Competition in Electricity Markets with Renewable Sources

Similar documents
Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

MODELING THE ELECTRICITY SPOT MARKETS

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

On Investment Decisions in Liberalized Electrcity Markets: The Impact of Spot Market Design

Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium

Analysis of the strategic use of forward contracting in electricity markets

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

Player 2 H T T -1,1 1, -1

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Answers to Problem Set 4

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Microeconomic Theory II Spring 2016 Final Exam Solutions

The competitive benefits of forward contracting over space and time

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity

Location, Productivity, and Trade

HW Consider the following game:

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

Noncooperative Oligopoly

MODELLING THE HEDGING DECISIONS OF A GENERATOR WITH MARKET POWER

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

Constraints. Nodir Adilov. April 30, Abstract. enhance efficiency. This paper analyzes the implications of forward markets when

Cournot Equilibrium in Price-capped Two-Settlement Electricity Markets

The Sharing Economy for the Smart Grid

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

Energy Systems under Uncertainty: Modeling and Computations

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

S 2,2-1, x c C x r, 1 0,0

Capacity precommitment and price competition yield the Cournot outcome

Valuation of Transmission Assets and Projects. Transmission Investment: Opportunities in Asset Sales, Recapitalization and Enhancements

Supply function equilibrium, price caps, and investment 1

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Renewable Energy and the Pricing of Electricity Futures

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Supply Function Equilibria with Capacity Constraints and Pivotal Suppliers*

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP'

Wind Generators and Market Power: Does it matter who owns them?

The science of monetary policy

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Electricity Markets. Prof. Dr. G. Erdmann Fachgebiet Energiesysteme / TU Berlin Einsteinufer 25 / TA 8 (Room TA 033) D Berlin

Game Theory: Additional Exercises

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Endogenous choice of decision variables

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Vertical Integration and Risk Management. Competitive Markets of Non-Storable Goods

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Game Theory Fall 2003

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Social Optimality in the Two-Party Case

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

H. Raouf Sheybani* and M. Oloomi Buygi**

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Problem Set 2 - SOLUTIONS

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Locational Marginal Pricing

PROBLEM SET 6 ANSWERS

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Value-at-Risk Based Portfolio Management in Electric Power Sector

Mixed strategies in PQ-duopolies

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

Scenario reduction and scenario tree construction for power management problems

Hedging Risk. Quantitative Energy Economics. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 47

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

Challenges and Solutions: Innovations that we need in Optimization for Future Electric Power Systems

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

MFE8825 Quantitative Management of Bond Portfolios

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Not 0,4 2,1. i. Show there is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium where player A chooses to play, player A chooses L, and player B chooses L.

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Asymmetric Supply Function Equilibrium with Applications to Investment Decisions in the Electricity Industry

1. (15 points) P1 P2 P3 P4. GAME THEORY EXAM (with SOLUTIONS) January 2010

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Strategic Production Game 1

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Transcription:

Competition in Electricity Markets with Renewable Sources Ali Kakhbod and Asu Ozdaglar Laboratory for Information and Decision Systems Electrical Engineering and Computer Science Department Massachusetts Institute of Technology FORCES Review Meeting June 2014 1

Introduction Introduction Our earlier work [Wei, Malekian, Ozdaglar 14] focused on demand management under competitive markets with rich heterogeneity on the demand side and production and ramp up/ramp down costs on the production side. Two important elements missing from this picture: Market power of several generators in deregulated wholesale markets oligopolistic rather than competitive modeling. Increasing importance of renewables. 2

Introduction Motivation Concerns about climate change have led both to an expansion in renewable energy investments and the establishment of ambitious targets for the share of future renewable energy sources. At least 67 countries, including 27 EU countries have renewable energy targets of some type. The EU baseline target is to have 20% of electricity provided by renewables by year 2020. This motivates many conventional (thermal) energy companies to diversify their energy portfolio and increase their investments in renewable plants, e.g. Xcel Energy in US, Alstom Energy in Europe: A diverse energy portfolio is the only sound business and policy strategy able to address any Energy & Climate scenario, says Alstom at World Energy Congress (WEC 2013). 3

