. Jorion, Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk, 3rd Edition.

The Markowitz framework

How quantitative methods influence and shape finance industry

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447. Midterm Review. Dr. Ted Ralphs

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Econ 424/CFRM 462 Portfolio Risk Budgeting

FINC3017: Investment and Portfolio Management

ORF 307: Lecture 3. Linear Programming: Chapter 13, Section 1 Portfolio Optimization. Robert Vanderbei. February 13, 2016

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

An Introduction to Resampled Efficiency

Economics 424/Applied Mathematics 540. Final Exam Solutions

Mean-Variance Portfolio Choice in Excel

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

International Financial Markets 1. How Capital Markets Work

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 07: Portfolio Optimization

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

An Analysis of Theories on Stock Returns

Characterization of the Optimum

Probability and Stochastics for finance-ii Prof. Joydeep Dutta Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur

Black-Litterman Model

P2.T5. Market Risk Measurement & Management. Bruce Tuckman, Fixed Income Securities, 3rd Edition

Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301

Risk and Return and Portfolio Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Key investment insights

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

Portfolio Optimization with Alternative Risk Measures

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 12 Jul 2012

8 th International Scientific Conference

Financial Analysis The Price of Risk. Skema Business School. Portfolio Management 1.

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Markowitz portfolio theory. May 4, 2017

EQUITY RESEARCH AND PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT

Non replication of options

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Fiduciary Insights LEVERAGING PORTFOLIOS EFFICIENTLY

Modern Portfolio Theory -Markowitz Model

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1

ORF 307 Lecture 3. Chapter 13, Section 1 Portfolio Optimization

The University of Sydney School of Mathematics and Statistics. Computer Project

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

6. Martingales. = Zn. Think of Z n+1 as being a gambler s earnings after n+1 games. If the game if fair, then E [ Z n+1 Z n

21 MATHEMATICAL MODELLING

Predictability of Stock Returns

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Theoretical Aspects Concerning the Use of the Markowitz Model in the Management of Financial Instruments Portfolios

RESEARCH GROUP ADDRESSING INVESTMENT GOALS USING ASSET ALLOCATION

Portfolio Theory and Diversification

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

MATH 4512 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance

Math 5760/6890 Introduction to Mathematical Finance

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Alternative VaR Models

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Transcription:

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 3: Markowitz Portfolios C. David Levermore University of Maryland, College Park, MD Math 42: Mathematical Modeling March 21, 218 version c 218 Charles David Levermore

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Part I: Portfolio Models 1. Risk and Reward 2. Covariance Matrices 3. Markowitz Portfolios 4. Solvent Portfolios 5. Limited Portfolios 6. Markowitz Frontiers for Unlimited Portfolios 7. Markowitz Frontiers for Long Portfolios 8. Markowitz Frontiers for Limited Portfolios 9. Unlimited Portfolios with Risk-Free Assets 1. Limited Portfolios with Risk-Free Assets

Markowitz Portfolios 1 Portfolios 2 Portfolio Returns 3 Portfolio Statistics 4 Long Portfolios 5 Critique

