Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti *

Similar documents
The implementation of monetary and fiscal rules in the EMU: a welfare-based analysis

Univ. Of Ghana ECON 212: ELEMENTS OF ECONOMICS GDP AND THE PRICE LEVEL IN THE LONG RUN Dr. Priscilla T. Baffour

FISCAL POLICY COOPERATION IN EMU: LITERATURE REVIEW

EMU G overnance: Governance: Fiscal Fiscal Policy

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Yves Mersch: The interplay between monetary policy and fiscal policy in EMU

Council of the European Union Brussels, 16 January 2017 (OR. en) General Secretariat of the Council

FISCAL POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION: HOW CAN FISCAL DISCIPLINE BE ACHIEVED? ***

What we know about monetary policy

Ryerson University Department of Economics ECN 204 MidtermTwo W12. Name: Student No:

The Economist March 2, Rules v. Discretion

L-6 The Fiscal Multiplier debate and the eurozone response to the crisis. Carlos San Juan Mesonada Jean Monnet Professor University Carlos III Madrid

EMU's Fiscal Rules and Economic Stabilization. Abstract

Implementation of the EU fiscal governance framework: Assessment of the fiscal stance appropriate for the euro area

ETUC Position Paper: A European Treasury for Public Investment

Fiscal policy coordination in the European Monetary Union. Lecture Udine May 30. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo. University of Teramo Faculty of Communication

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

Ms Hessius comments on the inflation target and the state of the economy in Sweden

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

The reform of EU s fiscal rules: between centralisation and decentralisation

The Coordination of Fiscal Policies in Europe


IMPROVING FISCAL MANAGEMENT IN GHANA: THE ROLE OF FISCAL POLICY RULES

Financial Integration in the Arab Region: A Focus on Monetary Coordination and a Presentation of New Ideas and Developments by:

Budgetary policy in EMU: times to change?

Brussels, COM(2016) 727 final. ANNEXES 1 to 2 ANNEXES. to the

A Fiscal Union in Europe: why is it possible/impossible?

THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN: CONSTITUTIONAL LIMITS AND THE NEW PUBLIC SPENDING GROWTH RULE

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

The EFB: the first year

Fiscal stabilisation and EMU. A discussion paper

ENGLISH SUMMARY Chapter I: Economic Outlook

Official Journal of the European Union L 140/11

Growth and inflation in OECD and Sweden 1999 and 2000 forecast Percentage annual change

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

Use the following to answer question 15: AE0 AE1. Real expenditures. Real income. Page 3

Monetary Policy in a New Environment: The U.S. Experience

Demand, Money and Finance within the New Consensus Macroeconomics: a Critical Appraisal

The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union

Mr. Bäckström explains why price stability ought to be a central bank s principle monetary policy objective

Discussion Papers. Tilman Brück, Andreas Cors, Klaus F. Zimmermann and Rudolf Zwiener

EUROPEA U IO. Brussels, 26 April 2013 (OR. en) 2011/0386 (COD) PE-CO S 6/13 ECOFI 163 UEM 38 CODEC 463 OC 109

Fiscal policies and economic growth

Macroeconomic stabilisation policies in the EMU: Spillovers, asymmetries, and institutions

Fragility of Incomplete Monetary Unions

7569/18 DA/NT/fh DGG 1A

The Stability and Growth Pact: A Discussion Paper. March 2004

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

1. When the Federal government uses taxation and spending actions to stimulate the economy it is conducting:

Economic analysis from the European Commission s Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs

Kiel Institute for World Economics. Macroeconomic Policy Coordination in Europe an Agnostic View

South Africa loses investment grade (IG) status on anticipated unfavourable policy shifts


Fiscal Policy - the basics:

ARTICLES FISCAL POLICY INFLUENCES ON MACROECONOMIC STABILITY AND PRICES

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW

Automatic Stabilizers at Euro Zone Level

15070/16 ADB/mz 1 DG B 1C

COMMISSION OPINION. of on the Draft Budgetary Plan of Italy and requesting Italy to submit a revised Draft Budgetary Plan

SCOTLAND S ECONOMIC FUTURE POST-2014 SUBMISSION FROM PROFESSOR ANTON MUSCATELLI

Global Macroeconomic Policy Implications of an Enlarged EMU

Fiscal policy in the goods market. Screen 1

Sovereign Debt Management, Fiscal Vulnerabilities and Monetary Policy Interaction Alessandro Missale University of Milan

