Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

Similar documents
Income Disparity, Uneven Economic Opportunities, and Verifiability. Masayuki Otaki (Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo)

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

A NOTE ON THE DYNAMIC ROLE OF MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION IN THE MONETARY ECONOMY. abstract

Monetary Theory and Policy. Fourth Edition. Carl E. Walsh. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

The Real Business Cycle Model

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Real Business Cycle Model

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Analysis of Business Cycles II : The Supply Side of the Economy

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Credit, externalities, and non-optimality of the Friedman rule

The science of monetary policy

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

1 Dynamic programming

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Macroeconomics and finance

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03a) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

On the new Keynesian model

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Overshooting of Exchange Rate and New Open Economy Macroeconomics : Some Implications for Japanese Yen and Korean Won

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University, Nishinomiya , Hyogo, Japan;

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

INDIAN HILL EXEMPTED VILLAGE SCHOOL DISTRICT Social Studies Curriculum - May 2009 AP Economics

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

Intermediate Macroeconomics, Sciences Po, Answer Key to Problem Set 10 Dynamic Micro-founded Macro Model

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

A Double Counting Problem in the Theory of Rational Bubbles

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

PROBLEM SET 6 New Keynesian Economics

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Models of the Neoclassical synthesis

Macroeconomics: Fluctuations and Growth

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 15 Problem 3 / 15 Problem 4 / 20 Problem 5 / 25 TOTAL / 100

Macroeconomics Review Course LECTURE NOTES

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

ADVANCED MODERN MACROECONOMICS

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

The New Keynesian Model

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

Characterization of the Optimum

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

Asset-price driven business cycle and monetary policy

Econ 3029 Advanced Macro. Lecture 2: The Liquidity Trap

Transcription:

DBJ Discussion Paper Series, No.1005 Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view Masayuki Otaki (Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo) and Yoshihiro Tamai (Faculty of Economics, Kanagawa University) January 2011 Discussion Papers are a series of preliminary materials in their draft form. No quotations, reproductions or circulations should be made without the written consent of the authors in order to protect the tentative characters of these papers. Any opinions, findings, conclusions or recommendations expressed in these papers are those of the authors and do not reflect the views of the Institute.

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view Masayuki Otaki (University of Tokyo) Yoshihiro Tamai (Kanagawa University) JEL Classification Numbers: E21; E24; E31 Keywords: Phillips Curve under Complete Markets; Intergenerational Learning by Doing; Welfare Improving Macroeconomic Policy

Abstract Assuming that the labor productivity varies with the previous employment level, we derive the Phillips curve based on the standard dynamic microeconomic foundation. The usage of the term standard implies that our theory entirely excludes the assumptions unfamiliar with microeconomics such as price or information stickiness, and money in the utility function. We find that when labor productivity decreases, disinflation advances. This is because disinflation, ceteris paribus, limits the current goods supply and increases the rate of return on money (the inverse of the inflation rate) in an overlapping generations (OLG) model. In addition, mass unemployment becomes a hazard for the intergenerational skill transformation, and thus, the higher the unemployment is, the lower the labor productivity becomes in the stationary state. Consequently, the negative correlation between inflation and unemployment emerges even in the dynamic general equilibrium in complete markets. It is also noteworthy that we depend neither on linear approximations nor on numerical methods: the method used to derive the Phillips curve is purely analytical.

1 Introduction Every work on the Phillips curve presumes some market imperfection. For example, Lucas (1972) assumes that the equilibrium price is a noisy signal disturbed by monetary shocks. Calvo (1983) and Woodford (1996) stochastically confine the opportunity of price realignment. Mankiw and Reis (2002) insist that there exist some substantial diffusive lags that inform about the necessity of price revision. These works imply that if there does not exist some price stickiness assumption or imperfect information (that is, the markets are complete), the negative correlation between inflation and unemployment will disappear, and the vertical Phillips curve will reemerge as Friedman (1968) suggests. This also means that money is neutral in the long run, when all adjustments are complete. Our main concern in this article is to construct the stationary negative correlation between inflation and unemployment in certainty without price frictions. This would not only enable us to interpret the Phillips curve as the long-run trade off relationship like in the original work (Phillips (1958)) but also contribute toward shortening the gulf between macroeconomic and microeconomic theory. The change in the labor productivity due to the learning effect plays a crucial role in this paper. Although recently, the focus with regard to the Phillips curve has been on the responses of inflation and unemployment to a monetary shock, the effect of a real shock (namely, the change in the labor productivity rate) should also be seriously considered. Hayashi and Prescott (2002) reveal that significant declines in the total factor productivity (TFP) and hours worked were observed in Japan during the 1990s. It is also noteworthy that disinflation was prominent throughout that decade, despite the easy monetary policy. The decline in the labor productivity, which partially consists of the TFP, results in disinflation in the deterministic overlapping generations (OLG) model of Otaki (2007, 2009), even if we do not make any price stickiness 1

