Can P* Be a Basis for Core Inflation in the Philippines?

Similar documents
Comparing GDP in Constant and in Chained Prices: Some New Results

The Demand for Money in China: Evidence from Half a Century

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

An Investigation into the Sensitivity of Money Demand to Interest Rates in the Philippines

P-STAR-MODEL BASED ANALYSIS OF INFLATION DYNAMICS IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC. Jan Frait, Luboš Komárek, Lumír Kulhánek * Abstract

CAN MONEY SUPPLY PREDICT STOCK PRICES?

The relationship amongst public debt and economic growth in developing country case of Tunisia

PRIVATE AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENT: A STUDY OF THREE OECD COUNTRIES. MEHDI S. MONADJEMI AND HYEONSEUNG HUH* University of New South Wales

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

ESTIMATING MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION OF BANGLADESH

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

VELOCITY AND THE VOLATILITY OF UNANTICIPATED AND ANTICIPATED MONEY SUPPLY IN THE UNITED KINGDOM

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Is the real effective exchange rate biased against the PPP hypothesis?

The Random Walk Hypothesis in Emerging Stock Market-Evidence from Nonlinear Fourier Unit Root Test

OKUN S LAW IN MALAYSIA: AN AUTOREGRESSIVE DISTRIBUTED LAG (ARDL) APPROACH WITH HODRICK-PRESCOTT (HP) FILTER

Vector Autoregression Analysis of Exchange Rate Movement

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Imperfect Knowledge, Asset Price Swings and Structural Slumps: A Cointegrated VAR Analysis of their Interdependence

The Balassa-Samuelson Effect and The MEVA G10 FX Model

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Exchange Rate Market Efficiency: Across and Within Countries

A study on the long-run benefits of diversification in the stock markets of Greece, the UK and the US

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Effects of FDI on Capital Account and GDP: Empirical Evidence from India

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Inflation and inflation uncertainty in Argentina,

Assessing Potential Inflation Consequences of QE after Financial Crises

International evidence of tax smoothing in a panel of industrial countries

Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology

Dollarization: Concepts and Implications for Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy in the Philippines

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Zhenyu Wu 1 & Maoguo Wu 1

Investigating Causal Relationship between Indian and American Stock Markets , Tamilnadu, India

Cointegration Tests and the Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity: Examination of Six Currencies in Asia

Sustainability of Current Account Deficits in Turkey: Markov Switching Approach

Dynamics Linkages among Money, Output, Interest Rate and Price: The Case in Malaysia

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Are Greek budget deficits 'too large'? National University of Ireland, Galway

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada?

Regional Business Cycles In the United States

Kiel Institute of World Economics Duesternbrooker Weg Kiel (Germany)

Fiscal sustainability: a note for Cabo Verde

The U.S. Congress established the East-West Center in 1960 to foster mutual understanding and cooperation among the governments and peoples of the

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

Does Monetary Policy Affect Stock Prices and Treasury Yields? An Error Correction and Simultaneous Equation Approach

Centurial Evidence of Breaks in the Persistence of Unemployment

Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence

Integration of Foreign Exchange Markets: A Short Term Dynamics Analysis

Money and Prices in Estonia

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 15 ( 2014 )

VOLATILITY COMPONENT OF DERIVATIVE MARKET: EVIDENCE FROM FBMKLCI BASED ON CGARCH

An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Stock Prices in Bangladesh

A DISAGGREGATED ANALYSIS OF GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES AND PRIVATE INVESTMENT IN TURKEY. Erdal Karagöl

Do Closer Economic Ties Imply Convergence in Income - The Case of the U.S., Canada, and Mexico

MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

MONEY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: SOME INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE. Abstract

Hock Ann Lee Labuan School of International Business and Finance, Universiti Malaysia Sabah. Abstract

Monetary Policy, Asset Prices and Inflation in Canada

Macroeconomic Variables and Unemployment: The Case of Turkey

STLS/US-VECM 6.1: A Vector Error-Correction Forecasting Model of the US Economy. Dennis L. Hoffman and Robert H. Rasche

Can inflation targeting mitigate monetary policy time-inconsistency? Evidence from Brazil

Global Slack as a Determinant of US Inflation *

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

DU Journal of Undergraduate Research and Innovation Volume 4, Issue 1, pp ABSTRACT

STABILITY OF DEMAND FOR MONEY IN NIGERIA

The German unemployment since the Hartz reforms: Permanent or transitory fall?