Macroeconomic Management in a Constrained Fiscal Environment. Dr. Louis Kasekende Deputy Governor Bank of Uganda

Economic analysis from the European Commission s Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs. By Aleksander Rutkowski*

COMMISSION OPINION. of on the Draft Budgetary Plan of Portugal. {SWD(2017) 525 final}

A review of the surplus target, SOU 2016:67

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EURO AND FISCAL POLICY. Antonio Fatas Ilian Mihov. Working Paper

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Slovakia. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty

Lecture 15. Fiscal Policy and the Stability Pact

Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the 2014 Draft Budget Act

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Jean-Claude Trichet: Reforming EMU time for bold decisions

Fiscal issues and central bank policy in the Czech Republic

Automatic Fiscal Stabilizers

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Fiscal frameworks in Europe: Striking the right balance between centralisation and decentralisation

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Box 2 Lessons to be drawn from the oil price shocks of the 1970s and early 1980s

Stability and Growth Pact: An Index to Trigger an Early Warning Earlier? Thierry Warin. January 2005

Lorenzo Bini Smaghi: Reflections on the exit strategy

IP/09/273. Brussels, 18 February 2009

Topic 4: AS-AD Model Dealing with longer run; more variance; look at the role of wages and prices

Market Reforms in a Monetary Union: Macroeconomic and Policy Implications

Karnit Flug: Macroeconomic policy and the performance of the Israeli economy

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Practice Problems

Svein Gjedrem: The role of the Central Bank

Pre-Test Chapter 9 ed17

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION

Svein Gjedrem: Inflation targeting in an oil economy

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

TOPIC 1: IS-LM MODEL...3 TOPIC 2: LABOUR MARKET...23 TOPIC 3: THE AD-AS MODEL...33 TOPIC 4: INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT...41 TOPIC 5: MONETARY POLICY

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL. on the effective enforcement of budgetary surveillance in the euro area

Comments on Stefan Niemann and Jürgen von Hagen: Coordination of monetary and fiscal policies: A fresh look at the issue Anna Larsson *

An Introduction to Basic Macroeconomic Markets

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Common principles on national fiscal correction mechanisms

Transcription:

SWEDISH ECONOMIC POLICY REVIEW 8 (2001) 99-105 Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti * A classic result in the literature on strategic analysis in macroeconomics is that, in the event of a symmetric shock, each country acting alone tends to over-react, because it will proceed on the assumption that the other country will take no action. Take the case of a negative shock. Non-coordination implies that fiscal authorities do not take into account that they will benefit from the leakage of the fiscal expansion in other countries via foreign trade. Hence, domestic and foreign demand add up, resulting in an excessive fiscal boost, which would have been prevented had governments coordinated their policies. In contrast, no sizeable gains from coordination arise in the event of country-specific shocks. In their most startling result, Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen (hereafter BDK) turn this conventional wisdom on its head: policy coordination improves social welfare under asymmetric shocks, but would most likely be counter-productive in the event of symmetric shocks. The key reasons for this finding are three elements: Rogoff s (1985) theorem on the potentially negative impact of coordination among a subset of actors (in this case the two fiscal authorities, leaving out the common central bank); instrument smoothing, which implies that there is a cost for the government in departing from the preferred level of the cyclically-adjusted budget balance (a position that should be close to balance or in surplus, according to the Stability and Growth Pact SGP) and for the central bank in changing the interest rate; and, finally, the assumption that using the budget deficit for smoothing the cycle carries a cost not only for the government but for society as a whole. In the case of a symmetric negative shock, BDK s story goes as follows. Unlike the traditional case sketched out above, an expansionary policy is costly for the government because it implies moving away from the preferred budget position. If national authorities coordinate their actions, they will be able to internalise the positive effects on the partner country in setting domestic fiscal policy and thereby be * Marco Buti is economic adviser to the President of the European Commission. 99

