Risky asset valuation and the efficient market hypothesis

Similar documents
Testing for efficient markets

Predictability in finance

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

Example 1 of econometric analysis: the Market Model

Financial Returns: Stylized Features and Statistical Models

A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street

Session 10: Lessons from the Markowitz framework p. 1

Chapter 13. Efficient Capital Markets and Behavioral Challenges

University 18 Lessons Financial Management. Unit 12: Return, Risk and Shareholder Value

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Washington University Fall Economics 487. Project Proposal due Monday 10/22 Final Project due Monday 12/3

DO SHARE PRICES FOLLOW A RANDOM WALK?

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

A Random Walk Down Wall Street

ECMC49S Midterm. Instructor: Travis NG Date: Feb 27, 2007 Duration: From 3:05pm to 5:00pm Total Marks: 100

Washington University Fall Economics 487

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Module 3: Factor Models

Efficient capital markets. Skema Business School. Portfolio Management 1. Course Outline

CHAPTER 13 EFFICIENT CAPITAL MARKETS AND BEHAVIORAL CHALLENGES

Mean-Variance Theory at Work: Single and Multi-Index (Factor) Models

From optimisation to asset pricing

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

The Markowitz framework

AFM 371 Winter 2008 Chapter 14 - Efficient Capital Markets

Weak Form Efficiency of Gold Prices in the Indian Market

LONG MEMORY IN VOLATILITY

Institutional Finance Financial Crises, Risk Management and Liquidity

Adaptive Market Hypothesis: Evidence from three centuries of UK data

Testing Capital Asset Pricing Model on KSE Stocks Salman Ahmed Shaikh

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

Stock Market Basics. Capital Market A market for intermediate or long-term debt or corporate stocks.

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions

Module 6 Portfolio risk and return

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Econ 422 Eric Zivot Summer 2004 Final Exam Solutions

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Return Predictability

Institutional Finance Financial Crises, Risk Management and Liquidity

ARCH Models and Financial Applications

MBF2253 Modern Security Analysis

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

The Random Walk Hypothesis in Emerging Stock Market-Evidence from Nonlinear Fourier Unit Root Test

Capital Asset Pricing Model - CAPM

ACCA. Paper F9. Financial Management June Revision Mock Answers

Econ 422 Eric Zivot Fall 2005 Final Exam

Math 5760/6890 Introduction to Mathematical Finance

Extrapolation of the Past: The Most Important Investment Mistake? Nicholas Barberis. Yale University. November 2015

State Switching in US Equity Index Returns based on SETAR Model with Kalman Filter Tracking

Hedge Portfolios, the No Arbitrage Condition & Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Lesson XI: Market Efficiency and FX. Forecasting

EIEF, Graduate Program Theoretical Asset Pricing

Efficient Capital Markets

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Basic Tools of Finance (Chapter 27 in Mankiw & Taylor)

Lower prices. Lower costs, esp. wages. Higher productivity. Higher quality/more desirable exports. Greater natural resources. Higher interest rates

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Portfolio Theory Forward Testing

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

Short-run Share Price Behaviour: New Evidence on Weak Form of Market Efficiency

Indian Association of Alternative Investment Funds (IAAIF) Swapnil Pawar Scient Capital

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Graduate School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2003, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

PowerPoint. to accompany. Chapter 11. Systematic Risk and the Equity Risk Premium

Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund?

I. Return Calculations (20 pts, 4 points each)

Library Class 09/12. Meets in Doe Library Room 105

Some history. The random walk model. Lecture notes on forecasting Robert Nau Fuqua School of Business Duke University

1 of :18 PM

Stock Price Behavior. Stock Price Behavior

An Analysis of Theories on Stock Returns

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Expectations are very important in our financial system.

