Corporate Payout Smoothing: A Variance Decomposition Approach

Similar documents
Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Leverage-Profitability Puzzle Re-examined Alan Douglas, University of Waterloo Tu Nguyen, University of Waterloo Abstract:

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Corporate Liquidity Management and Financial Constraints

Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy?

THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006

Debt Financing and Survival of Firms in Malaysia

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Investment and Financing Constraints

Government spending and firms dynamics

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Dividends and Share Repurchases: Effects on Common Stock Returns

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Determinants of the Trends in Aggregate Corporate Payout Policy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Dividends, Investment, and Financial Flexibility *

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Debt Capacity and Tests of Capital Structure Theories

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

Do Dividends Convey Information About Future Earnings? Charles Ham Assistant Professor Washington University in St. Louis

Investment, Alternative Measures of Fundamentals, and Revenue Indicators

FINANCIAL FLEXIBILITY AND FINANCIAL POLICY

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

The Effect of Matching on Firm Earnings Components

How Does Earnings Management Affect Innovation Strategies of Firms?

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

In for a Bumpy Ride? Cash Flow Risk and Dividend Payouts

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

Deregulation and Firm Investment

Firms Histories and Their Capital Structures *

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

The notion that income taxes play an important role in the

Macro Notes: Introduction to the Short Run

Investment and internal funds of distressed firms

Executive Compensation, Financial Constraint and Product Market Strategies

Inflation and the Evolution of Firm-Level Liquid Assets

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

financial constraints and hedging needs

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

The Real Business Cycle Model

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

The Effect of Financial Flexibility on Payout Policy

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Paper. Working. Unce. the. and Cash. Heungju. Park

Corporate Cash Savings: Precaution versus Liquidity

Corporate Precautionary Cash Holdings 1

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

The Long-Run Equity Risk Premium

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Journal of Corporate Finance

Financing Payouts * Martin Schmalz University of Michigan. March 31, 2015

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions

Chinese Firms Political Connection, Ownership, and Financing Constraints

Volatility and Growth: Credit Constraints and the Composition of Investment

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis

Do dividends convey information about future earnings? Charles Ham Assistant Professor Washington University in St. Louis

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-3

MIT Sloan School of Management

Market Overreaction to Bad News and Title Repurchase: Evidence from Japan.

Does Macro-Pru Leak? Empirical Evidence from a UK Natural Experiment

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

The Effects of Uncertainty and Corporate Governance on Firms Demand for Liquidity

Evaluating the Impact of Macroprudential Policies in Colombia

Financial Flexibility, Performance, and the Corporate Payout Choice*

Financial Constraints and U.S. Recessions: How Constrained Firms Invest Differently

Cash flow sensitivities and bank-finance shocks in nonlisted firms

Firms Capital Structure Choices and Endogenous Dividend Policies

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds

The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen

Investment and Financing Policies of Nepalese Enterprises

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR

Valuation of tax expense

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

Transcription:

Corporate Payout Smoothing: A Variance Decomposition Approach Edward C. Hoang University of Colorado Colorado Springs Indrit Hoxha Pennsylvania State University Harrisburg Abstract In this paper, we apply a variance decomposition methodology to quantify the smoothness of corporate payouts. We find that firms use debt and investment to smooth a large fraction of shocks to net income to keep payouts less variable. Specifically, our empirical results show that firms keep the growth of payouts relatively small and stable over time. Furthermore, our findings support theoretical work that demonstrates that the dynamics of investment and debt policy should be jointly modeled with payout policy. JEL Codes: G30, G32, G35 Keywords: Debt, Investment, Lintner Model, Net Income, Payout We would like to thank Dale DeBoer, Bart Lambrecht, Bent Sorensen, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at Carnegie Mellon University and Penn State Harrisburg for comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are our own.

1 Introduction This paper empirically examines corporate payout policy in a dynamic model that includes both investment and debt. Much of the theoretical and empirical work on corporate payout policy has taken investment and debt policies as being independent from payout policy. 1 However, the corporate finance literature conjectures that other financing decisions, such as investment and debt, may be used to balance the firm s cash flow if managers want to keep corporate payouts less variable. Although previous research has suggested that corporate payouts are smoothed, we make a further contribution to this literature by using a variance decomposition methodology to measure the smoothness of payouts along with quantifying the adjustments of debt and investment that are driven by shocks to net income. Examining the joint dynamics of investment, debt and payout policies is important for understanding firm behavior. Goel and Thakor (2003) argue that managers of firms with compensation tied to corporate earnings have an incentive to reduce the volatility of their firm s earnings stream. This suggests that managers may use mechanisms such as investment and debt policies to smooth shocks to earnings to keep the patterns of their compensation smoothed. Lambrecht and Myers (2012) draw from different agency theories to conceptualize their theoretical model of the dynamics of firm behavior, which demonstrates that managers reduce the volatility in the distribution of payouts in order to smooth their own compensation. In their model, for a given investment policy, shocks to earnings are primarily absorbed by debt financing in order to keep payouts and, hence, managerial compensation smooth. If it is the case that managers have a preference towards maintaining smooth payouts, then it is of the utmost importance to the corporate finance literature to provide empirical evidence on the matter. The setting of payout policy may reflect managerial risk preferences that in turn 1 Modigliani and Miller (1958) conjectured that in a setting with perfect capital markets, investment and debt financing decisions are made independently. Financial economists have since extended the analysis of firm behavior beyond the assumption of perfect capital markets by incorporating financial frictions in dynamic models examining the interaction between investment and debt financing. For a detailed review, see Strebulav and Whited (2012). 1