more willing to accept changes in the budget deficit. This leads to a more active response to the shock under coordination, but will also affect monetary policy. Here, the nature of the shock is important. In the event of a demand shock which implies a fall in inflation and a negative output gap monetary and fiscal authorities have the same goal because stabilising output is tantamount to stabilising inflation. Hence, the central bank will free-ride on the stabilisation provided by fiscal authorities and loosen monetary policy by less than would otherwise be the case. In the event of supply shocks which cause output and inflation to move in opposite directions the stronger fiscal response under fiscal coordination will exacerbate the conflict between price and output stability and entail a stronger offsetting reaction of monetary policy. In either case, fiscal coordination may turn out to be counter-productive. The opposite holds in the event of country-specific shocks, where the adverse reaction of the central bank would not take place or be limited. BDK s result in the case of a symmetric negative demand shock is illustrated in Figure 1. Figure 1. Fiscal policy reactions under a negative shock d s * B FP FP* E N 0 B* d s Lines FP and FP* are the reaction functions of the two fiscal authorities in the instrument space (the cyclically-adjusted deficits, d s and d s *), which show how the deficit in one country depends on that in the other. The reaction functions are upward-sloping, because we take the case of monetary spillovers, dominating the direct foreign trade 100

spillovers, which implies that the two fiscal policies are complements. 1 A negative demand shock will shift the two reaction functions as indicated in the diagram, since it becomes optimal to pursue more expansive fiscal policies. Following the shock both countries will enact an expansionary fiscal policy under non-coordination and the new equilibrium will be E N. As discussed above, since governments internalise the positive demand effect on each other, they will run a more expansionary fiscal policy under fiscal policy coordination than under noncoordination. Where will the new cooperative equilibrium lie? That depends on the relative negotiating power of the two governments. Clearly, each country prefers to be as close as possible to its bliss point (B for the domestic country and B* for the foreign country), where its structural balance remains unchanged and the whole fiscal response falls on the other country. The new equilibrium will be a point on the contract curve BB*. At the opposite side of the spectrum, if, instead of pursuing active fiscal management, the two countries simply let automatic stabilisers play, the initial equilibrium does not change. As will be discussed below, this behaviour would be in line with the non-activist fiscal philosophy of the SGP. Coordination may well entail higher stabilisation of inflation and output than non-coordination which is indeed the case in most of BDK s numerical examples but this is achieved by a larger use of the socially costly instrument the budget deficit thereby implying a possible welfare loss. As shown by BDK, in case fiscal authorities play Stackelberg leaders vis-à-vis the central bank (which means that they take into account the ensuing monetary reaction in deciding the fiscal stance), the equilibrium will be close to E N. Since fiscal coordination implies that the two fiscal authorities behave as one, BDK s analysis is complementary to that of Buti et al. (2001), who examine the implications of coordination between fiscal and monetary policy in a single-country setting. That paper finds that fiscal-monetary coordination is beneficial in the event of supply shocks, since it reduces the movements of monetary and fiscal policies in the opposite direction. The paper also finds that the gains from monetary-fiscal coordination, if any, are limited in the event of demand shocks where both policies move in the same direction. Although Buti et al. (2001) consider the welfare loss of the policy authorities and not the social loss as is the case in BDK s analysis, 1 See Figure 4 in BDK s article. 101

some tentative conclusions can nonetheless be drawn on the likely benefits of coordination. Taking the two papers together, one would conclude that, in the case of symmetric shocks, Stackelberg fiscal leadership is likely to give a better social outcome under demand shocks, while full coordination between fiscal and monetary policies would be preferable when shocks originate on the supply side. In either case, fiscal policy coordination alone may not create welfare gains as compared to non-coordination. 1. Does the model capture core EMU features? Steadystate versus transition BDK s model implicitly applies to a steady state of the EMU: countries are close to balance or in surplus, according to the SGP, and have sufficient room for manoeuvre to run fiscal policies without infringing on the three per cent of GDP deficit ceiling. Monetary policy has also earned high anti-inflationary credibility. However, in the early years of EMU, when countries remain too close to the three per centof-gdp deficit limit and the ECB is still building its anti-inflationary reputation, the situation may be different. Take once more the case of a negative symmetric demand shock. Following upon the drop in output, fiscal policy becomes expansionary and, as a direct response to the shock, monetary policy will relax. However, if the initial budgetary position was too close to the deficit ceiling, a fiscal loosening may shift the deficit into the credibility danger zone, which may prompt the newly-created ECB to respond by increasing the interest rate. If so, the non-cooperative equilibrium would be characterised by higher budget deficits and a restrictive monetary stance. Given the credibility effect attached to the deficit ceiling, monetary policy may then be more restrictive than without a Pact. Barring ex ante coordination between monetary and fiscal authorities, a better outcome would be achieved if the fiscal authorities played Stackelberg leaders and, anticipating the reaction of the ECB, enacted a coordinated fiscal tightening which would allow a substantial drop in the interest rate. The case against non-cooperative behaviour is even stronger when a supply shock gives rise to a trade-off between output and inflation stabilisation and hence, creates a potentially serious policy conflict. 102