Portfolios We will consider portfolios in which an investor can hold one of three positions with respect to any risky asset. The investor can: hold a long position by owning shares of the asset; hold a short position by selling borrowed shares of the asset; hold a neutral position by doing neither of the above. In order to keep things simple, we will not consider derivative assets. Remark. We hold a short position by borrowing shares of an asset from a lender (usually our broker) and selling them immediately. If the share price subsequently goes down then we can buy the same number of shares and give them to the lender, thereby paying off our loan and profiting by the price difference minus transaction costs. Of course, if the price goes up then our lender can force us either to increase our collateral or to pay off the loan by buying shares at this higher price, thereby taking a loss that might be larger than the original value of the shares. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolios We will consider portfolios that hold n i (d) shares of asset i throughout trading day d. If we hold a long position in asset i on day d then n i (d) >. If we hold a short position in asset i on day d then n i (d) <. If we hold a neutral position in asset i on day d then n i (d) =. The value of such a portfolio at the end of trading day d is The return of such a portfolio for trading day d is r(d) = N π(d) = n i (d) s i (d). (1.1) π(d) π(d) π(d 1) 1 =, (1.2) π(d 1) π(d 1) where we assume that π(d 1) > for every d. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolios Such a portfolio is called self-financing if {n i (d)} N satisfies N π(d 1) = n i (d) s i (d 1) for every d. (1.3) This is an idealization that neglects trading costs and assumes that the opening price for a share of asset i on day d is s i (d 1). If a portfolio is self-financing then by using (1.1) and (1.3) in (1.2) we see that its return for trading day d is r(d) = N n i (d) ( si (d) s i (d 1) ). (1.4) π(d 1) C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolios A 1952 paper by Harry Markowitz had enormous influence on the theory and practice of portfolio management and financial engineering ever since. It presented his doctoral dissertation work at the Unversity of Chicago, for which he was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 199. It was the first work to quantify how diversifying a portfolio can reduce its risk without changing its potential reward. It did this because it was the first work to use the covariance between different assets in an essential way. The key to carrying out this work was modeling. The first modeling step was to develop a class of idealized portfolios that is simple enough to analyze, yet is rich enough to yield useful results. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolios Markowitz carried out his analysis on a class of idealized portfolios that are each characterized by a set of real numbers {f i } N that satisfy N f i = 1. (1.5) The portfolio picks n i (d) at the beginning at each trading day d so that n i (d)s i (d 1) π(d 1) = f i, (1.6) where n i (d) need not be an integer. We call these Markowitz portfolios. The number f i is called the allocation of asset i. It uniquely determines n i (d) at the start of each trading day. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolios Specifically, at the start of trading day d we determine {n i (d)} N from (1.6) as n i (d) = f i π(d 1) s i (d 1). (1.7) We see that for so long as π(d 1) > and s i (d 1) > the portfolio holds a long position in asset i if f i >, holds a short position in asset i if f i <, holds a neutral position in asset i if f i =. Remark. If every f i is nonnegative then f i is the fraction of the portfolio s value held in asset i at the start of each day. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolio Returns Because by (1.5) the allocations {f i } N sum to 1, it follows from (1.6) that every Markowitz portfolio satifies (1.3) and thereby is self-financing. Because Markowitz portfolios are self-financing, it follows from (1.4) and relationship (1.6) between n i (d) and f i that the return r(d) of a Markowitz portfolio for trading day d is r(d) = N n i (d)s i (d 1) π(d 1) s i (d) s i (d 1) s i (d 1) N = f i r i (d). (2.8) The return r(d) for the Markowitz portfolio characterized by {f i } N is thereby simply the linear combination of the r i (d) with the coefficients f i. This relationship makes the class of Markowitz portfolios easy to analyze. It is the reason we will use Markowitz portfolios to model real portfolios. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolio Returns Relationship (2.8) can be expressed in the compact form where f and r(d) are the N-vectors defined by f = f 1. f N r(d) = f T r(d), (2.9), r(d) = r 1 (d).. r N (d) We call f the allocation vector or simply the allocation. The constraint (1.5) can be expressed in the compact form 1 T f = 1, (2.1) where 1 denotes the N-vector with each entry equal to 1. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolio Statistics Recall that if we assign weights {w(d)} D d=1 to the trading days of a daily return history {r(d)} D d=1 then the N-vector of return means m and the N N-matrix of return covariances V can be expressed in terms of r(d) as m = m 1. = m N v 11 v 1N V =..... v N1 v NN = D w(d) r(d), d=1 D w(d) ( r(d) m ) ( r(d) m ) T. d=1 The choices of the daily return history {r(d)} D d=1 and weights {w(d)}d d=1 specify the calibration of our models. Ideally m and V should not be overly sensitive to these choices. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolio Statistics Because r(d) = f T r(d), the portfolio return mean µ for the Markowitz portfolio with allocation f is then given by Hence, µ = f T m. µ = D w(d) r(d) = D w(d) f T r(d) d=1 d=1 ( D ) = f T w(d) r(d) = f T m. d=1 C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolio Statistics Because r(d) = f T r(d), the portfolio return variance v for the Markowitz portfolio with allocation f are then given by v = = D w(d) ( r(d) µ ) 2 D = w(d) ( f T r(d) f T m ) 2 d=1 D d=1 = f T ( D d=1 w(d) ( f T r(d) f T m )( r(d) T f m T f ) d=1 w(d) ( r(d) m )( r(d) m ) ) T f = f T Vf. Hence, v = f T Vf. Because V is positive definite, v >. Remark. These simple formulas for µ and v are the reason that returns are preferred over growth rates when compiling statistics of markets. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Portfolio Statistics Remark. This simplicity arises because f is independent of d and because the return r(d) for the Markowitz portfolio with allocation f depends linearly upon the vector r(d) of returns as r(d) = f T r(d). In contrast, the growth rates x(d) of a Markowitz portfolio are given by ( ) π(d) x(d) = log = log ( 1 + r(d) ) π(d 1) ( ) ( ) N = log 1 + f T r(d) = log 1 + f i r i (d) ( = log N 1 + f i (e x i (d) 1) ) ( N = log f i e x i (d) Because the x(d) are not linear functions of the x i (d), averages of x(d) over d are not simply expressed in terms of averages of x i (d) over d. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218 ).

