Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Similar documents
Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Non-semimartingales in finance

Fractional Brownian Motion as a Model in Finance

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Fractional Brownian Motion as a Model in Finance

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON ARBITRAGE BY CHANGING THE STOCK EXCHANGE

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

King s College London

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

The Black-Scholes Model

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

The Black-Scholes Model

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

King s College London

Lévy models in finance

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Risk Neutral Valuation

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Option Pricing Models for European Options

S t d with probability (1 p), where

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

CRRAO Advanced Institute of Mathematics, Statistics and Computer Science (AIMSCS) Research Report. B. L. S. Prakasa Rao

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Hedging under Arbitrage

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Path Dependent British Options

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

The Black-Scholes Model

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Slides for Risk Management Credit Risk

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

The stochastic calculus

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

VII. Incomplete Markets. Tomas Björk

Risk Neutral Measures

Enlargement of filtration

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

The mathematical finance of Quants and backward stochastic differential equations

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

A Worst-Case Approach to Option Pricing in Crash-Threatened Markets

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

Hedging under arbitrage

MAS452/MAS6052. MAS452/MAS Turn Over SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS. Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

The British Russian Option

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Monte Carlo Simulations

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Computational Finance

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Recent Advances in Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models

Transcription:

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Matematiikan päivät, Tampere, 4-5. January 2006 Tommi Sottinen University of Helsinki 4.1.2006

Outline 1. The classical pricing model: Black & Scholes model.

Outline 1. The classical pricing model: Black & Scholes model. 2. Geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model.

Outline 1. The classical pricing model: Black & Scholes model. 2. Geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model. 3. Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion?

Outline 1. The classical pricing model: Black & Scholes model. 2. Geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model. 3. Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? 4. Mixed fractional Brownian motion.

Outline 1. The classical pricing model: Black & Scholes model. 2. Geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model. 3. Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? 4. Mixed fractional Brownian motion. 5. Replication and arbitrage in non-semimartingale models. [Joint work with C. Bender, WIAS, Berlin;and E. Valkeila, Helsinki University of Technology.] This is the part with new results.

Outline 1. The classical pricing model: Black & Scholes model. 2. Geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model. 3. Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? 4. Mixed fractional Brownian motion. 5. Replication and arbitrage in non-semimartingale models. [Joint work with C. Bender, WIAS, Berlin;and E. Valkeila, Helsinki University of Technology.] This is the part with new results. 6. Closing remarks.

The basic pricing model: Black & Scholes model The riskless bond has dynamics db t = rb t dt, B 0 = 1; and the risky stock has dynamics ds t = S t (µdt + σdw t ), S 0 = s > 0. Here r is the short rate, σ is the volatility parameter, µ is the growth rate, and W is a Brownian motion.

The basic pricing model: Black & Scholes model The riskless bond has dynamics db t = rb t dt, B 0 = 1; and the risky stock has dynamics ds t = S t (µdt + σdw t ), S 0 = s > 0. Here r is the short rate, σ is the volatility parameter, µ is the growth rate, and W is a Brownian motion. The option f (S T ) has price v f v f = e rt E Q [f (S T )]; here Q is the equivalent martingale measure.

The basic pricing model: Black & Scholes model The replication price is the same as the risk neutral price v f : f (S T ) = V T (Φ, v f ; S) = v f + T 0 Ψ s db s + T 0 Φ s ds s.

The basic pricing model: Black & Scholes model The replication price is the same as the risk neutral price v f : f (S T ) = V T (Φ, v f ; S) = v f + T 0 Ψ s db s + T The self-financing hedge Φ is obtained from 0 Φ s ds s. by Φ t (S t ) = C x (t, S t ). C(t, x) = e r(t t) E Q [f (S T ) F S t ] St=x

The basic pricing model: Black & Scholes model The replication price is the same as the risk neutral price v f : f (S T ) = V T (Φ, v f ; S) = v f + T 0 Ψ s db s + T The self-financing hedge Φ is obtained from 0 Φ s ds s. by Φ t (S t ) = C x (t, S t ). C(t, x) = e r(t t) E Q [f (S T ) F S t ] St=x Properties of the Black & Scholes model: log-returns are independent. log-returns are Gaussian.

Geometric fractional Brownian motion To model dependence of the log-returns we could use fractional Brownian motion B H. It is a continuous Gaussian process with mean zero and covariance E[B H t B H s ] = 1 2 (t2h + s 2H t s 2H ).

Geometric fractional Brownian motion To model dependence of the log-returns we could use fractional Brownian motion B H. It is a continuous Gaussian process with mean zero and covariance E[B H t B H s ] = 1 2 (t2h + s 2H t s 2H ). The paratemeter H is the self-similarity index: for a > 0 Law(B H a P) = Law(a H B H P).