The SGP can be seen as a coordination device for reducing the likelihood of such a conflict and attaining a favourable policy mix at the outset of EMU: as stressed by Allsopp and Vines (1996, p. 99), only if all (countries) act together will the monetary offset to fiscal tightening be likely to eventuate. Thus, participating governments will not only want to commit themselves, they will want to impose commitment on others as well. Without such a common undertaking, the likelihood of an over-restrictive monetary stance would increase. The experiences of the Asian crisis in 1999 and, to some extent, the oil price hike in 2000 seem to be in line with this early years story (Buti and Sapir, 2002). 2. Active fiscal policies versus automatic stabilisers In BDK s model, countries use fiscal policy to fine tune aggregate demand. The underlying philosophy of the SGP is different. According to the Pact, countries should set appropriate medium-term targets and let automatic stabilisers play symmetrically over the business cycle. As a consequence, the implicit model of fiscal policy coordination is one of negative or pre-emptive coordination, whose main task is the surveillance of compliance with the announced national budgetary targets and consolidation efforts. In line with much of the recent literature, the SGP reflects a sceptical view of active fiscal management, which is undermined by model uncertainty implying long and uncertain impact lags; the risk of procyclical behaviour due to cumbersome parliamentary approval and implementation; irreversibility of spending decisions leading to ratcheting up of public spending; and supply-side inefficiency linked to excessive volatility of tax rates. In other words, fiscal fine tuning would not only enter the social loss function, but would also have an economic cost. While the BDK model is not suitable to account for these concerns, it is still instructive to compare the social effects of optimising governments to those of a neutral fiscal policy. 2 In the baseline parameter setting, active fiscal management makes it possible to attain higher welfare in the event of demand shocks, regardless of the colour of the government. However, in the case of supply shocks, the simple operation of automatic stabilisers is preferable to an active fiscal policy from a social welfare standpoint if the government is liberal 2 As previously pointed out, this is represented by point 0 in Figure 1. 103

(and only marginally worse in the case of a representative government). The result of numerical simulations under supply shocks and a liberal government is even starker if the latter is characterised not only by a lower weight on inflation in its loss function, but also by a lower weight on the deficit. 3 All in all, and taking into account the above concerns about active fiscal management, a neutral budgetary stance may lead to a better social outcome, especially if supply shocks tend to dominate. 3. In sum In spite of the limitations of their model, BDK provide an interesting contribution to a growing literature on macroeconomic coordination in the EMU. Their result that partial coordination may not necessarily be welfare-improving could well apply also in other areas of the EMU policy game. 3 The authors find that excluding inflation in the loss function of a liberal government implies less activist fiscal policy in the event of demand shocks. However, a liberal government is better characterised by a lower weight on both inflation and deficit relative to output stabilisation. Calculations kindly performed by the authors of the paper show that if a liberal government is described by θ = 4 instead of θ = 2, Nash coordination implies a more active fiscal policy than non-coordination. Hence, as in the other cases in BDK s simulations, coordinated fiscal policies are welfare-reducing. 104

References Allsopp, C. and Vines, D. (1996), Fiscal policy and EMU, National Institute Economic Review 158, 91-107. Buti, M. and Sapir, A. (2002), EMU in the early years: differences and credibility, in M. Buti, and A. Sapir (eds.), EMU and Economic Policy in Europe Challenges of the Early Years, Edward Elgar Publisher, UK, forthcoming. Buti, M., Roeger, W. and in t Veld, J. (2001), Stabilising output and inflation: policy conflicts and coordination under a stability pact, Journal of Common Market Studies 39, 801-28. Rogoff, K. (1985), Can international monetary policy coordination be counterproductive?, Journal of International Economics, 18, 199-217. 105