Valuation Models and Asset Returns

Risk and Return. Nicole Höhling, Introduction. Definitions. Types of risk and beta

High Frequency Autocorrelation in the Returns of the SPY and the QQQ. Scott Davis* January 21, Abstract

Martingales, Part II, with Exercise Due 9/21

Chapter 9. Technical Analysis & Market Efficiency. Technical Analysis. Market Volume Kaplan Financial. Market volume 9-1

FINC3017: Investment and Portfolio Management

BPK6C SECURITY ANALYSIS AND PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT. Unit : I to V. BPK6C - Security analysis and portfolio management

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

EIEF/LUISS, Graduate Program. Asset Pricing

RE-EXAMINE THE WEAK FORM MARKET EFFICIENCY

Portfolio Risk Management and Linear Factor Models

Stock Prices and the Stock Market

Risk and Return. CA Final Paper 2 Strategic Financial Management Chapter 7. Dr. Amit Bagga Phd.,FCA,AICWA,Mcom.

Technical Anomalies: A Theoretical Review

Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2014, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Midterm

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Efficiency in the Australian Stock Market, : A Note on Extreme Long-Run Random Walk Behaviour

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model

Probability Weighted Moments. Andrew Smith

In this model, the value of the stock today is the present value of the expected cash flows (equal to one dividend payment plus a final sales price).

Serial Persistence and Risk Structure of Local Housing Market

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

Transcription:

Risky asset valuation and the efficient market hypothesis IGIDR, Bombay May 13, 2011

Pricing risky assets

Principle of asset pricing: Net Present Value Every asset is a set of cashflow, maturity (C i, T i ) pairs. There can be fixed/variable cashflows at fixed/variable times. (Eg. Bonds, options; insurance, equity.) Price of the asset is the price of all expected cashflows E(C), at dates T. What is a cashflow E(C) at T worth today? NPV = Compound interest version: E(C) (1 + r) T NPV = e st E(C) where we use s = log(1 + r) and r is the discount rate. Valuation is all about getting the correct E(C), T, and r. The work we did to understand risk with Markowitz optimisation and CAPM comes in handy here to define r for any asset with risk.

Recap: Value of a security with risky cashflows A security produces cashflows E(C t ) from t = 1 till. The security is worth P: P = N t=1 Operationalising this requires: E(C t ) (1 + r f + ) t 1 The distribution of all E(C t ) in the future 2 The risk premium,, for the discount rate Which is hard!

Implementation of NPV, risky bond Let s assume that estimates of E(C i ) are available. If (say) there is a risky bond with N cashflows, and we use risk neutrality, price P is: P = N t=1 E(C t ) (1 + r f ) t where r f is the risk free rate of return. If we know the credit premium for the risk of cashflows, P becomes: P = N t=1 E(C t ) (1 + r f + ) t

Implementation of NPV, equity Equity is harder than bonds in that future cashflows are even more uncertain. Equity promises a fraction of the profits of the company at some undefined future time, called dividends. The hard part is making estimates of E(d t ) at future dates. Once we estimate of d t, the pricing technology is the same. NPV the future values of E(d t ), P = P = N t=1 N t=1 E(d t ) (1 + r f ) t under risk-neutrality (1) E(d t ) (1 + ) t (2) Note: Finance theory focuses on modelling. Security analysis focuses on models to forecast E(d t ). This focuses on one security at a time relatively little theory goes there.

Why price are hard to estimate, and volatile The NPV of the firm s share depends supremely on your views about 1 future dividend growth, and 2 the required risk premium. Slight changes to these views generate large changes in the price!

Sensitivity of stock prices: an example Starting from d 0 = 10: Discount rate (%) 11 12 13 14 15 7 8 9 10 11 Dividend growth (%) A huge range of stock prices associated with small changes in your view about future dividend growth and/or the risk

Summary In a risk neutral world, future E(C) are discounted at r f. However, in a risk-averse context, we need to incorporate a risk premium for risky cashflows. Asset pricing theory is about looking at an asset and saying what the should be for the risk characteristics of the firm. Even if were known, valuation is hard!! It requires forecasting expected cashflows at future dates. Particularly for equity: NPV is very very sensitive to slight changes in either growth of dividends or risk premium. Every day, as views on these two numbers change, stock prices fluctuate.