affects investment and debt financing decisions. For example, managers that prefer to avoid risk may enact less than optimal corporate policies for investment and debt (Gormley and Matsa, 2014). Therefore, measuring the response of payouts may be informative for firm risk management, investment decisions and debt policy. Using an intertemporal budget constraint formulated by Lambrecht and Myers (2012), we quantitatively describe the dynamics of firm behavior in response to shocks to net income. In their theoretical models of mature and profitable firms, Lambrecht and Myers (2012, 2014) argue that if the optimal level of investment is determined by investment opportunities and managers are motivated to keep payouts smoothed then debt policy is solely responsible for absorbing all of the variation in net income. This implies that debt policy not only absorbs all of the shocks to earnings but also smooths any marginal changes in investment to keep the optimal investment policy unresponsive to net income shocks. Furthermore, their analysis allows for the possibility that debt policy does not entirely absorb all of the shocks to net income, thus allowing unabsorbed net income shocks to be potentially smoothed by investment. For example, if positive shocks to net income reflect the availability of favorable opportunities for economic growth, managers may choose to increase investment and, therefore, net income shocks will be distributed to investment policy. In this paper, we decompose the variance in net income to estimate the fraction of shocks to net income that are absorbed by debt and investment. The amount left unabsorbed measures the response of payouts after debt and investment have smoothed shocks to net income. The empirical design of our paper uses panel data covering 6,225 public firms from the Compustat database that distributed dividends over the years 1973 2013. Our sample not only includes mature and profitable firms, but also encompasses all of the different types of non-utility and nonfinancial public firms listed in Compustat. Our findings are based on the decomposition of the variance in net income that produces the following relation: β D + β I + β P = 1, where β D and β I measure the fraction of shocks to net income absorbed by investment and debt policy, respectively; 2

β P measures the response of payouts to shocks to net income left unabsorbed by debt and investment. After estimating the components of the relation, we find that debt policy and investment absorbs 56.9% and 40.7% of shocks to net income, respectively. Payouts change by 2.4% in response to a shock to net income. The dynamics of debt, investment, and payouts reported in our study fits well with the theoretical findings in Lambrecht and Myers (2012), which shows that managers are motivated to keep payouts stable by using debt policy or investment to smooth net income shocks. In our empirical framework, if shocks to net income are entirely absorbed by debt policy and investment, then payouts should be completely smoothed (i.e., β P = 0). We show that investment and debt together absorb roughly 97.6% of shocks to net income. Since investment and debt financing both smooth a large fraction of shocks to net income, the amount left unabsorbed, 2.4%, is reflected as the change in payouts. Although we do not find complete smoothing, the relatively small change in payouts suggests that managers attempt to keep payouts less variable. We provide several additional empirical tests to demonstrate our results are robust to different exogenous settings. For example, shocks to earnings could be attributed to overall economic conditions and industry conditions that in turn would affect payout policy. Beyond our baseline model, we estimate the effects of business cycle fluctuations and capital market conditions on firm behavior, and examine the response of debt, investment, and payouts for firms in different industries. We test whether persistent shocks to net income have a larger effect on investment and payout, as predicted in Lambrecht and Myers (2014). Furthermore, we estimate our empirical model by splitting our data into different time periods, stratifying the firms into small and large size categories, grouping firms based on their age, sorting firms into external financing dependent and independent samples, and using different measures of payouts. In these specifications, the estimates of the responses of investment, debt policy, and payouts are consistent with the baseline results. The joint dynamics documented in this paper add to a small but growing literature focusing on the interaction of the three corporate financing decisions. Theoretical work provided by Hennessy 3

and Whited (2005, 2007) and DeAngelo, DeAngelo, and Whited (2011) examine the interactions of investment, debt policy, and payouts in models with taxes, and transaction and adjustment costs. Chang et al. (2014), Gatchev et al. (2010), and Ostergaard et al. (2011) decompose firm cash flow and measure the sensitivities of cash flow items such as investment, debt, and dividends. In a closely related paper, Leary and Michaely (2011) find empirical evidence of payout smoothing. We further contribute to this literature by quantifying the smoothness of payouts, which we measure as the sum of dividends and net stock repurchases, in an empirical model that also estimates the amount of variation in net income that is absorbed by investment and debt policies. In the next section, we discuss the background of the paper. Section 3 describes the empirical implementation. Section 4 presents the results. Section 5 concludes. 2 Background: Budget Constraint and Smoothing of Net Income, and Related Literature and Hypothesis 2.1 The Firm s Budget Constraint and Smoothing of Net Income To develop the foundation for our empirical analysis, we begin with considering the implications of the intertemporal budget constraint for an individual firm as described in Lambrecht and Myers (2012) (referred to as LM hereafter): Debt t + Net Income t = Investment t + P ayout t. (1) Equation (1) presents several implications for firms in a model without financial constraints. 2 If there are fluctuations to net income, the firm can adjust debt or investment to smooth net income. Debt financing is a dominant source of external funds which affects operating income flexibility and the financing of investment activities. Therefore, changes in net debt ( Debt), which is the repayment of debt, increased borrowing of funds, and changes in cash balances, can help to maintain 2 Equation (1) is extended to include managerial rents in Lambrecht and Myers (2014). 4

