Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model

Similar documents
Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model

Portfolio Optimization Under a Stressed-Beta Model

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models

Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities

Calibration to Implied Volatility Data

The stochastic calculus

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

Volatility Time Scales and. Perturbations

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Heston 1.5

Linear-Rational Term-Structure Models

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

The Term Structure of Interest Rates under Regime Shifts and Jumps

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Stochastic Volatility Effects on Defaultable Bonds

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Locally risk-minimizing vs. -hedging in stochastic vola

7 th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference 2015

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Asian Options under Multiscale Stochastic Volatility

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Applications to Fixed Income and Credit Markets

Pricing Pension Buy-ins and Buy-outs 1

Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation in a Stochastic Volatility Environment

Enlargement of filtration

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Calculating Implied Volatility

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Stochastic Volatility Modeling

Timing the Smile. Jean-Pierre Fouque George Papanicolaou Ronnie Sircar Knut Sølna. October 9, 2003

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Theoretical Problems in Credit Portfolio Modeling 2

Risk Neutral Measures

Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Fair Valuation of Insurance Contracts under Lévy Process Specifications Preliminary Version

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

PDE Methods for the Maximum Drawdown

Portability, salary and asset price risk: a continuous-time expected utility comparison of DB and DC pension plans

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Investors Attention and Stock Market Volatility

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Derivation Of The Capital Asset Pricing Model Part I - A Single Source Of Uncertainty

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Dynamic Asset and Liability Management Models for Pension Systems

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Information, Interest Rates and Geometry

MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY ASYMPTOTICS

Lévy models in finance

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

LOG-SKEW-NORMAL MIXTURE MODEL FOR OPTION VALUATION

Risk Neutral Valuation

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

1 Introduction. 2 Old Methodology BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Interest Rate Curves Calibration with Monte-Carlo Simulatio

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Transcription:

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model Adam Tashman in collaboration with Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California, Santa Barbara Department of Statistics and Applied Probability Center for Research in Financial Mathematics and Statistics January 29, 2010 1

Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Discrete-time approach Excess return of asset R a R f is linear function of excess return of market R M and Gaussian error term: R a R f = β(r M R f ) + ɛ Beta coefficient estimated by regressing asset returns on market returns. 2

Difficulties with CAPM Some difficulties with this approach, including: 1) Relationship between asset returns, market returns not always linear 2) Estimation of β from history, but future may be quite different Ultimate goal of this research is to deal with both of these issues 3

Extending CAPM: Dynamic Beta Two main approaches: 1) Retain linearity, but beta changes over time; Ferson (1989), Ferson and Harvey (1991), Ferson and Harvey (1993), Ferson and Korajczyk (1995), Jagannathan and Wang (1996) 2) Nonlinear model, by way of state-switching mechanism; Fridman (1994), Akdeniz, L., Salih, A.A., and Caner (2003) ASC introduces threshold CAPM model. Our approach is related. 4

Estimating Implied Beta Different approach to estimating β: look to options market Forward-Looking Betas, 2006 P Christoffersen, K Jacobs, and G Vainberg Discrete-Time Model Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities, 2009 J-P Fouque, E Kollman Continuous-Time Model, stochastic volatility environment 5

Example of Time-Dependent Beta Stock Industry Beta (2005-2006) Beta (2007-2008) AA Aluminum 1.75 2.23 GE Conglomerate 0.30 1.00 JNJ Pharmaceuticals -0.30 0.62 JPM Banking 0.54 0.72 WMT Retail 0.21 0.29 Larger β means greater sensitivity of stock returns relative to market returns 6

Regime-Switching Model We propose a model similar to CAPM, with a key difference: When market falls below level c, slope increases by δ, where δ > 0 Thus, beta is two-valued This simple approach keeps the mathematics tractable 7

Dynamics Under Physical Measure IP M t value of market at time t S t value of asset at time t dm t M t = µdt + σ m dw t Market Model; const vol, for now ds t S t = β(m t ) dm t M t + σdz t Asset Model β(m t ) = β + δ I {Mt <c} Brownian motions W t, Z t indep: d W, Z t = 0 8

Dynamics Under Physical Measure IP Substituting market equation into asset equation: ds t S t = β(m t )µdt + β(m t )σ m dw t + σdz t Asset dynamics depend on market level, market volatility σ m This is a geometric Brownian motion with volatility β 2 (M t )σ 2 m + σ 2 Note this is a stochastic volatility model 9

