All questions are weighted equally, and each roman numeral is weighted equally within each question. log(q i ) pq i + w i, max. pq j c 2 q2 j.

Similar documents
log(q i ) pq i + w i, max pq j c 2 q2 j.

q S pq S cq S. b q D p = 0, firms maximize profits taking prices as given, so they which to produce 0, p < c , p > c

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Market Design. Econ University of Notre Dame

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Strategic Production Game 1

S 2,2-1, x c C x r, 1 0,0

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Problem Set: Contract Theory

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Practice Exam Questions 2

Noncooperative Oligopoly

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

PhD Qualifier Examination

Solution Problem Set 2

ECONOMICS 336Y5Y Fall/Spring 2014/15. PUBLIC ECONOMICS Spring Term Test February 26, 2015

Externalities 1 / 40

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Externalities 1 / 40

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

ECONOMICS QUALIFYING EXAMINATION IN ELEMENTARY MATHEMATICS

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

ANSWERS FINAL 342 VERSION 1

max x + y s.t. y + px = m

Open Math in Economics MA National Convention 2017 For each question, E) NOTA indicates that none of the above answers is correct.

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

Microeconomics I - Midterm

HW Consider the following game:

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Interbank market liquidity and central bank intervention

Interest Rates, Market Power, and Financial Stability

Trade on Markets. Both consumers' initial endowments are represented bythesamepointintheedgeworthbox,since

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

Problem Set: Contract Theory

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

Cournot with N rms (revisited)

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

There are 10 questions on this exam. These 10 questions are independent of each other.

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Illiquidity and Interest Rate Policy

Mohammad Hossein Manshaei 1394

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

Patents. Patents. Chapter 9. March 30, 2015

Strategy -1- Strategy

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Honors General Exam PART 1: MICROECONOMICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2013

Games of Incomplete Information

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Time, Uncertainty, and Incomplete Markets

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Insurance Markets

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies:

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Answers to Odd-Numbered Problems, 4th Edition of Games and Information, Rasmusen. PROBLEMS FOR CHAPTER 14: Pricing

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

Business Economics Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets (Deriving the Supply Curve))

ECO 445/545: International Trade. Jack Rossbach Spring 2016

A brief introduction to economics

Final Solutions ECON 301 May 13, 2012

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

1 Auctions. 1.1 Notation (Symmetric IPV) Independent private values setting with symmetric riskneutral buyers, no budget constraints.

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Final Exam (100 Points Total)

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Transcription:

All questions are weighted equally, and each roman numeral is weighted equally within each question. Good luck!. There are I buyers who take prices as given and each solve max q i log(q i ) pq i + w i, and there are sellers who take prices as given and each solve Assume I >. max q j pq j c q j. i. In the centralized market, all buyers and sellers trade together. Determine the equilibrium price and quantity traded. Each buyer i s demand is characterized by so that total demand is Each seller j s supply is characterized by q i p = 0 q i = p, I q i = I p. i= p cq j = 0 q j = p c, so that total supply is Setting supply and demand equal yields j= q j = p c. p c = I p p = I c and I q = c. ii. In the decentralized market, matching is one-to-one, so only of the I buyers get to match to a seller to trade. Determine the prices and quantities traded within each match, and the total quantity traded. In this case, within each mini-market, we set supply equal to demand to get and quantity in each mini-market is p = p c p = c, q = c.

Then the price in the decentralized market is just c and the quantity is / c. iii. Compare the prices and quantities traded in the centralized and decentralized markets. The price in the centralized market is I/c, and since I >, this implies I/c > /c = /c, which is the price in the decentralized market. So prices are higher. The quantity in the centralized market is I/c > /c = / c, which is the quantity in the decentralized market. So prices are higher and quantities are higher. iv. In the centralized market, how does the price depend on market tightness, I/? If there are I buyers and sellers, there are ways to match the first buyer to each seller, ways to match the second buyer to each seller, and so on, f a total of I connections. How does the quantity in the centralized market depend on the total number of connections? As the number of sellers grows large in the decentralized market, does price get closer to marginal cost as would happen in a centralized perfectly competitive market not? The price is increasing in market tightness. The quantity is increasing in the number of connections. As the number of sellers in the centralized market gets large, the price never varies from c, so no, it does not converge to the perfectly competitive outcome.. While many people enjoy consuming alcohol, it has a number of negative externalities: lowered inhibitions lead to fights and drunk driving, and life-long consumption can lead to cirrhosis of the liver various kinds of cancer. To model this, suppose there is a representative household that takes prices as given and decides how much alcohol to consume, Q, solving max Q Q Q pq + w X where X = xq is an externality that the household does not take into account when making its consumption decision. Alcohol is produced by j =,,..., profit-maximizing firms in Cournot competition, whose costs are C(q j ) = q j. i. What amount is produced and consumed in equilibrium? The household s demand curve is Each firm k then maximizes with FONC Q p = 0 p = Q. π k = ( ) q j q k q k j= q j q k = 0. j= Since the firms face the same demand curve and have the same costs, let q = q =... = q, and we ll look f a symmetric solution to the game. This implies ( + )q = 0 q = +