a balanced intertemporal budget constraint in response to changes to net income. In addition to using debt financing to smooth shocks to net income, the firm can adjust investment spending to keep the intertemporal budget constraint balanced. In their analysis, LM keep investment fixed and argue that debt is responsible for smoothing shocks to net income. However, they argue that if shocks to net income present favorable growth opportunities to the firm, managers may respond by increasing investment and, therefore, both investment and debt policy may smooth shocks to net income. These scenarios imply that payouts do not play a role in balancing the intertemporal budget constraint when there is a change to net income. Ultimately, debt financing and investment are the key mechanisms the firm can use to absorb fluctuations to net income. The conjecture that payouts are not used to smooth shocks to net income is based on the idea that payout policy follows the prediction set forth by the Lintner model (Lintner, 1956). In the Lintner model, payouts are comprised solely of dividends and firm managers infrequently make changes to payouts from year to year so that dividends paid out to shareholders satisfy a long run target. 3 However, in the LM model payouts will increase in response to shocks to net income, but this response will be larger for persistent shocks than for transitory shocks. The observation that payouts may increase is not associated with a motivation to balance the budget constraint, but to distribute more income to shareholders when firm earnings are persistent. 4 Total payouts used in the LM budget constraint includes cash dividends and stock repurchases net of equity issues. Jagannathan, Stephens and Wiesbach (2000) claim that repurchases are an important source of payouts, and a measure of payouts including both dividends and repurchases performs relatively better in following the Lintner theory of payout policy (Skinner, 2008). Therefore, the use of payouts consisting of dividends and net repurchases may support the implications of the Lintner model for payout policy. Also, a broader measure of payouts beyond dividends may 3 The Lintner Model of payouts is applied to mature firms that distributes dividends. 4 This theory is connected with the motivation to increase managerial compensation. However, we do not further investigate this relationship as it is beyond the scope of this paper. 5

make the Lintner model more relevant to contemporary firm payout policy since repurchases have supplanted dividends as the primary source of payouts to shareholders for the past 20 years. To summarize, the LM budget constraint shows that changes to debt and investment policies can bring balance to the firm s intertemporal budget constraint in response to a shock to net income. Payouts are not considered to be a mechanism used by the firm to smooth net income fluctuations but are influenced to change if shocks to net income are persistent and there is an increase in investment. An increase in investment leads to a permanent increase in net income and, therefore, there will be a new higher target for payouts. Finally, LM derive a joint theory for debt and payouts while holding investment fixed. For the purpose of our empirical analysis where we explore the smoothness of shocks to net income, we allow both debt and investment to simultaneously adjust in response to a shock to net income. 2.2 Related Literature and Hypothesis The determinants of corporate finance policies such as investment, debt and payout have been extensively studied. To begin with a model without financial frictions, Modigliani and Miller (1958) argue that firm investment depends on the ratio of the value of an additional unit of capital to its acquisition cost a ratio known as marginal q. In models with financial constraints, it has been documented that investment is sensitive to cash flow because financial frictions make external finance more expensive than internal finance. In particular, Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988), Campello, Graham, and Harvey (2010) and Campello et al. (2011) find that financially constrained firms decrease investment in response to a negative shock to cash flow. 5 Bolton, Chen and Wang (2011) develop a model which shows that the ratio of marginal q to the marginal value of cash influences investment for financially constrained firms. Generally, in models with financial frictions, the sensitivity of investment to cash flow shocks has 5 In addition to finding firm investment decreases, Campello et al. (2010, 2011) show that financially constrained firms burned more cash, drew more credit from banks, and also engaged in more asset sales in the recent financial crisis. 6

implications for debt policy. In DeAngelo, DeAngelo, and Whited (2011) and Denis and McKeon (2012), debt is used to finance investment related capital needs when there is a shortfall in cash. Specifically, firms temporarily abandon a long run leverage target in favor of increased borrowing to fund investment. In a model with financial frictions and asymmetric information, Myers and Majluf (1984) find that although firms prefer internal financing to external financing to fund investment, external financing primarily takes the form of debt. Brav, Graham, Harvey, and Michaely (2008) conduct a comprehensive survey of 384 financial executives to ascertain the determinants of payout policy. They find that payouts are preferred to be smoothed over time but will exhibit positive growth if positive earnings are persistent or investment increases. In addition, in response to an economic shock, executives prefer to use debt to absorb shortfalls in cash before making any changes to their payout policy. The structure of payout policy has changed over the past few decades where stock repurchases have come to constitute a relatively larger share of payouts. Related studies such as Brown, Liang and Weisbenner (2007) and Jagannathan, Stephens and Weisbach (2000) examine how the joint distribution of cash dividends and stock repurchases are set by firms. Surprisingly, work to tie the theories of debt, investment, and payouts into a unified corporate finance framework is lacking. LM fill this gap by developing a dynamic theory encompassing these three policy instruments. According to LM, a firm s budget constraint which follows Equation (1) suggests that a dynamic interaction between payout and investment produces debt policy. Likewise, a dynamic theory of debt and investment will yield a dynamic theory of payout. In this paper, we take the first step in empirically examining whether firm behavior is consistent with the implications of the LM budget constraint. Specifically, we attempt to quantify the amount of shocks to net income absorbed through debt and investment, while examining whether payouts are sensitive to changes in net income. Generally, there has been a strong emphasis on the effects of changes in cash flow on debt and investment, but in our analysis we focus on changes to net income. Our hypothesis is that firms absorb a substantial amount of shocks to net income through 7