assumption a priori. When the labor productivity is lowered, ceteris paribus, the current goods supply is reduced, and this increases the rate of return on money (the inverse of the inflation rate). Thus, the decline in the labor productivity is accompanied by disinflation. The same mechanism intertemporal substitution is also adopted by Lucas (1972). We further assume that skills nurtured through production process transmits to the child generation, and that the more employment opportunities are offered to fathers, the more productive children become. It is considered to be based on the enlargement of the educational opportunity by the increase of income, and on, perhaps unintentional, educational effect in a family. To sum up, the current labor productivity is assumed to be the increasing function of the previous employment level. In stationary states, where the employment level is kept constant, the lower the employment level is, the fewer individuals are productive. Consequently, there emerges the negative correlation between the inflation and unemployment rate. This is our understanding on the long-run Phillips curve or the aggregate supply curve under complete markets. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 exhibits the basic model. The Phillips curve is also derived. Section 3 deals with the economic welfare implications of the expansionary fiscal-monetary policy. Section 4 contains brief concluding remarks. 2 Model 2.1 Model Structure We consider a standard two-period OLG model. There exist continuous individuals [0, 1] [0, 1]. They supply labor at their discretion only when they are young. Each firm monopolistically produces the differentiated good that is distributed within [0, 1]. The monopoly rent is equally distributed among the young regardless of their employment status. 2

Fiat money is the only store of value. The government finances its expenditure by seigniorage. For simplicity, we assume that the goods purchased by the government bear no additional utility to the individuals. 2.2 Individuals Each individual maximizes the following lifetime utility function: U = u(c 1 t, C 2 t+1) δ t α, C i j [ 1 0 c i j(z) 1 η 1 dz ] 1 1 η 1, (1) where c i j(z) denotes the consumption of good z by the individuals in the ith stage of life during period j. α is the disutility of labor. δ t is a definition function that takes the values one (when employed) and zero (when unemployed). In addition, we assume that u( ) is a linear homogenous function. Then, the indirect utility function H of u is represented as H(P t, P t+1, δ t W t + Π t ) = [δ tw t + Π t ] h(p t, P t+1 ), P t [ 1 0 p t (z) 1 η dz ] 1 1 η, (2) where W t is the nominal wage and Π t is the aggregate nominal monopoly rent. We must note that h is also linear homogenous. Using (2), we can calculate the nominal reservation wage W R t W R t = α h(p t, P t+1 ). (3) Since our main concern is the imperfect employment equilibrium where some individuals are always unemployed and possess no bargaining power, W R t becomes the equilibrium nominal wage. However, the nominal wage might exceed the reservation wage when the individuals possess collective bargaining power. Nevertheless, as long as the nominal wage negotiation is efficient in the sense of McDonald and Solow (1981), there is no need to discuss any modification. See Otaki (2009) for the precise proof. It is also noteworthy that the following aggregate consumption function of the younger generation C 1 t is obtained from the linear homogeneity of u: Ct 1 c(ρ)[ W t R L t + Π t ] c(ρ) Y t, (4) P t P t P t 3 as

where ρ( P t+1 /P t ) denotes the gross inflation rate. employment level. L t is the aggregate 2.3 Firms From (1), each firm faces the following identical aggregate demand function D t (z): D t (z) = ( p t (z)) η W [ t R L t + Π t ], (5) P t P t P t where L t is the aggregate employment level. Furthermore, we assume that each firm z has the following identical production function y s t (z): y s t (z) = γ(l t 1 )L t (z), γ > 0. (6) γ is the function of the productivity of labor, which plays a key role in our comparative statics. (6) implies that there is a socially significant learning effect in the productivity of labor. Namely, when the more individuals who belong to the previous generation are employed and more skills for production are socially accumulated, the easier they are transmitted to the current generation.this is considered to be an overlapping-generations model version of Arrow s (1962) learning by doing. rule: The profit maximization problem leads us to the following optimal pricing p t (z) = W R t γ(l t 1 )[1 η 1 ] = α h(p t, P t+1 ) γ(l t 1 )[1 η 1 ]. (7) Aggregating (7) on z, we obtain the following important difference equation: P t = α h(p t, P t+1 ) γ(l t 1 )[1 η 1 ]. (8) From the linear homogeneity of h, Eq.(8) determines the equilibrium inflation rate ρ independent of the nominal money supply. Differentiating (8) logarithmically and using Roy s identity, we obtain (1 c) dρ ρ = Lγ dl γ L ν dl, 0 < c < 1, (9) L 4

where ν is the elasticity of the labor productivity to the employment level. The left-hand side of Eq.(9) indicates the number of future goods that can be substituted for present goods when inflation occurs. From Eq.(9), it is clear that the inflation rate ρ is determined so as to equalize the additional present aggregate supply ν dl to the additional L demand for present goods (1 c) dρ. Namely, an improvement in the labor ρ productivity implies a potential increase in the current consumption level; this advances inflation and reduces the rate of return on money to decrease savings. 2.4 Government In this model, the role of the government is very simple. It issues new money, M t M t 1, to finance wasteful expenditure G t. Avoiding any diversion from the stationary equilibrium, we assume that the expenditure is controlled so as to keep the real money stock m M t P t, constant over time. Hence, the budget constraint of the government can be written as g G t+j P t+j = M t+j M t+j 1 P t+j = m m ρ. (10) 2.5 Market Equilibrium 2.5.1 The Aggregate Demand Function Since our attention is confined to the imperfect employment equilibrium in stationary state, the labor markets are in equilibrium whenever W t = W R t and L t = L t 1. The real aggregate demand y is defined as y = c(ρ)y + g + m ρ = c(ρ)y + m, y Y P, (11) where the third term of Eq.(11) is the consumption demand of the old individuals. Because every equilibrium is stationary in the sense that it is independent of time t, we abbreviate the subscripts. This is the dynamically extended multiplier process developed by Otaki (2007, 2009). Solving 5