Long Portfolios Because the value of any portfolio with short positions can become negative, many investors will not hold a short position in any risky asset. Portfolios that hold no short positions are called long portfolios. A Markowitz portfolio with allocation f is long if and only if f i for every i. This can be expressed compactly as f, (4.11) where denotes the N-vector with each entry equal to and the inequality is understood entrywise. Therefore the set of all long Markowitz portfolio allocations Λ is given by Λ = { f R N : 1 T f = 1, f }. (4.12) C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Long Portfolios Let e i denote the vector whose i th entry is 1 while every other entry is. For every f Λ we have N f = f i e i, where f i for every i = 1,, N and N f i = 1 T f = 1. This shows that Λ is simply all convex combinations of the vectors {e i } N. We can visualize Λ when N is small. When N = 2 it is the line segment that connects the unit vectors ( ) ( ) 1 e 1 =, e 2 =. 1 C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Long Portfolios When N = 3 it is the triangle that connects the unit vectors e 1 = 1, e 2 = 1, e 3 = 1. When N = 4 it is the tetrahedron that connects the unit vectors e 1 = 1, e 2 = 1, e 3 = 1, e 4 = 1. For general N it is the simplex that connects the unit vectors {e i } N. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Critique Aspects of Markowitz portfolios are unrealistic. These include: the fact portfolios can contain fractional shares of any asset; the fact portfolios are rebalanced every trading day; the fact transaction costs and taxes are neglected; the fact dividends are neglected. By making these simplifications the subsequent analysis becomes easier. The idea is to find the Markowitz portfolio that is best for a given investor. The expectation is that any real portfolio with an allocation close to that for the optimal Markowitz portfolio will perform nearly as well. Consequently, most investors rebalance at most a few times per year, and not every asset is involved each time. Transaction costs and taxes are thereby limited. Similarly, borrowing costs are kept to a minimum by not borrowing often. The model can be modified to account for dividends. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218

Critique Remark. Portfolios of risky assets can be designed for trading or investing. Traders often take positions that require constant attention. They might buy and sell assets on short time scales in an attempt to profit from market fluctuations. They might also take highly leveraged positions that expose them to enormous gains or loses depending how the market moves. They must be ready to handle margin calls. Trading is often a full time job. Investors operate on longer time scales. They buy or sell an asset based on their assessment of its fundamental value over time. Investing does not have to be a full time job. Indeed, most people who hold risky assets are investors who are saving for retirement. Lured by the promise of high returns, sometimes investors will buy shares in funds designed for traders. At that point they have become gamblers, whether they realize it or not. The ideas presented in this course are designed to balance investment portfolios, not trading portfolios. C. David Levermore (UMD) Markowitz Portfolios March 21, 218