Dynamics Under Physical Measure IP Process preserves the definition of β: Cov V ar ( ds t S t ), dm t M t ( dm t M t ) = = ( Cov β(m t ) dm t M t V ar ( Cov β(m t ) dm t = β(m t ) V ar ) + σdz t, dm t M t ( ) dm t M t M t ), dm t M t ( dm t M t ) Since BM s indep 10

Dynamics Under Risk-Neutral Measure IP Market is complete (M and S both tradeable) Thus, unique Equivalent Martingale Measure IP defined as dip dip { = exp T t θ (1) dw s T t θ (2) dz s 1 2 T t } { (θ (1) ) 2 + (θ (2) ) 2} ds with θ (1) = µ r σ m θ (2) = r(β(m t) 1) σ 11

Dynamics Under Risk-Neutral Measure IP dm t M t = rdt + σ m dw t ds t S t = rdt + β(m t )σ m dw t + σdz t where dw t = dw t + µ r σ m dt dzt = dz t + r(β(m t) 1) dt σ By Girsanov s Thm, W t, Z t are indep Brownian motions under IP. 12

Option Pricing P price of option with expiry T, payoff h(s T ) Option price at time t < T is function of t, M, and S (M,S) Markovian Option price discounted expected payoff under risk-neutral measure P { } P (t, M, S) = IE e r(t t) h(s T ) M t = M, S t = S 13

State Variables Define new state variables: X t = log S t, ξ t = log M t Initial conditions X 0 = x, ξ 0 = ξ Dynamics are: dξ t = dx t = ( ) r σ2 m dt + σ m dwt 2 ( r 1 ) 2 (β2 (e ξ t )σm 2 + σ 2 ) dt + β(e ξ t )σ m dw t + σdz t 14

State Variables WLOG, let t = 0 In integral form, ξ t = ξ + ( ) r σ2 m t + σ m Wt 2 Next, consider X at expiry (integrate from 0 to T ): ) T X T = x + (r σ2 T σ2 m β 2 (e ξ t )dt 2 2 + σ m T 0 β(e ξ t )dw t + σz T 0 15

Working with X T M t < c e ξ t < c ξ t < log c β(m t ) = β + δ I {Mt <c} β(e ξ t ) = β + δ I {ξt <log c} Using this definition for β(e ξ t ), X T becomes X T = x + (r β2 σm 2 + σ 2 ) T + σ m βwt + σzt 2 (δ 2 + 2δβ) σ2 m 2 T 0 I {ξt <log c}dt + σ m δ T 0 I {ξt <log c}dw t 16

Occupation Time of Brownian Motion Expression for X T involves integral T 0 I {ξ t <log c}dt This is occupation time of Brownian motion with drift To simplify calculation, apply Girsanov to remove drift from ξ 17

Occupation Time of Brownian Motion Consider new probability measure ĨP defined as dĩp { dip = exp θwt 1 } 2 θ2 T θ = 1 σ m ( ) r σ2 m 2 Under this measure, ξ t is a martingale with dynamics dξ t = σ m d W t d W t = dw t + 1 σ m ( ) r σ2 m dt 2 18

Changing Measure: IP ĨP Since W and Z indep, Z not affected by change of measure Can replace Z with Z Under ĨP, XT = x + A1T + σmβ WT + σ Z T A 2 T + σ m δ T where constants A 1, A 2 defined as 0 0 I {ξt <log c}dt I {ξt <log c}d W t A 1 = r(1 β) σ2 m(β 2 β) + σ 2 A 2 = δ(δ + 2β 1) σ2 m 2 + δr 19 2

First Passage Time Now that ξ t is driftless, easier to work with occupation time Run process until first time it hits level log c Denote this first passage time { τ = inf {t 0 : ξ t = log c} = inf t 0 : W } t = c where c = log c ξ σ m Density of first passage time of ξ t = ξ to level log c is p(u; c) = c ( ) exp c2, u > 0 2πu 3 2u 20

Including First Passage Time Information First passage time τ may happen after T, so need to be careful Can partition time horizon into two pieces: [0, τ T ] and [τ T, T ] If ξ t < log c, τ T counts as occupation time 21

Including First Passage Time Information Incorporating this information into X T yields X T = x + A 1 T + σ m β W T + σ Z T T A 2 (τ T ) I { c>0} A 2 +σ m δ W τ T I { c>0} + σ m δ τ T T τ T I { Wt < c} dt I { Wt < c} d W t 22