Traditional accounting methods For equity holders, the cashflows that are relevant are the free cashflow available to equity. These have been proxied by (a) the dividends paid out and (b) income net of the cashflows to debt holders, net of repayments, including new debt issued etc. These led to traditional approaches such as the free cashflow and the dividend discount models. Such models assume there is: 1 Consensus on the future free cashflows to equity, D i. 2 Consensus on the discount rate, r i. 3 Equity is infinitely lived. Established markets have financial analysts that forecast future cashflows from the balance sheets/p&ls of companies.

How on earth does any finance get done? The best economist would face a huge struggle to get a fix on P in any precise sense. The revolutionary idea of finance Speculative trading by atomic traders on organised financial markets does a pretty good job of getting the correct P.

Markets as a valuation methodology

Markets: The wisdom of crowds There are millions of speculators on the market. If a security is too cheap, speculators buy. If a security is too costly, speculators sell. No one speculator has market power. Each speculator is well incentivised: he makes huge profits if he s right, and huge losses if he s wrong. The equilibrium price works out to be remarkably smart. Market efficiency : The proposition that the price discovered by a speculative market does a pretty good job of embedding forecasts of future d t and a sensible risk premium. We shift gears from modelling equity prices, and try the understand the behaviour of prices from speculative markets.

Understanding prices and returns

The notion of returns The market produces a time-series P 1, P 2,... We like to focus on the percentage change in prices, the returns. Prowess jargon: Adjusted Closing Price (ACP).

Example: Mahindra & Mahindra M&M price 100 200 300 400 1990 1995 2000 2005

M&M returns (%) 20 10 0 10 1990 1995 2000 2005

Returns can be computed over any frequency Daily returns is common Weekly returns is useful You can go intra-day! Returns over five-minute intervals is precious.

M&M weekly returns (%) 40 20 0 10 20 30 1990 1995 2000 2005

Numerical example > load("mnm.rda") > tail(p) 2005-09-27 2005-09-28 2005-09-29 2005-09-30 2005 364.95 371.10 371.85 377.50 389. > prices2returns(tail(p)) 2005-09-28 2005-09-29 2005-09-30 2005-10-04 1.6711210 0.2018979 1.5080022 0.8442107

Summary statistics about returns > load("mnm.rda") > r <- prices2returns(p) > summary(r) Index r Min. :1990-01-02 Min. :-21.25614 1st Qu.:1995-02-08 1st Qu.: -1.46368 Median :1998-09-06 Median : 0.00000 Mean :1998-07-13 Mean : 0.08008 3rd Qu.:2002-03-20 3rd Qu.: 1.64140 Max. :2005-10-04 Max. : 15.41507 > sd(r) [1] 2.950983

Density 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 density.default(x = r) 20 10 0 10 N = 2746 Bandwidth = 0.428

Market efficiency In an efficient market, all speculators know the historical prices. Competition between them will eliminate opportunities for earning money for free. This is like the zero-profit condition under perfect competition. In the limit, when millions of smart speculators are in play, returns should become non-forecastable (i.e. random). This is a testable statement. Simplest model: Returns are homoscedastic normal. But reality doesn t have to oblige.

The random walk of speculative market prices

A model for speculative market prices We know that many rational speculators in a market ought to eliminate any arbitrage. Ie, similar assets will be similarly priced. Speculative markets ought to have prices with no forecastability no predictable runs, no autocorrelations in returns. Samuelson 1965 was the first paper to put a model to prices in such a speculative market. The model: perfectly competitive markets with rational agents have prices which are a random walk. This became the first widely accepted quantitative model for the DGP of speculative market prices.

The random walk If x t is a random walk variable, then where ɛ t is iid. x t = x t 1 + ɛ t Prices are log-normally distributed. Then, prices being a random walk means: where ɛ t is iid as N(0, σ 2 ). log p t = log p t 1 + ɛ t

Example: plotting a simulated random walk > P = 100 # In Rs. > N = 500 > m = 0.01 # In percent > sg = 1.2 # In percent > > plot(p*cumprod(1+(rnorm(n,m,sg)/100)),type="l", > ylab="p",xlab="t", > col="red")