the use of debt and investment and that the sensitivity of payouts to net income is relatively small. To explore our hypothesis, we use a novel variance decomposition methodology that allows us to estimate the responses of debt, investment and payouts to net income shocks. 3 Empirical Implementation: Methodology and Data The focus of this paper is to measure the variability of corporate payouts in response to shocks to net income. Specifically, in an empirical framework that incorporates all three corporate financing decisions, we measure the smoothness of payouts by estimating the amount of shocks to net income that are absorbed by investment and debt policies. In this section, we describe the empirical methodology and data used to estimate the smoothness of payouts. 3.1 Methodology Asdrubali, Sorensen and Yosha (1996) and Sorensen and Yosha (1998) develop an empirical strategy to decompose the variance of shocks to Gross Domestic Product that are absorbed by fiscal policy and private markets. We adapt this same methodology in the current paper to measure the fraction of shocks to net income (NI) that are smoothed through changes in debt and investment for 6,225 COMPUSTAT firms over the period 1973 2013. The amount of shocks to net income that are left unabsorbed in this empirical framework represents the variability in corporate payouts. We begin by considering the firm s intertemporal budget constraint developed in LM, which we then use to construct the following identity for NI: NI = NI NI + D P. (2) NI + D P In the above identity, NI stands for net income, D is the change in net debt, and P is the payout of the firm. Shocks to net income can be smoothed by corporate financing decisions such as debt policy and investment. Firms may smooth net income shocks through debt policy, which is reflected 8

by the difference between NI and NI + D. If shocks to net income are not fully smoothed by debt policy, then further smoothing can be achieved through investment, which is reflected as the difference between NI + D and P. To obtain a system of regression equations that will enable us to estimate the amount of shocks to NI absorbed by changes in debt and the level of investment, we construct a complete decomposition of the cross-sectional variance of firm net income growth. We log transform and first difference the variables in Equation (2) to express them as growth rates. Finally, we multiply both sides by log N I and take expectations of the transformed identity to obtain the following decomposition of the cross sectional variance in NI: var{ log NI} = cov{ log NI, log NI log(ni + D)} + cov{ log NI, log(ni + D) log P } + cov{ log NI, log P }. (3) Dividing both sides of Equation (3) by the variance of log NI obtains the slope coefficients from three different panel univariate regressions which sum to 1: 1 = β D + β I + β P. (4) Our estimates of net income smoothing are based on two slope coefficients, which are β D and β I. β D, the slope coefficient in the regression of log NI log(ni + D) on log NI, is represented as the percentage of smoothing of a net income shock by debt; β I, the slope coefficient in the regression of log(ni + D) log P on log NI, is represented as the percentage of smoothing of a net income shock by investment. The third slope coefficient, β P, is obtained from a regression of log P on log NI and represents the amount of shocks to NI that is left unsmoothed; specifically, it measures the sensitivity of firm payouts to shocks to NI. 9

According to a theoretical prediction in LM, if investment is held fixed and there is a preference for payout smoothing, debt absorbs all of the shocks to net income. This prediction implies that Equation (4) yields β D = 1 and β I = β P = 0. Furthermore, Lambrecht and Myers (2014) argue that once an optimal investment policy is implemented, debt policy is the main shock absorber of net income shocks and, thus, smooths the shocks in investment and payouts. Since debt smooths all of the variation in net income, the coefficient β D takes on a value of 1; the other coefficients, β I and β P, are both equal to 0 because there are no remaining shocks to be passed through to investment and payouts. However, Lambrecht and Myers (2012, 2014) allow for the possibility that both debt policy and investment can absorb net income shocks. The main purpose of our analysis is to examine the adjustments of debt and investment to keep payouts smooth in response to net income shocks. The coefficients from Equation (4) are estimated according to the following three panel regressions: log NI it log(ni + D) it = α i D + γ t D + β D log NI it + ɛ itd, (5a) log(ni + D) it log P it = α i I + γ t I + β I log NI it + ɛ iti, (5b) log P it = α i P + γ t P + β P log NI it + ɛ itp. (5c) In the above equations, i indexes firms, t indexes years, α i are firm fixed effects and γ t are year fixed effects. Since the variables in the panel equations above are expressed in growth rates we can economically interpret a hypothetical 100% increase in the growth rate of N I. According to Equation (5a), if shocks are perfectly smoothed by paying down debt, the growth rate of D is 100% which induces the term NI + D to grow at a rate of 0. A regression of log NI log(ni + D) on log NI yields the coefficient β D equal to 1 in the case where shocks to net income are completely absorbed by a policy of paying down debt. If NI increases by 100% and there is no smoothing at all at the debt level, then NI + D grows at the same rate as NI and, 10