Working with the Stochastic Integral Stochastic integral can be re-expressed in terms of local time L c of W at level c. Applying Tanaka s formula to φ(w) = (w c)i {w< c} between τ T and T, we get: T τ T I { Wt < c} d W t = φ( W T ) φ( W τ T ) + L c T L c τ T. 23

Starting Level of Market: Three Cases Consider separately the three cases ξ = log c, ξ > log c, and ξ < log c (or equivalently c = 0, c < 0, c > 0) Notation for terminal log-stock price, given ξ Case ξ = log c terminal log-stock price Ψ 0 Case ξ > log c terminal log-stock price Ψ + Case ξ < log c terminal log-stock price Ψ 24

Consider Case ξ < log c as Example In this case, c > 0 and we have X T = x + A 1 T + σ m β W T + σ Z T T A 2 (τ T ) A 2 I { Wt < c} dt + σ mδ W τ T τ T ) ) ] +σ m δ [( WT c I ( Wτ T { WT < c} c I { Wτ T < c} + L c T L c τ T Treat separately cases {τ < T } and {τ > T } 25

Case ξ < log c, contd. On {τ > T }, we have: X T = x + (A 1 A 2 )T + σ m (β + δ) W T + σ Z T =: Ψ T + ( W T, Z T ), where lower index T + stands for τ > T Distribution of X T is given by distn of independent Gaussian r.v. ZT, and conditional distn of W T given {τ > T }. 26

Case ξ < log c, contd. Conditional distn of W T given {τ > T }: From Karatzas and Shreve, one easily obtains: } ( 1 IP { WT da, τ > T = e a2 2T e (2 c a)2 2T 2πT =: q T (a; c) da ) da, a < c, 27

Case ξ < log c, contd. On {τ = u} with u T, we have W u = c, and X T = x + (A 1 A 2 )T + σ m (β + δ) c + σ m β( W T W u ) + σ Z T T +A 2 I { Wt W u >0} dt u +σ m δ [( WT W ) ] u I { WT W u <0} + L c T L c u Distn of X T given by distn of Z T and indep triplet ( BT u, L 0 T u, Γ+ T u) Triplet comprised of value, local time at 0, and occupation time of positive half-space, at time T u, of standard Brownian motion B. 28

Case ξ < log c, contd. In distribution: X T = x + (A 1 A 2 )T + σ m (β + δ) c + σ m B T u ( β + δ I{BT u <0}) + σ ZT +A 2 Γ + T u + σ mδl 0 T u =: Ψ T (B T u, L 0 T u, Γ + T u, Z T ). Distn of triplet ( B T u, L 0 T u, Γ+ T u) developed in paper by Karatzas and Shreve. 29

Karatzas-Shreve Triplet (1984) IP { WT da, L 0 T db, Γ } + T dγ 2p(T γ; b) p(γ; a + b) if a > 0, b > 0, 0 < γ < T, = 2p(γ; b) p(t γ; a + b) if a < 0, b > 0, 0 < γ < T, where p(u; ) is first passage time density 30

Back to Option Pricing Formula Given final expression for X T, option price at time t = 0 is P 0 = IE { e rt h(s T ) } { = ĨE e rt h(e X T ) dip } { dĩp } = ĨE e rt h(e X T )e θ W T 1 2 θ2 T = e rt e 1 2 θ2 T ĨE {h(e X T )e θ W T } 31

Option Pricing Formula, contd. Decompose expectation on {τ T } and {τ > T }, Denote by n T (z) the N (0, T ) density, Define the following convolution relation involving the K-S triplet: T γ 0 = g(a, b, γ; T u)p(u; c)du 2p(γ; a + b) p(t γ; b + c ) if a > 0 2p(γ; b) p(t γ; a + b + c ) if a < 0 =: G(a, b, γ; T ) 32

Option Pricing Formula, contd. The option pricing formula becomes P 0 = e (r+ 1 2 θ2 )T where [ e θ c ( + D ± = T 0 0 h(e Ψ± T (a,b,γ,z) )e θa G(a, b, γ; T ) da db dγ n T (z)dz )] h(e Ψ ± T + (a,z) )e θa q T (a; c)da n T (z)dz D ± (, c) if c > 0 ( c, ) if c < 0 33