WHAT DOES THE HOUSE PRICE-TO-

Chapter 5 Mean Reversion in Indian Commodities Market

Case Study: Predicting U.S. Saving Behavior after the 2008 Financial Crisis (proposed solution)

Foreign Direct Investment & Economic Growth in BRICS Economies: A Panel Data Analysis

At the European Council in Copenhagen in December

The Real Business Cycle Model

Financial Liberalization and Money Demand in Mauritius

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

THE IMPACT OF IMPORT ON INFLATION IN NAMIBIA

Most recent studies of long-term interest rates have emphasized term

INTERDEPENDENCE OF THE BANKING SECTOR AND THE REAL SECTOR: EVIDENCE FROM OECD COUNTRIES

MONEY, PRICES, INCOME AND CAUSALITY: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

Sectoral Analysis of the Demand for Real Money Balances in Pakistan

AN ANALISYS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INFLATION IN SOUTH AFRICA. Mr Kotikoti Tleane 1. University of Limpopo.

THE CREDIT CYCLE and the BUSINESS CYCLE in the ECONOMY of TURKEY

Comparative analysis of monetary and fiscal Policy: a case study of Pakistan

Contribution of VAT to the GDP of Bangladesh: A Trend Study

An Examination of the Stability of Narrow Money Demand Function in Nigeria

The Credit Cycle and the Business Cycle in the Economy of Turkey

Inflation and Stock Market Returns in US: An Empirical Study

Causal Analysis of Economic Growth and Military Expenditure

The Effectiveness of Non-traditional Monetary Policy and the Inflation Target Policy : The Case of Japan in Comparison with the US

Market Integration, Price Discovery, and Volatility in Agricultural Commodity Futures P.Ramasundaram* and Sendhil R**

Inflation Targeting and Economic Growth: Case of Albania

EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN SPOT AND FUTURE PRICE OF CRUDE OIL

INVESTIGATION OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT AND SAVINGS IN MENA ECONOMIES: AN EMPIRICAL APPROACH

LINKAGES OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, STOCK PRICE AND MONETARY POLICY: THE CASE OF MALAYSIA CHONG CHIN SIENG

Transcription:

Philippine Institute for Development Studies Can P* Be a Basis for Core Inflation in the Philippines? Josef T. Yap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES NO. 96-10 The PIDS Discussion Paper Series constitutes studies that are preliminary and subject to further revisions. They are being circulated in a limited number of copies only for purposes of soliciting comments and suggestions for further refinements. The studies under the Series are unedited and unreviewed. The views and opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the Institute. Not for quotation without permission from the author(s) and the Institute. September 1996 For comments, suggestions or further inquiries please contact: The Research Information Staff, Philippine Institute for Development Studies 3rd Floor, NEDA sa Makati Building, 106 Amorsolo Street, Legaspi Village, Makati City, Philippines Tel Nos: 8924059 and 8935705; Fax No: 8939589; E-mail: publications@pidsnet.pids.gov.ph Or visit our website at http://www.pids.gov.ph

CAN P* BE A BASIS FOR CORE INFLATION IN THE PHILIPPINES? Josef T. Yap I Introduction Inflation has become the central issue again in economic discussions with t_e Secretary of Socio-economic Planning and the Governor of the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) admitting that the inflation rate will likely remain above i0 percent for the first quarter of 1996. A steady, manageable inflation rate is a key ingredient for macroeconomic stability and the BSP is intent to pursue its mandate along this line. This is one reason that the concept of core inflation is being considered as a basis for conducting monetary policy. Core or "underlying" inflation is defined by the BSP to be the long-run trend in the general price level. The items that are usually excluded from the computation of core inflation are: I) prices subject to government policy such as taxes and changes in the price of oil and, in some countries, interest rates; 2) components which are volatile and/or seasonal. In this paper we attempt to relate core inflation to the concept of P* and determine whether it can be applied in the Philippine economy. Basic Concepts The P-star (P*) concept was first developed by the Federal Reserve as a simple, yet comprehensive, indicator of inflationary pressure (Hallman, et al. 1989, 1991). P* is defined as the price level which is consistent with current money supply and equilibrium in goods and financial markets. As the gap between the actual price level P and P* is zero in equilibrium, deviations from P and P* indicate the amount of price adjustment which has not yet materialized and can help predict future movements in the price level. 1Research Fellow, Philippine Institute for Development Studies. This paper was prepared for a workshop on the definition and measurement of inflation organized by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas and held on 16 February 1996. The usual disclaimer applies.