therefore, regressing log NI log(ni + D) on log NI yields β D equal to zero. The coefficient β D represents the percentage of smoothing of a net income shock carried out by debt (i.e., through paying down debt). If debt does not fully smooth shocks to net income, then there is scope for further smoothing of the remaining shocks by changes in investment. Moving beyond Equation (5a), the next level of smoothing occurs in Equation (5b) where the dependent variable is investment which is constructed as the difference between log(ni + D) and log P ; the coefficient β I measures the incremental amount of shocks to net income that are passed through to investment. In this equation, the term P growing at the same rate as NI + D implies that there is no smoothing of shocks to net income at the investment level; therefore, regressing log(ni + D) log P on log NI yields β I equal to zero. In the event that debt policy does not completely smooth net income shocks, complete smoothing by investment will imply that β I is equal to 1 β D. In other words, if the combination of debt and investment completely smooths net income shocks then β D + β I = 1. However, if β D + β I < 1, the combination of debt and investment incompletely absorbs shocks to net income and, therefore, payout is sensitive to changes in net income. By construction of the variance decomposition equation, the sensitivity of payouts, β P, is equal to 1 β D β I. In Equation (5c), β P is estimated; this coefficient reflects the growth of payouts or percentage of net income shocks left unabsorbed. To demonstrate the economic implication of β P consider a firm that prefers not to use investment to absorb shocks to net income (i.e., β I = 0) but allows payouts (β P ) to constantly grow at 3%. This payout policy would imply that debt (β D ) absorbs 97% of shocks to net income. Finally, the coefficients β D, β I, and β P are estimated from panel regressions, which include both year and firm fixed effects. These fixed effects are included to demean each observation by its yearly mean and firm level mean to control for macroeconomic effects and firm-level unobservables. 11

3.2 Data To estimate the amount of shocks to net income absorbed by debt and investment, and the amount left unabsorbed (i.e., growth in total payout), we collect annual data on U.S. firms from the Compustat database for the period 1973 2013. Specifically, we obtain data on variables such as net income, short term and long term debt, cash balances, cash dividends, stock repurchases and equity issues. Our measure of total payout is cash dividends plus stock repurchases minus equity issues. We exclude utility firms with SIC codes between 4900 and 4999 and financial firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6999. We also collect data on US gross domestic product (GDP) and deflate our variables using the GDP price deflator, which are both obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). To reduce the potential impact of outliers, we winsorize our sample at the 1st and 99th percentiles. Our baseline sample is an unbalanced panel with 6,225 firms where we exclude firms that do not distribute cash dividends. In Panel A of Table 1, the means and standard deviations for net income, debt, investment, and payouts are reported. A correlation matrix is reported in Panel B which shows the correlation between each of the variables. 4 Results 4.1 Baseline Results In Table 2, we present our baseline results. We find that both paying down debt and increases in investment absorb 97.6% of positive shocks to net income. Specifically, 56.9% of shocks to net income are absorbed via debt and 40.7% of shocks are absorbed via investment. Our results suggest that both debt and investment play primary roles in smoothing a large fraction of shocks to net income; however, not all of the shocks to net income are smoothed. We find that a 100% increase in net income is associated with a 2.4% increase in payouts, a figure which represents the amount of shocks left unsmoothed. Our results confirm the intuition of the LM budget constraint that debt and investment are the primary mechanisms which smooth fluctuations in net income. Also, 12

payouts are sensitive to changes in net income which can be explained by increases in investment or by permanent shocks to net income. In our empirical methodology, we do not differentiate between temporary and permanent shocks to net income. However, in a later section, we extend our first difference model to longer difference intervals to capture the responses of debt, investment and payouts to permanent shocks to net income. Nevertheless, our observed pattern of debt and investment smoothing is similar to Daniel, Denis and Naveen (2010) who find that debt and investment each cover half of a shock to cash flow. Furthermore, we find that there is a relatively small but economically significant fraction of shocks to net income left unabsorbed. Specifically, our measure of payouts, which is cash dividends plus repurchases minus equity issues, increases by 2.4% in response to a shock to net income. 4.2 Controlling For Business Cycle Fluctuations and Capital Market Conditions We have established the smoothing patterns of net income, but this has been done without examining the potential effects of business cycle fluctuations and capital market conditions. In this section, we present results to show that, conditional on these aggregate measures, the patterns of smoothing of net income are robust. 4.2.1 Business Cycle Fluctuations To examine the impact of business cycle fluctuations on the smoothing of shocks to net income, we re-estimate the system of panel equations ((5a), (5b), and (5c)) by parameterizing each of the three different slope coefficients as the following: β Z = β Z,0 + β Z,1 log GDP t. (6) Z is a generic variable denoting whether the slope coefficient is a measure of smoothing via debt (D) or via investment (I), or a measure of the amount of shocks unsmoothed which reflects the 13

response of payouts (P ). GDP is US gross domestic product and changes to log GDP represent business cycle fluctuations. Multiplying both sides of Equation (6) by log NI it produces the following expression: β Z log NI it = β Z,0 log NI it + β Z,1 ( log GDP t log NI it ). (7) According to Equation (7), the slope coefficient on net income growth (β Z ) is a linear combination of the regression coefficients for the main effect term ( log NI it ) and the interaction term ( log GDP t log NI it ). 6 In the regressions, if the interaction effect captured by the coefficient β D,1 is significantly positive, this implies that positive shocks to net income will be absorbed through debt when there is positive growth in GDP. Conditional on economic growth, if β I,1 and β P,1 are statistically negative, there is dis-smoothing by investment and payouts negatively grow in response to positive net income shocks. 7 In Panel A of Table 3, we report the cyclical patterns of the channels of net income smoothing. Column 2 shows that positive shocks to net income are absorbed by debt in a procyclical manner: more debt is paid off during economic expansions and more debt is accumulated during recessions. This finding may be inconsistent with the results documented in Covas and Den Haan (2011) where it is suggested that debt issuances increase during economic expansions. But their result is conditional on holding shocks to net income constant while we find that firms pay off debt during expansions to absorb positive shocks to net income. McLean and Zhao (2014) support our finding by showing that debt issuances decrease in response to an increase in cash flow during expansions. Interestingly, the pattern of investment is found to be countercyclical with the business cycle. We find that, during expansions, firms substitute the smoothing of shocks to net income away from investment and towards paying down debt. Firms may behave in this manner to pay off debt 6 If log GDP is held constant in Equation (7), then log GDP is equal to 0 and, hence, β Z is equal to the main effect β Z,0. 7 We exclude log GDP t as a non-interacted term in Equation (7) because the inclusion of year and firm fixed effects in the decomposition equations will remove variables which are invariant along both year and firm dimensions. 14