Note About Market Stochastic Volatility (SV) Assumption of constant market volatility σ m not realistic Let market volatility be driven by fast mean-reverting factor Introducing market SV in model has effect on asset price dynamics To leading order, these prices are given by risk-neutral dynamics with σ m replaced by adjusted effective volatility σ (see Fouque, Kollman (2009) for details) One could derive a formula for first-order correction, but formula is quite complicated and numerically involved 34

Market Implied Volatilities Following Fouque, Papanicolaou, Sircar (2000) and Fouque, Kollman (2009), introduce Log-Moneyness to Maturity Ratio (LM M R) LMMR = log(k/x) T and for calibration purposes, we use affine LMMR formula I b + a ɛ LMMR with intercept b and slope a ɛ to be fitted to skew of options data Then estimate adjusted effective volatility as ( ) σ b + a ɛ r b 2 2 35

Numerical Results and Calibration 36

Asset Skews of Implied Volatilities Using Stressed-Beta model, price European call option Use following parameter settings: c S 0 r β σ σ T 1000 100 0.01 1.0 0.30 0.01 1.0 K = 70, 71,..., 150 to build implied volatility curves 37

Figure 1: Implied Volatility Skew vs. δ (M 0 = c) 0.48 0.46 0.44 δ=0.7 δ=0.5 δ=0.3 Implied Volatility (%) 0.42 0.4 0.38 0.36 0.34 0.32 0.3 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 K/S 38

Figure 2: Implied Volatility Versus Starting Market (δ = 0.5) 0.46 Implied Volatility (%) 0.44 0.42 0.4 0.38 0.36 0.34 M0=500 M0=900 M0=1000 M0=1100 M0=2000 0.32 0.3 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 K/S 39

Calibration to Data: Amgen Consider Amgen call options with October 2009 expiry Strikes: Take options with LMMR between 1 and 1, using closing mid-prices as of May 26, 2009 For simplicity, asset-specific volatility σ = 0 Market volatility σ estimated from call option data on S&P 500 Index (closest expiry Sep09) From affine LMMR, σ = 0.2549 40

Figure 3: Affine LMMR Fit to S&P 500 Index Options Implied Volatility (%) 0.29 0.28 0.27 0.26 0.25 0.24 0.23 0.22 0.21 0.2 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 LMMR 41

Calibration to Data: Amgen, contd. Need c, β, and δ Select params which min SSE between option model prices, market prices For context, closing level of S&P 500 Index as of May 26, 2009 was 910.33 Estimated parameters: ĉ = 925, ˆβ = 1.17, and ˆδ = 0.65. So market is below threshold 42

Figure 4: Volatility Skews for Amgen Call Options 0.5 0.48 0.46 0.44 market model Implied Volatility (%) 0.42 0.4 0.38 0.36 0.34 0.32 0.3 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 K/S 43

References Akdeniz, L., Salih, A.A., and Caner, M.: Time-Varying Betas Help in Asset Pricing: The Threshold CAPM. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 6 (2003). Ferson, W.E.: Changes in Expected Security Returns, Risk, and the Level of Interest Rates. Journal of Finance, 44(5), 1191-1214 (1989). Ferson, W.E., and Harvey, C.R.: The Variation of Economic Risk Premiums. Journal of Political Economy, 99(2), 385-415 (1991). 44

References, contd. Ferson, W.E., and Harvey, C.R.: The Risk and Predictability of International Equity Returns. Review of Financial Studies, 6(3), 527-566 (1993). Ferson, W.E., and Korajczyk, R.A.: Do Arbitrage Pricing Models Explain the Predictability of Stock Returns? Journal of Business, 68(3), 309-349 (1995). Fouque, J.-P., Papanicolaou, G., and Sircar, R.: Derivatives in Financial Markets with Stochastic Volatility. Cambridge University Press (2000). 45

References, contd. Fouque, J.-P., and Kollman, E.: Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities. Submitted (2009). Fridman, M.: A Two State Capital Asset Pricing Model. IMA Preprint Series #1221 (1994). Jagannathan, R., and Wang, Z.: The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns. Journal of Finance, 51(1), 3-53 (1996). Karatzas, I., and Shreve, S.E.: Trivariate Density of Brownian Motion, its Local and Occupation Times, with Application to Stochastic Control. Annals of Probability, 12(3), 819-828 (1984). 46

THANK YOU! 47