P 75 80 85 90 95 100 0 100 200 300 400 500 T

Simulations off the same DGP P 90 100 110 120 130 P 85 95 105 75 0 100 200 300 400 500 T 0 100 200 300 400 500 T P 85 90 95 105 P 80 90 100 110 0 100 200 300 400 500 T 0 100 200 300 400 500 T P 80 90 100 110 P 100 120 140 0 100 200 300 400 500 T 0 100 200 300 400 500 T

Properties of a random walk The innovation at time t is ɛ t. ɛ t is i.i.d. drawn from N(0, σ 2 ). All innovations to the DGP are permanent. log P t+1 = log P t + ɛ t And, log P t+1 = log P t k + k i=0 ɛ t i The best estimate of the forecasted price P t+1 is P t. This is true for forecasts at all horizons, h, in the future. Ie, E(P t+h ) = P t These are also properties of a time series with a unit root.

A random walk is non-forecastable P t+1 = P t + ɛ t+1 Forecastability is focussed on any new information/pattern, ɛ t+1 over P t. This is a problem because: 1 ɛ t+1 tends to be a small change over P t. 2 ɛ t+1 is a random number. The focus of speculators tend to be on picking patterns in the data, either in the short run or the long run. Most appear to forget that random draws from a normal distribution have some non-zero probability of (a) runs and (b) temporal serial correlation.

Random walk prices, white noise returns If prices follow a random walk, then log p t+1 = log p t + ɛ t+1 where ɛ t+1 is iid as N(0, σ 2 ). Quantitatively, this implies that E(r t ) = E(ɛ t ) = E(ɛ) = 0 E(r t r t ) 2 = σ 2 ɛ This should hold irrespective of what point t in the time series is observed. E(r t+1 r t ) = 0; there is no autocorrelation in the series. This should hold for autocorrelations at all lags. Eg., E(r t+k r t ) = 0, k

Autocorrelations in white noise series > library(tseries) > load("6_5.rda") > > acf(r[1000:1090])

Example: Nifty, 90 days 1 Series r[500:590] ACF 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 5 10 15 Lag

Example: Nifty, 90 days 2 Series r[1000:1090] ACF 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 5 10 15 Lag

Example: Nifty, 2000 days Series r ACF 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Lag

Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH)

The grand market efficiency debate A strong market efficiency position is: There is zero forecastability of returns. Some people get excited when a t stat of 2.5 turns up, they have rejected the H 0 of market efficiency. There is a lot of talk about inefficient markets based on such rejections. But no forecasting equations have substantial power. H 0 can be rejected, but with a tiny R 2, the process is mostly white noise! What is remarkable is not that there are small chinks: what is remarkable is how the broad idea works rather well. The socialist view is: Speculators are evil, the speculative process is gambling. Modern finance knows better.

EMH: Definition EMH claims that investment in an asset priced in a speculative market is done at the fair value of the asset. "Asset prices fully and instantaneously rationally reflect all available relevant information." (Fama 1969,1971) "Asset prices reflect information to the point where the marginal benefits of acting on information (the profits to be made) do not exceed the marginal costs." Good textbook reference: John Y Campbell, Andrew W. Lo, Craig A. MacKinlay, 1995, The econometrics of financial markets, published by Princeton University Press.

EMH: Implications If the price is the correct discounted value of future cashflows, there are two sets of implications: 1 There are no arbitrage opportunities: you only get returns if you take risk. 2 There are implications on E(r) of any asset: this ought to be a function only of the risk premium on equity. This means E(excess returns) across any pair of assets ought not to differ persistently. These ought to be true given a fixed information set. Research goal: Do these statements about no-arbitrage actually hold in a market? We need to test EMH for a given market.

Tests of EMH Tests of EMH are categorised depending upon the information captured by market prices. The test categories are: 1 Weak form: tests based on publicly observed information. 2 Semi-strong form: based on information that is originally observed by a few, and then becomes publicly disclosed. 3 Strong form: based on information that only a small set of investors could be privy to. For example, testing for autocorrelation in a price series is a weak form test of EMH. The tests are based on prices, which are publicly observed.

References ANDREW LO, (editor) Market Efficiency: Stock Market Behaviour in Theory and Practice (International Library of Critical Writings in Economics). Edward Elgar Publishing, 1997