obligations and accumulate precautionary savings which they can use to fund investment during recessions. In addition, McLean and Zhao (2013) argue that during economic expansions the cost of external financing is relatively low and, therefore, firms prefer to use external financing to fund investment. They empirically show that investment decreases in response to positive cash flow shocks during expansions. Conditional on positive shocks to net income, we find that payouts are also countercyclical with economic expansions. Lambrecht and Myers (2012) argue that there is positive comovement between payouts and investment. Therefore, since investment is found to be countercylical with the business cycle given a positive shock to net income, payouts should also be countercyclical with economic expansions. Additionally, if the cost of external financing is relatively low during expansions, firms may prefer to finance payouts out of external funds rather than internal funds. The non-interacted main effects reported in Panel A show that both debt and investment absorb roughly 97% of shocks to net income. These results are consistent with the baseline results reported in Table 2. However, during booms and busts, the channels of smoothing of net income display different patterns. We find that during expansions there is increased smoothing of net income by debt but dis-smoothing through investment. We also find that positive shocks to net income are transmitted to payouts less during the business cycle boom. 4.2.2 Capital Market Conditions We have examined the effects of macroeconomic conditions on firm behavior. However, conditions in capital markets might also affect firm behavior because they potentially influence the firm s ability to raise capital and accessibility to these markets. We apply the same methodology as in the previous section to estimate the effect of capital market conditions on firm behavior. The main variable of interest is the interaction term, where we interact net income with a measure reflecting capital market conditions, rather than GDP, in the regressions. To proxy for capital market conditions, we use the Wilshire 5000 Total Market Index. This data is a market capitalization 15

weighted index of the market value of all stocks traded in the US. We collect the annual data from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED database. 8 In Panel B of Table 3, we show that the non-interacted main effects are similar to the regressions where we control for the business cycle. Specifically, debt absorbs 53.83% of shocks to net income; investment absorbs 42.60% of shocks to net income. However, when we control for capital market conditions the elasticity of payouts is 3.57%, which is slightly larger than that reported in Panel A. Also, we find the coefficients on the interaction terms follow similar patterns to those reported in Panel A. Conditional on a positive shock to net income, when capital market conditions are relatively good, as reflected by an increase in the value of Wilshire Index, we report that debt is procyclical. Furthermore, conditional on a positive shock to net income, we find that investment and payouts are countercyclical with upturns in capital markets. Investment and payout may be countercyclical with capital market conditions because of the potential changes to the cost of external financing. During upturns in capital markets, the cost of external financing may be relatively low and, therefore, firms may use external sources to finance investment spending and payouts rather than own cash flows. 4.3 Different Sample Periods We exploit our long time series data by disaggregating the data into sub-periods. Different events such as the Great Moderation, the Great Recession and other recessionary periods, or strict and lax periods of regulation may have had an effect on the ability of firms to smooth shocks to net income. Although we do not isolate our examination of firm behavior explicitly for specific and significant events, we estimate our variance decomposition equations based on our sample period that is decomposed into time intervals. Starting with the interval between the years 1973 1982, Table 4 shows that firms absorb 53.93% 8 We use the Standard & Poor s (S&P) 500 index as an alternative proxy for capital market conditions, also. The results using the S&P 500 index in the estimations are similar to the results reported in Panel B of Table 3 which uses the Wilshire 5000 index. 16

of shocks to net income through debt and 41.08% through investment, leaving the amount of shocks unabsorbed at 4.99%, which is the elasticity of payouts to net income. In the years 1983 1992, firms are paying down more debt in response to shocks to net income and investment absorbs a larger share of shocks during this time period. The sensitivity of payouts falls to 3.42%, indicating that there are less shocks unabsorbed. We observe similar patterns of smoothing during the years 1983 1992 as for the period 1993 2006. Specifically, shocks to net income are absorbed by debt on the order of 58.90 to 59.05%, and smoothed by investment on the order of 37.67 to 39.89% between these two periods. However, because of the marginal increases in smoothing by debt and investment, the amount of shocks left unabsorbed falls from 3.42 to 1.06% between 1983 1992 and 1993 2006. Finally, in the years 2007 2013, we find that firms are using less debt but more investment to absorb shocks to net income. Also, during this period, the sensitivity of payouts, or the fraction of shocks left unabsorbed, falls to 0.85%. These results are interesting because they reveal that firms absorbed a larger share of shocks through investment than debt policy. Perhaps due to the tightening of credit in capital markets, firms preferred to use investment to promote growth in firm income in response to positive shocks to net income, which would leave them less dependent on credit in the event of future negative shocks to net income. 4.4 Varying Difference Intervals The empirical framework used in this paper constructs the one year difference of variables in logarithms to yield growth rates. We extend the empirical model beyond the one year differencing to include longer multi-year differences (k years). If firm adjustment to shocks to net income vary depending on whether the shocks are temporary or permanent, specifications with longer differences may yield estimates different from those based on shorter differences. Additionally, if the regressor is measured with error, longer differenced specifications may produce less biased estimates compared to shorter differenced estimates. Thus, as we compare elasticity estimates at 17