Geometric fractional Brownian motion To model dependence of the log-returns we could use fractional Brownian motion B H. It is a continuous Gaussian process with mean zero and covariance E[B H t B H s ] = 1 2 (t2h + s 2H t s 2H ). The paratemeter H is the self-similarity index: for a > 0 Law(B H a P) = Law(a H B H P). Brownian motion W is a special case of fractional Brownian motion B H with the parameter value H = 1 2.

Geometric fractional Brownian motion Fractional Brownian motion is not a semimartingale, but one can show for H > 1 2 the stochastic differential equation has the solution ds t = S t (µdt + σdb H t ), S 0 = s S t = s exp{µt + σb H t }.

Geometric fractional Brownian motion Fractional Brownian motion is not a semimartingale, but one can show for H > 1 2 the stochastic differential equation has the solution ds t = S t (µdt + σdb H t ), S 0 = s S t = s exp{µt + σb H t }. Empirical studies of several financial time series have shown that H 0.6.

Geometric fractional Brownian motion Fractional Brownian motion is not a semimartingale, but one can show for H > 1 2 the stochastic differential equation has the solution ds t = S t (µdt + σdb H t ), S 0 = s S t = s exp{µt + σb H t }. Empirical studies of several financial time series have shown that H 0.6. For H > 1 2 the increments of BH are positively correlated.

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The main axiom in mathematical finance is the absense of arbitrage opportunities (no free lunch, no profit without risk).

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The main axiom in mathematical finance is the absense of arbitrage opportunities (no free lunch, no profit without risk). The fundamental theorem of asset pricing states that no-arbitrage means existence of an equivalent martingale measure. So, non-semimartingales are ruled out as models for stock.

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The main axiom in mathematical finance is the absense of arbitrage opportunities (no free lunch, no profit without risk). The fundamental theorem of asset pricing states that no-arbitrage means existence of an equivalent martingale measure. So, non-semimartingales are ruled out as models for stock. Fractional Brownian motion is not a semimartingale. Therefore, the geometric fractional Browanian motion is not a semimartingale.

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The main axiom in mathematical finance is the absense of arbitrage opportunities (no free lunch, no profit without risk). The fundamental theorem of asset pricing states that no-arbitrage means existence of an equivalent martingale measure. So, non-semimartingales are ruled out as models for stock. Fractional Brownian motion is not a semimartingale. Therefore, the geometric fractional Browanian motion is not a semimartingale. Explicit arbitrage examples with geometric fractional Brownian motion are given by Dasgupta & Kallianpur and Shiryaev with continuous time trading. In the context of discrete time trading arbitrage is discussed in the Ph.D. thesis of Cheridito.

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The arbitrage possibilities seem to rule out geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model in stochastic finance.

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The arbitrage possibilities seem to rule out geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model in stochastic finance. Mathematically the arbitrage depends on the special stochastic integrals one is using to understand the self-financing (discounted) wealth t V t (Φ, v 0 ; S) = v 0 + Φ s ds s. 0

Why not geometric fractional Brownian motion? The arbitrage possibilities seem to rule out geometric fractional Brownian motion as a pricing model in stochastic finance. Mathematically the arbitrage depends on the special stochastic integrals one is using to understand the self-financing (discounted) wealth t V t (Φ, v 0 ; S) = v 0 + Φ s ds s. 0 Most arbitrage opportunities are based on Riemann-Stieltjes type of understanding of the stochastic integrals. Several authors suggested that one should use divergence [Skorohod] integrals to avoid arbitrage possibilities. However, to give an economical meaning to divergence integrals is difficult, or even impossible.

Mixed fractional Brownian motion Consider X = W + B H, where W and B H are independent. Then X is not a semimartingale with respect to F W F BH ; The quadratic variation of X is the same as the quadratic variation of W ; X is a semimartingale with respect to F X, if and only if H > 3 4 [Cheridito].

Mixed fractional Brownian motion Consider X = W + B H, where W and B H are independent. Then X is not a semimartingale with respect to F W F BH ; The quadratic variation of X is the same as the quadratic variation of W ; X is a semimartingale with respect to F X, if and only if H > 3 4 [Cheridito]. The existence of quadratic variation implies that F (t, X t ) = F (0, 0) + + 1 2 t 0 t 0 F t (s, X s )ds + F xx (s, X s )ds. t The integral is defined as a limit of forward sums. 0 F x (s, X s )dx s

Mixed fractional Brownian motion Consider X = W + B H, where W and B H are independent. Then X is not a semimartingale with respect to F W F BH ; The quadratic variation of X is the same as the quadratic variation of W ; X is a semimartingale with respect to F X, if and only if H > 3 4 [Cheridito]. The existence of quadratic variation implies that F (t, X t ) = F (0, 0) + + 1 2 t 0 t 0 F t (s, X s )ds + F xx (s, X s )ds. t 0 F x (s, X s )dx s The integral is defined as a limit of forward sums. Consider now the mixed process X as the source of the randomness: ds t = S t (µdt + σdx t ) and hence S t = s exp{σx t + µt 1 2 σ2 t}.