and the total quantity produced is Q = q = +. ii. What quantity maximizes utilitarian social welfare? Utilitarian social welfare is W = Q Q pq + w xq + pq Q where Q is the total amount produced. The transfers cancel, and maximizing yields Q x = 0 Q o = x. iii. If me firms entered the market, does it raise lower social welfare in equilibrium? Explain. Is the amount in the market greater less than the optimal amount? + x ( x)( + ) x x + x x So if the number of firms is too large relative to ( x)/x, the externality dominates and social welfare is harmed by entry. iv. If the government imposed a tax tq on the household s consumption, what t implements the socially optimal outcome? The household s FONC then becomes Q p t = 0 p = t Q, and the total quantity produced in the market is q (t) = ( t) +. In der to match the social efficient quantity, this means and ( t) = ( x) + t = + ( x). 3

v. Briefly explain in wds how when there are multiple market failures, crecting one might reduce social welfare overall. In this case, market power reduces quantity, which can be beneficial in the presence of a negative externality. In general, when there are multiple market failures wking in opposite directions, society might benefit on net relative to a market where someone intervenes to solve one market failure but not another. 4

3. Consider a lending market, where entrepreneurs with different levels of talent take out loans f businesses. There are two kinds of browers: low risk, L, who occur with probability r and succeed with probability, and high risk, H, who occur with probability r, and succeed with probability /. The profit of a successful business is π, and it costs c to start a business. Banks can loan c to the brower in der to fund the business, not. Successful businesses produce profits π and repay t, while those that fail produce no profits and do not repay the loan. Call t the price of the loan. The payoff to the low risk type from getting a loan is π t, while getting no loan gives a payoff of zero; the payoff to high risk types from getting a loan is (π t) + 0, while getting no loan gives a payoff of zero. Assume π > c. i. Suppose the lending market is perfectly competitive, so that the expected return on the loan is equal to the cost of a loan (remember, loans ending in default repay nothing). If types are observable, what are the prices of loans f low and high risk browers? Under what conditions do the low risk browers take out loans? What about high-risk browers? If types are observable, the expected profit on a loan to a low-risk firm is t c so that t L = c. The expected profit to a high-risk firm is t + 0 c = 0, so that t H = c. Low risk browers always take out loans since π > c, but high-risk browers select out of the market on their own if π < c. ii. Suppose the lending market is perfectly competitive, so that the expected return on the loan is set equal to the cost of a loan. If types are unobservable, what is the price of a loan? How does the price depend on r? Suppose π = and c = 3/4: at what value of r do the low-risk types withdraw from the market? At what value of r do the high-risk types withdraw from the market? The expected profit on a loan is now rt + ( r) t c = 0, so that c t I = r + ( r) = c + r. The price is decreasing in r, since the presence of me low-risk people in the market reduces the cost of capital/lending. With these numbers, both types brow if 3/ + r 0 + r 3 r. iii. Suppose, instead, that a monopolist bank was selling loans to maximize its profits but could not observe browers types. What price would it charge? Suppose π = and c = 3/4: f what 5

values of r is lending profitable? The monopolist faces the constraints π t 0 and (π t) 0, so he can charge all the way up to π = t. Then his profits are F those parameters, his profits are positive if πr + ( r) π c. r + ( r) 3 4 0 r + ( r) 3 r. iv. Explain in wds how the presence of bad lending risks in the market can cause it to collapse, and no one ends up with loans. (This is an imptant part of the 008 financial crisis that started in the market f mtgages.) The presence of the high types with incomplete infmation drives up the price of a loan. If there are too many bad risks, the price is too high f anyone to want to brow in the perfectly competitive market, and under the same conditions, it is not profitable f a monopolist to lend. This causes the market to unravel, and no credit is available f anyone. 6