varying difference lengths, we take into account potential measurement errors in the regressor as well as the long-run response of the firm to more persistent shocks to net income. In Table 5, we show the baseline results along with the results from specifications differenced up to k = 10. As k increases, the fraction of smoothing at the debt level falls until it reaches 41% at the 10 year interval. In contrast, the percentage of shocks absorbed by investment increases as k increases until it reaches a peak of 48%. The fraction of shocks unsmoothed also increases as the difference interval widens. When k = 10, the amount of shocks left unsmoothed, as represented as the coefficient on payouts, is 11%. Overall, the increase in k is associated with increases in payouts; this is consistent with the prediction set forth by LM budget constraint. As the difference interval increases, the percentage of smoothing captured by debt and investment reflect long run responses. According to Lambrecht and Myers (2014), if shocks to net income are persistent, investment increases and payouts follows suit by increasing as well. They argue that as investment increases, payouts should also increase since investment leads to future profitability for the firm. According to Table 5, as k reaches 5 years, investment increases and levels out at 48%. We find that payouts follows the same pattern as investment which increases and eventually levels out. 4.5 Different Industries The effects of cash flow on corporate financing decisions may differ across different industries. As such, industry type may play a prominent role in the smoothing of shocks to net income by firms. In this section, we re-estimate our variance decomposition equations for firms in each of the 1 digit standard industrial classification (SIC) industries. We compare the patterns in the debt, investment, and payout for firms in the following five sectors: mining and construction, manufacturing, transportation, trade, and services. According to Table 6, debt policy for manufacturing firms absorbs the largest share of shocks to net income compared to other firms. Specifically, 61.12% of net income shocks are absorbed by 18

manufacturing firms. Across the other four industry sectors, the amount of shocks to net income smoothed by debt policy is on the order of 49.12 to 60.44%. Table 6 also shows that investment policy for manufacturing firms smoothes the smallest share of net income shocks. Manufacturing firms absorb 36.77% of shocks while investment policy for firms in the transportation sector smoothes 49.26% of shocks, which represents the largest share of net income shocks smoothed by investment across the five different sectors. Consistent with the baselines results reported in Table 2, we find that debt policy is the main absorber of net income shocks for all firms. The amount of shocks left unabsorbed by debt and investment policies reflects sensitivity of firm payout. Compared to the baseline result for payouts, we find that payouts for firms in the trade sector is highly sensitive to net income shocks. Payouts for trade sector firms grow by 6.78% in response to a 100% increase in net income. For the other remaining sectors, we find relatively less sensitivity in payouts with the percentage of shocks left unabsorbed ranging from 1.17 to 2.16%. It is interesting to infer why payouts in the trade sector are more sensitive compared to other firms. Foster et al. (2006) conjecture that retail trade firms attempt to grow by opening new stores rather than expanding existing stores. Perhaps to finance this expansion through the formation of new stores, retail trade firms issue relatively more payouts to attract investors. 4.6 Firm Size It is possible that cash flow may be more stable for large firms compared to small firms. Therefore, in response to net income shocks, payouts for larger firms may exhibit relatively less sensitivity to net income shocks. In this section, we explore whether payout smoothing differs among firms conditional on firm size. According to Table 7, we characterize firms as small, medium and large based on their average total assets. We classify firms as small if their total assets are in the bottom 25% of our sample, firms as medium if total assets are in the 2nd or 3rd quartile, and firms as large if total assets are in the top 25%. We find that small firms use debt to absorb a relatively larger fraction of shocks to net income. Specifically, for small firms, debt absorbs 58.25% of shocks to 19

net income while investment absorbs 36.88% of shocks to net income. The amount of shocks left unabsorbed is captured by the coefficient on β P which is 4.87%. The patterns of debt and investment for medium and large firms are similar to that for small firms. We find that for these firms, debt absorbs a large fraction of changes to net income ranging from 55.02% to 57.61%. For medium firms, investment smoothes 41.98% of shocks to net income, while investment for large firms absorbs 40.20%. In addition, we document that payouts become less sensitive to changes in net income where the growth of payouts falls from 3% to 2.19% as we move from medium to large firms. Overall, we find that the elasticity of payouts is relatively higher for smaller firms than for large firms. In response to a positive shock to net income, small firm behavior may deviate from the LM model by issuing more income to shareholders to attract new investors. Small firms may have more limited access to credit markets and thus exhibit more volatility in earnings relative to large firms. In response, shareholders might demand more income to compensate them for the risk in investing in these small firms. Once the firm s total assets grow, payouts become relatively less sensitive to shocks to net income. Our result on payout smoothing for small firms is consistent with Leary and Michaely (2011) who find reduced payout smoothing for small firms compared to larger firms. 4.7 Young Vs. Mature Firms The response of corporate payouts may differ at various stages in the life cycle of a firm. For example, aging firms may issue more payouts than recently established firms. Therefore, in contrast to young firms, mature firms may have a stronger preference to smooth payouts. In this section, we re-estimate the variance decomposition equations by splitting the data to account for firm age. We classify firms as young or mature, depending on their age relative to the date of their Initial Public Offering (IPO). Firms that have been publicly traded for ten years or less are classified as young; otherwise, firms are classified as mature. According to Table 8, young firms absorb 64.38% of shocks to net income through debt policy and investment absorbs 33.45% of shocks. In contrast, 20