Mixed fractional Brownian motion We can now repeat the replication arguments in the classical Black & Scholes model using the PDE approach and we obtain the surprising fact that the replication price in this mixed model is the same as the replication price in the classical Black & Scholes model! This was first observed by Kloeden and Schoenmakers.

Mixed fractional Brownian motion We can now repeat the replication arguments in the classical Black & Scholes model using the PDE approach and we obtain the surprising fact that the replication price in this mixed model is the same as the replication price in the classical Black & Scholes model! This was first observed by Kloeden and Schoenmakers. So there seems to be a paradox here: if H 3 4 for the fractional component B H there are arbitrage possibilities, but the replication price with continuous trading is the same as in the classical Black & Scholes model.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Market model A discounted market model is a five-tuple (Ω, F, S, F, P) such that (Ω, F, F, P) is a filtered probability space satisfying the usual conditions and S = (S t ) 0 t T is an F t -progressively measurable positive quadratic variation process with continuous paths starting at s R. The constants T and s are fixed. We assume that our model has the following property: given any nonnegative continuous function η with η(0) = s and any ɛ > 0 P({ω; S(ω) η < ɛ}) > 0 (1)

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Model class Given a continuous positive function σ(t, x) we define a model class by M σ = { (Ω, F, S, F, P); (Ω, F, S, F, P) is a discounted market model satisfying (1) and d S t = σ(t, S t )dt P a.s. } We will also restrict the possible strategies. In the classical Black & Scholes pricing model the only restriction to strategies is the fact that we do not allow doubling strategies. Here we will restrict more. But we shall still have enough strategies to hedge all practically relevant options.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Allowed strategies g : [0, T ] C s,+ ([0, T ]) R is a hindsight factor if 1. for every 0 t T g(t, η) = g(t, η) whenever η(u) = η(u) for all 0 u t;

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Allowed strategies g : [0, T ] C s,+ ([0, T ]) R is a hindsight factor if 1. for every 0 t T g(t, η) = g(t, η) whenever η(u) = η(u) for all 0 u t; 2. g(t; η) is of bounded variation and continuous as a function in t for every η C s,+ ([0, T ]) ;

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Allowed strategies g : [0, T ] C s,+ ([0, T ]) R is a hindsight factor if 1. for every 0 t T g(t, η) = g(t, η) whenever η(u) = η(u) for all 0 u t; 2. g(t; η) is of bounded variation and continuous as a function in t for every η C s,+ ([0, T ]) ; 3. t 0 t f (u)dg(u, η) 0 f (u)dg(u, η) K max f (r) η η 0 r t (2)

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Allowed strategies g : [0, T ] C s,+ ([0, T ]) R is a hindsight factor if 1. for every 0 t T g(t, η) = g(t, η) whenever η(u) = η(u) for all 0 u t; 2. g(t; η) is of bounded variation and continuous as a function in t for every η C s,+ ([0, T ]) ; 3. t 0 t f (u)dg(u, η) 0 f (u)dg(u, η) K max f (r) η η 0 r t (2) E.g. the running maximum, minimum, and average of the stock prices are hindsight factors.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Allowed strategies Suppose hindsight factors g 1,..., g m and a function ϕ : [0, T ] R + R m R are given. We shall consider strategies of the form Φ t = ϕ(t, S t, g 1 (t, S),..., g m (t, S)). (3) Here Φ t denotes the number of stocks held by an investor. Hence, the wealth process corresponding to the strategy Φ is t V t (Φ, v 0 ; S) = v 0 + Φ s ds s (4) 0 where v 0 R denotes the investor s initial capital. Recall that the stochastic integral is defined as a limit of forward sums.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Allowed strategies Next we have to specify conditions on ϕ. We first state a result on absence of arbitrage under the smoothness condition ϕ C 1 ([0, T ] R + R m ). Φ is supposed to be nds-admissible in the classical sense, i.e. there is a constant a > 0 such that for all 0 t T t 0 Φ u ds u a; P a.s. A strategy fulfilling these conditions is called a smooth allowed strategy.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Smooth no-arbitrage theorem Let (Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ and suppose Φ smooth allowed.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Smooth no-arbitrage theorem Let (Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ and suppose Φ smooth allowed. Then Φ cannot be an arbitrage in the model (Ω, F, S, F, P) provided one model ( Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ admits an equivalent local martingale measure.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Smooth no-arbitrage theorem Let (Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ and suppose Φ smooth allowed. Then Φ cannot be an arbitrage in the model (Ω, F, S, F, P) provided one model ( Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ admits an equivalent local martingale measure. For example, the model, where the mixed process X = W + B H is the driving process, and H ( 1 2, 1) does not admit arbitrage with allowed smooth strategies.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Smooth no-arbitrage theorem Let (Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ and suppose Φ smooth allowed. Then Φ cannot be an arbitrage in the model (Ω, F, S, F, P) provided one model ( Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ admits an equivalent local martingale measure. For example, the model, where the mixed process X = W + B H is the driving process, and H ( 1 2, 1) does not admit arbitrage with allowed smooth strategies. It is known, however, in the classical Black-Scholes model that the smoothness condition ϕ C 1 ([0, T ] R + R m ) is too restrictive to contain hedges even for vanilla options.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Discussion Our aim is to extend allowed strategies such that the new class contains the natural class of smooth strategies depending on the spot and hindsight factors, i.e. Φ is of form (3) with ϕ C 1 ([0, T ] R + R m );