Merit Order Effect Introduction Because marginal cost of wind and solar is negligible, expansion of their supply reduces spot prices (the so called ARTICLE merit IN order" PRESS effect). ARTICLE IN P F. Sensfuß et al. / Energy Policy 36 (2008) 3086 3094 3087 3088 F. Sensfuß et al. / Energy Policy 36 electricity market prices in the years 2001 and 2004 2006. A detailed description of the PowerACE model can be found in Sensfuß (2007) and Genoese et al. (2007). The model provides a detailed representation of the German electricity sector. The model simulates reserve markets and the spot market. The spot market prices are calculated on an hourly level for an entire year. Based on a price prognosis power plants and pumped storage plants are bid into reserve markets 2 and the spot market. For the given simulation the bid price for power plants is based on variable cost and start up cost. Demand and renewable load are bid with price inelastic bids into the market. It is assumed that the entire electricity demand is traded at the simulated spot market. This assumption deviates from the real world situation in two ways: Fig. 1. Merit-order effect of renewable electricity generation. Source: own illustration. Figure: Source: [Sensfuss et al. 2008] which was not foreseen in the futures markets (European Energy Exchange [EEX], 2007a). This aspect leads to slight differences regarding the estimation of the market value. In addition the electricity generated by renewable energy 1. In the real world situation only ca. 89 TWh or 16.5% of the electricity demand were traded on the spot market in 2006 (European Energy Exchange [EEX], 2007b). It can be assumed Fig. 2. The impact of renewable generation on market prices in different segments that an important amount of electricity is traded in bilateral on electricity demand. Source: own illustration contracts which are likely to be less volatile than the spot market. demand. 2. TheThis simulated difference spotinmarket the impact priceson aremarket based prices on fundamental is caused by thedata. different Therefore slopeprices or stepare size less ofvolatile the German than merit-order real world market curve in different prices. load It issegments not likelyofthat the electricity peak prices demand. of several Thehundred slope of the German h/mwh merit-order at the real spot is higher market in represent cases of high a good demand. price signal This for the entire electricity demand in a given hour. Under the effect is illustrated in a stylized way in Fig. 2. A representation of given assumption that the entire electricity demand is traded 4

Merit Order Effect Introduction Figure: Relation between prices in red ($/MWh) and renewable energy output in blue (MWh) in Germany. Source: European Energy Exchange (EEX). Based on this evidence and theoretical expectation, it is generally forecast that merit order effect will continue to reduce prices in the future. 5

Our Contribution Introduction The fact that much of wind power may come to be supplied by conventional energy companies (which rely on thermal generators) may neutralize the merit order effect. In an oligopolistic market, firms may strategically reduce their conventional supply exactly to offset the increase in wind output. This effect crucially depends on conventional energy companies being the suppliers of wind power. Otherwise they would not internalize the increase in profits in wind supply from reducing conventional energy supply. This suggests that the diversification of conventional energy companies and their potential dominance over wind power may need to be regulated. 6

Plan Introduction We illustrate the merit order neutralization using a simple oligopoly model with conventional and wind energy. We show that strategic supply choices creates an offset on the impact of wind supply. If all wind is owned by conventional suppliers, then this offset is complete and there is no impact from wind power penetration on prices. If there are forward contracts (a common feature of energy markets), then prices are uniformly lower but neutralization of merit order effect still applies. We will also consider the incomplete information case when the wind availability is stochastic, heterogeneous and not commonly known. 7

Introduction A Note on Modeling Electricity market competition (on generation) modeled using two approaches. Supply Function Competition: Firms (or generators) compete by choosing supply functions specifying power supply as a function of price. ([Klemperer, Meyer 89], [Green, Newbery 92], [Rudkevich et al. 98], [Baldick, Hogan 02], [Baldick et al. 04]). Appealing due to its similarity to how markets operate in practice where generators submit step-wise increasing offer function. Cournot Competition: Firms compete by choosing their power supply (price determined by market clearing) ([Borenstein et al. 95], [Borenstein, Bushnell 99], [Hogan 97], [Oren 97], [Yao et al. 08]). Appealing due to its analytical tractability. Cournot model often provides a good explanation of observed price variations ([Baldick 02], [Willems et al. 09]) We will use Cournot model in representing the strategic interactions between generators (we ignore transmission constraints for now). 8

Simplified Model Simplified Oligopoly Model Two conventional generators each producing q i units of thermal energy (from gas or fuel) at cost c i (q i ) = γq i, where γ > 0 is a scalar. We assume there are wind farms producing a total amount of R units of wind energy (with zero marginal cost of production). Inverse demand function (specifying market price as a function of total amount) is given by P(q) = α (q + R), where α > 0 is a scalar. 9

Simplified Oligopoly Model Case 0: Merit Order Effect (MoE) with Nonstrategic Suppliers As a benchmark, suppose that the two conventional generators supply some amount q 1 and q 2 to the market regardless of wind availability. We can see the starkest form of merit order effect: implying that dp dr = 1. p C0 = P(q 1 + q 2 ) = α (q 1 + q 2 + R), In this case, when R increases, price goes down one for one. 10

Simplified Oligopoly Model Case 1: MoE with Strategic Suppliers Now suppose that supply is determined by Cournot competition by two conventional generators that do not own wind farms. Each generator i is interested in maximizing his profit given by Π C1 i (q 1, q 2 ) = P(q 1 + q 2 )q i γq i = (α (q 1 + q 2 + R))q i γq i. The price at the Nash equilibrium of the resulting game is given by p C1 = 1 (α R + 2γ), 3 implying that dp dr = 1 3, an offset relative to full MoE. This is due to strategic substitutes in Cournot competition (when one player increases its strategy, other player s best response declines). Here strategic substitutes entails that when R increases, both q 1 and q 2 decreases accounting for partial offset of MoE. 11