Eq.(11), we obtain y = m 1 c(ρ(l)). (12) (12) is the aggregate demand function of our model. It can be easily seen that an expansionary fiscal-monetary policy increases the real GDP as long as the inflation rate is kept constant. 2.5.2 The Aggregate Supply Function: The Phillips Curve We have already established the negative correlation between inflation and unemployment in 2.3. Phillips curve is implicitly defined by Eq. (9). Consequently, the Phillips curve is obtained as illustrated by Curve AS in Figure 1. 2.5.3 Market Equilibrium The good market equilibrium is expressed by the solution of (8) and (12). It is illustrated by Figure 2. Although the slope of the aggregate demand function AD in (L, ρ) plain is ambiguous, a sufficient stability condition of the stationary state E is that Curve AD cuts AS from the downward. It implies that the intertemporal substitution rate on consumption is positive but not too high. From empirical analyses, (For example, see Hansen and Singleton (1983) and Campbell and Mankiw (1989)) it does not seem so restrictive assumption, and hence, we assume that the stationary state is stable. The fiscal-monetary policy can only control the location of the aggregate demand curve (12). Namely, fiscal-monetary expansion results in a rightward parallel shift in the aggregate demand curve. This implies that a discretionary expansion in the fiscal-monetary policy can increase the real GDP y together with accelerating inflation. 6

3 The Welfare Implication of Fiscal-Monetary Policy Since the indirect lifetime utility is represented by Eq.(2), considering that the labor supply is never in surplus, the social welfare SW is defined as SW (L) Π t h(p t, P t+1 ) = αη 1 h( ) [1 η 1 ]h( ) L = αη 1 L. (13) 1 η 1 Let us analyze the welfare implication of our macroeconomic policy in the imperfect employment equilibrium. The result can be easily obtained from Figure 2 and Eq.(13). From Figure 2, it is apparent that the real money supply m increases the real GDP y and employment level L. Accordingly, Eq.(13) reveals that the social welfare is always enhanced by an expansionary fiscal-monetary policy. 4 Concluding Remarks We have developed the microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets. The obtained results are as follows. First, the Phillips curve can be derived not from a monetary shock but from an endogenous structure of the economy per se. Whenever the labor productivity increases, inflation rises. This is because the current consumption needs to be stimulated in accordance with the potential increase in the production capacity. Hence, the rate of return on money decreases, and the inflation rate increases. Thus, a positive correlation between the labor productivity and inflation emerges. On the other hand, the lower labor productivity is reproduced by itself. Namely, the mass unemployment of the previous generation deprives the formal and informal educational opportunity from the current generation. Thereby, the lower employment level causes the lower labor productivity. Thus, the stationary negative correlation between the inflation and unemployment emerges even under complete markets. 7

Second, as long as the stationary state is stable, an expansionary policy can raise the real GDP and improve the social welfare. This is because the expansionary policy increases the real GDP by the multiplier process and improves the labor productivity through the reduction of the unemployment level. 8

ρ AS O Figure 1: The Phillips Curve L 9

ρ AD AS E O Figure 2: Market Equilibrium L 10

References [1] Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing.review of Economic Studies, 155-173. [2] Calvo, G. A. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 383-398. [3] Campbell, J. Y. and Mankiw, N. G. (1989). Consumption, income, and interest rates: reinterpreting the time series evidence. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 4, 185-216. [4] Friedman, M. (1968). The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review, 1-17. [5] Hansen, L. P. and Singleton, K. J. (1983). Stochastic consumption, eisk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy, 249-265. [6] Hayashi, F. and Prescott, E. C. (2002). The 1990s in Japan: a lost decade. Review of Economic Dynamics, 206-235. [7] Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 103-124. [8] Mankiw, N. G. and Reis, R. (2002). Sticky information versus sticky prices: a proposal to replace the new Keynesian Phillips curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1295-1328. [9] McDonald, I. M. and Solow, R. M. (1981). Wage bargaining and employment. American Economic Review, 896-908. [10] Otaki, M. (2007). The dynamically extended Keynesian cross and the welfare-improving fiscal policy. Economics Letters, 23-29. [11] Otaki, M. (2009). A welfare economics foundation for the fullemployment policy. Economics Letters, 1-3. 11

[12] Phillips, A. W. (1958). The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957. Economica, New Series, 283-299. [13] Woodford, M. (1996). Control of the public debt: A requirement for price stability? NBER Working Papers: 5684. 12