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Discussion Our aim is to extend allowed strategies such that the new class contains the natural class of smooth strategies depending on the spot and hindsight factors, i.e. Φ is of form (3) with ϕ C 1 ([0, T ] R + R m ); is sufficiently large to contain hedges for relevant vanilla and exotic options;

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Discussion Our aim is to extend allowed strategies such that the new class contains the natural class of smooth strategies depending on the spot and hindsight factors, i.e. Φ is of form (3) with ϕ C 1 ([0, T ] R + R m ); is sufficiently large to contain hedges for relevant vanilla and exotic options; is sufficiently small to guarantee the absence of arbitrage for the extended class of strategies.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Discussion Our aim is to extend allowed strategies such that the new class contains the natural class of smooth strategies depending on the spot and hindsight factors, i.e. Φ is of form (3) with ϕ C 1 ([0, T ] R + R m ); is sufficiently large to contain hedges for relevant vanilla and exotic options; is sufficiently small to guarantee the absence of arbitrage for the extended class of strategies. All this is possible to establish, but that would be somewhat technical. We shall not give the details in this talk.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Replication and no-arbitrage Consider next replication and absence of arbitrage in a class M σ. Every model in M σ is free of arbitrage with allowed strategies provided one admits an equivalent local martingale measure.

Replication, arbitrage and non-semimartingales Replication and no-arbitrage Consider next replication and absence of arbitrage in a class M σ. Every model in M σ is free of arbitrage with allowed strategies provided one admits an equivalent local martingale measure. Suppose G is a continuous functional on C s,+ ([0, T ]) and in some model ( Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ there is an allowed strategy Φ t = ϕ (t, S t, g 1 (t, S),..., g m (t, S)) and an initial wealth v 0 such that V T ( Φ, v 0 ; S) = G( S) P a.s. Then in every model (Ω, F, S, F, P) M σ the allowed strategy ϕ (t, S t, g 1 (t, S),..., g m (t, S)) replicates the payoff G(S) at terminal time T P-almost surely and with initial capital v 0.

Concluding remarks Replication, summary It has been known that for some pricing models the replication of certain options is the same as in the case of classical Black & Scholes pricing model. We have extended this to a rather big class of pricing models and strategies. The class of allowed strategies is big enough to replicate standard options, and small enough to exclude arbitrage. The replication procedure is the same for each model in a model class!

Concluding remarks Volatility It is well known that the implied volatility and the historical volatility do not agree. But if the driving process is mixed fractional, this is clear: The hedging price depends on the quadratic variation of the stock price S, but the historical volatility is estimated as the variance of the log-returns. These are different notions. Deviations from Gaussianity There is a lot of evidence that the log-returns are not Gaussian. By adding a zero-energy process to Brownian motion we do not change the replicating portfolio, but we have a full panorama to change the distributional properties of the stock prices.

Concluding remarks Irrelevance of probability By setting (W, B H ) to be jointly Gaussian, say, with suitable covariance structure can have any autocorrelelation we want in the mixed model. However, the hedging prices are not affected. So, in option pricing the probabilistic structure of the log-returns is irrelevant!

References Föllmer (1981): Calcul d Itô sans probabilités Schoenmakers, Kloeden (1999): Robust Option Replication for a Black-Scholes Model Extended with Nondeterministic Trends Russo, Vallois (1993): Forward, backward and symmetric stochastic integration Sottinen, Valkeila (2003): On arbitrage and replication in the Fractional Black-Scholes pricing model. This talk: Bender, Sottinen, Valkeila (2006): On Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models.