Simplified Oligopoly Model Case 2: Neutralization of MoE Suppose that each conventional generator owns δ R 2 units of wind, δ [0, 1]. When δ = 1, all wind is supplied by conventional power generators. Generator i s profit is now given by ( Π C2 i (q 1, q 2 ) = P(q 1 +q 2 ) q i +δ R ) ( γq i = (α (q 1 +q 2 +R)) q i +δ R ) γq i. 2 2 The price at the Nash equilibrium of the resulting game is given by p C2 = 1 (α R + δr + 2γ). 3 When δ 1, dp dr = 0, thus MoE is fully neutralized. What explains this paradoxical result? When δ 1, all wind supply generates profits for conventional power generators. Incentive to hold back on conventional supply to keep prices higher and protect their profits from wind. 12

Simplified Oligopoly Model Case 3: Forward Contracts We now consider the same economy, but allow conventional generators to sign forward contracts. Forward contracts have become increasingly important in electricity markets. They are sometimes argued to: reduce price by creating a precommitted supply in the market, reduce volatility by making certain quantity available before cost and wind power availability is realized. We will now see that introducing forward contracts indeed reduce prices, but MoE is still neutralized in the presence of diversified producers. 13

Simplified Oligopoly Model Case 3: Forward Contracts (Continued) Economy has two dates, t = 1, 2. At t = 1, each conventional generator i signs a contract (q f i, pf i ), promising to generate q f i units of (thermal) energy at price p f i for delivery at t = 2 (similar to the model in [Allaz, Vila 93]). 1 The price at the (subgame perfect) Nash equilibrium of the resulting game is given by p C3 = 1 5 (α R + δr + 4γ)< pc2. With forward contracts, prices are uniformly lower because forward commitments make each Cournot oligopolists act partially as a Stackleberg leader (since they first choose their forward contract and this forces other producer to cut back on his production). Therefore forward contracts make competition fiercer pushing prices down. 1 We assume no arbitrage. Forward price must be equal to spot price given forward positions. 14

Simplified Oligopoly Model Case 4: Incomplete Information Now imagine incomplete information where the availability of wind at generator i is given by R i = R/2 + θ i, where θ i N (0, σ 2 ) (each generator owns δr i units of wind). θ i is private information of generator i: each generator knows his own realized wind. We assume θ 1 and θ 2 are correlated capturing the geographic proximity of the wind farms of the generators affected by some local condition. Cov(θ 1, θ 2 ) = κσ 2, where κ is inversely proportional to the distance between the wind farms. 15

Equilibrium Simplified Oligopoly Model Proposition There exists a unique pure-strategy perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE) in linear strategies in which each generator i produces ( ) complete information 1 + δ + κ q i (θ i ) = qi θ i and the resulting price satisfies 2 + κ = 2 5 (α R δr/4 γ) ( 1 + δ + κ 2 + κ Var(p C4 ) = 2 E[p C4 ] = p C3, ( ) 2 1 δ (1 + κ)σ 2. 2 + κ ) θ i, 16

Intuition Simplified Oligopoly Model Each generator cuts back on supply (relative to complete information) as a function of their wind availability for the same reason as before. This effect is now modulated because θ i also gives information about wind availability of competitor: When κ high, wind availability more correlated and greater holding back. When δ = 1: this effect disappears, production does not depend on κ! With δ = 1, there is complete neutralization of MoE, i.e., total production of each producer (conventional +wind) is independent of θ. Volatility of prices is decreasing in κ, because lower κ creates more miscoordination in supplies across competitors. When δ = 1, total supply of each producer independent of θ, hence price volatility disappears. 17

General Model General Oligopoly Model Suppose we have n conventional generators. The availability of wind at generator i is given by R i = R/n + θ i, where θ i N (0, σ 2 ) (each generator owns δr i units of wind). The covariance matrix of (θ 1,..., θ n ) is given by 1 κ 1,2 κ 1,n Σ σ 2 κ 2,1 1 κ 2,n...... κ n,1 κ n,2 1 where κ i,j is inversely proportional to the distance between wind farms of generators i and j. 18

General Oligopoly Model Equilibrium Proposition There exists a unique pure-strategy perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE) in linear strategies in which each generator i produces q i (θ i ) = n ( n 2 α R δr ) + 1 n 2 γ a i θ i where a = A 1 v, A = 1 σ 2 Σ + I, I is the identity matrix, and each element of the vector v = (v 1, v 2,, v n ) T is given by v i = 1 + δ + j i κ i,j. The resulting price satisfies E[p] = 1 n 2 + 1 (α R + δr + n2 γ), Var(p) = a T Σa 2a T Σ1 + 1 T Σ1 19

Conclusions Conclusions We presented an oligopoly model with conventional and wind energy. We studied the effect of diversification of energy portfolio of conventional generators on spot market prices. Ongoing Work and Extensions: Effect of network structure" of wind farms on price volatility. Optimal pricing when renewable generators have incentive to hold back their supply: Oligopoly pricing with stochastic and correlated capacity constraints. Market design to reduce prices and price volatility. Transmission constraints: Introduce power flow constraints and treat each bus separately. Price will be location dependent: Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP). 20