the patterns of net income smoothing among mature firms is almost identical to the baseline results reported in Table 2. Specifically, debt policy absorbs 55.88% of shocks to net income and investment policy absorbs 41.72% of shocks. The growth in payouts for mature firms is slightly larger than that for young firms. Young and mature firms distribute roughly 2.17% and 2.41% of shocks to net income as payouts, respectively. The coefficient on payouts for mature firms is very similar to that reported in the baseline results. This is not surprising since the majority of the firms in our baseline sample are mature firms. However, we find that young firms smooth relatively more shocks to net income via debt, and less shocks are distributed to investment and payout. A possible reason for these findings is that young firms may be trying to pay down more debt in order to finance future investment. Therefore, debt policy for young firms will absorb relatively more shocks to net income compared to investment. Furthermore, our findings suggest that the response of payouts to net income shocks does not vary much across young and mature firms. Although the coefficient on payouts for mature firms is slightly larger than that for young firms, these coefficients are within one standard deviation of each other. Therefore, we conclude that both young and mature firms try to smooth their payouts to roughly the same extent. 4.8 External Finance: Independent Firms Vs. Dependent Firms Many studies have shown that firms in different industries utilize their cash flows differently. Firms in certain industries are in need of external finance, while other firms can raise the required funds internally to finance projects. The ability to raise the required funds internally or externally may affect the firm s payout policy. Following Rajan and Zingales (1998), we rank industries based on their external dependency and split the data sample into two categories: firms in externally dependent industries and firms in externally independent industries. The firms in the top 50% of the ranking are considered in the dependent on external finance category, and the other half in the bottom of the ranking are considered independent from external finance. Our sample in this 21

empirical test includes only manufacturing firms. According to Table 9, firms in sectors that do not depend on external financing absorb 61.19% of shocks to net income through debt policy, and 36.46% through investment policy. Firms in the sectors in need of external finance distribute 61.25% of a shock to net income to debt policy and 36.85% to investment policy. There is a slight difference in the smoothing of payouts where firms independent of external finance have their payouts grow by 2.35% in response to a shock to net income. Further, payouts grow by 1.9% for firms in need of external finance. Firms dependent on external financing might have a relatively lower percentage of net income shocks left unabsorbed compared to independent firms as they may want to pay down more debt to increase their creditworthiness and to increase investment to become more profitable in the future which will enable them to continue to have access to external funds. 4.9 Different Measures of Payout In our estimations, we use a sample of firms that distribute dividends to shareholders. For these firms, we construct a measure of payout which includes both dividends and net stock repurchases. In Table 10, we examine the fraction of shocks to net income absorbed using different measures of payouts in our specifications. In Column (1), the data sample is restricted to firms that issue dividends and the measure of payouts consist of only dividends. For firms that distribute only dividends (excluding net repurchases), debt and investment respectively absorb 56.61% and 42.86% of shocks to net income. The response of dividends to shocks to net income left unabsorbed is relatively small; a 100% increase in net income is associated with a 0.53% increase in payouts. In Column (2), the data sample is restricted to firms that do not issue dividends, and the measure of payouts consists of only net repurchases. For firms that only issue or buy back corporate stocks, the responses of debt and investment to shocks to net income are similar to those reported in Column (1); in addition, net repurchases increase by 0.87% in response to a 100% increase in net income, which is slightly larger than the growth of dividends in Column (1). 22

In Columns (3), (4), and (5), all firms available in the dataset without our baseline restrictions are used in the sample to re-estimate the baseline model based on different measures for payouts. In Column (3), we find that when payouts are only comprised of dividends, debt absorbs 57.69% of shocks to net income and investment absorbs 42.13% of shocks. Also, we find that the fraction left unabsorbed is 0.18%. In Column (4), which considers firm payouts that are only comprised of repurchases, firms use debt and investment to respectively absorb 57.47% and 40.9% of shocks to net income. Payouts increase by 1.64% in response to a 100% increase in net income. Finally, in Column (5), where only firms whose payouts consist of both dividends and repurchases are considered, the patterns of debt, investment, and payouts found are similar to those contained in Column (4). 5 Conclusion In this paper, we extend the literature on corporate governance by applying a variance decomposition methodology to evaluate the financial adjustments firms make in response to changes in net income. Based on the theories proposed by Lambrecht and Myers (2012, 2014), we decompose the variance in net income to quantify the amount of shocks to net income absorbed by investment and debt policy. In our baseline results, firms use debt policy and investment to respectively absorb 56.9% and 40.7% of shocks to net income. Payouts, which is another important decision firms make in this adjustment process, grow by 2.4% in response to a positive shock to net income. Our findings conform with the predictions set forth by Lambrecht and Myers (2012, 2014) in that firms will maintain smooth payouts by using investment and debt policy to absorb shocks to net income. In addition, the findings in this paper support the conclusions of Daniel, Denis, and Naveen (2010) that firms use primarily investment and debt policy to absorb financial shocks while making relatively small adjustments to payouts. Overall, these results suggest that managers have an incentive to keep adjustments to payouts small while allowing investment and debt policy to absorb most of the shocks to net income. Our conceptual and methodological contributions 23