2 Calculation of P* takes the quantity theory of money as the starting point. The simple quantity equation is: PQ MV (i) where Q is real GDP, P is the GDP price deflator, M is the stock of money and V is the velocity of money. P* is also considered as the long-run equilibrium price level and, based on Equation (I), defined as the price level consistent with the current value of M, the long-run equilibrium value of velocity (V*), and the current value of potential real GDP (Q*) : MV" p- (2) Q- Following the quantity theory, it is assumed that both Q* and V* are determined independently, and, moreimportantly that both are independent of the money stock. Thus, the equilibrium' pricelevel moves proportionally with the stock of money. As mentioned earlier, any divergence of the price level P* from the actual price level P, i.e. any positive or negative price gaps P* - P, indicates whether the future price level will accelerate or slow down. An application of this framework is to identify the equilibrium price level through the construction of P* and then to estimate reduced-form short-run dynamics that drive the actual price level to P* and thereby are consistent with. the longrun constraints imposed by P*. Such a short-run dynamic model of inflation is given by the following error-correction model: N ALn (Pt) i ALn (P) _-i"_ (Pt-l" -Pt-I ) (3) i.1 Hoeller and Poret (1991) point out that Equation (3) focuses on the adjustment towards long-run equilibrium levels; hence it does not capture important factors influencing prices in the short run, e.g. indirect tax changes, food or energy price shocks. P* then provides a measure of where the price level will go after such

3 transitory shocks have worked themselves out. This is the characterization that links the P* concept to core inflation. The idea behind equations (2) and (3) therefore is that any increase in the stock of money which is not accompanied by an increase of real output, will cause an increase of P in the longrun (note that _>0). For equation (3) to be a valid representation of.the data, however, P and P* must form a cointegrating relationship in the sense of Engle and Granger (1987). In other words, there should be a tendency for P to approach P* in the long run. Calculation of P* A key question in implementing the P* approach is how to measure potential output (Q*) and trend velocity (V*). At the outset, it must be determined whether actual output Q and actual velocity V contain a unit root. The presence of unit roots in output and velocity implies that they do not revert to some deterministic time trends or historical averages in the long run. This will rule out the use of (deterministic) time trends or mean values for calculating potential output and equilibrium velocity. Using time trends in the presence of unit root will yield a nonstationary price gap, i.e. P*-P, which is inconsistent with the I assumption of the P* model. One alternative is to use structural models of the determination of potential output and equilibrium velocity. This was applied by Funke and Hall (1992) to calculate for V* and subsequently adopted by Reyes and Yap (1993). Earlier versions of the PIDS model used an aggregate production function framework to derive an estimate of potential output. Another alternative for computing potential output and equilibrium velocity is the use of filters to compute for stochastic trends. The most popular is the Kalman filter although it entails some computational difficulty. Hoeller and Poret use the Hodrick-Prescott filter which is more straightforward. Once estimates of Q* and V* are obtained Equation (2) is then used to estimate P*. The next step is to determine whether the price gap P*-P contains a unit root. If it is shown that.,the

4 assumptions of the P* model are satisfied, an inflation model built around Equation 3 can be estimated. Empirical Results To test for unit roots in a series y_ we apply an augmented Dickey-Fuller test.(adf) by running the following regression: _Yt = Y + 5t + PYt-i + _SjAYt-j + et The null hypothesis is that the series is nonstationary, i.e. p = 0. For completeness we test three hypotheses, H0: @ = 0 against HA: p < 0; H0: p = 0, y = 0 against HA: p < 0 ;and H0: p = 0, 8 = 0 against HA: p < 0 This is to account for the possibility of a trend stationary series. Three variables are tested for stationarity: GDP, V1 and V2 using quarterly data over the period 1981-1994. Vl is velocity computed based on narrow money using Equation (i) while v2 is calculated based on broad money or total liquidity. The ADF tests on these three variables show that he null hypothesis-of nonstationarity cannot be rejected. Hence it is not possible to apply deterministic time trends or mean values for calculating potential output and equilibrium velocity. I It has been argued that the presence of structural breaks in a time series will bias the test toward the null hypothesis. Given the various crises in the past (e.g. the BOP crisis in 1983), several macroeconomic variables do exhibit structural breaks. Capuno (1994) applying a segmented trend model to Philippine data shows that even if structural breaks are taken into account the tests fail to reject the unit root hypothesis. Attempts to apply the Kalman filter were not successful. In addition, a software program for the Hodrick-Prescott filter is not available. In order to present some empirical results, Q* was computed using a time trend and V* was taken to be the mean value of velocity over the sample period. The corresponding values of P* (P*1 and P*2) are plotted against PGDP in Figures i and 2. A unit root test reveals that the resulting price gap (P*-P) is nonstationary and hence cannot be used in estimating Equation 3.

5 A preliminary regression shows, however, that the price gap based on total liquidity (P*2 - P) yields better empirical results which means that broad money seems to be a better anchor for monetary policy. Concluding Remarks Further work should focus on estimating more appropriate values of Q* and V*. This would assure a more realistic value of P* and a stationary price gap. Previous studies using P* show that the model seems to work better with larger than smaller countries. Kool and Tatom (1994) attribute this to the neglect of the importance of the prevailing exchange rate regime for the determinants of prices and inflation. They proceed by incorporating a foreign price gap to account for the influence of imported inflation especially for small economies. Their empirical results show that the fit of the P* model improves with the addition of the foreign price gap. It would be useful to include a foreign price gap when estimating Equation (3) for the Philippine case. References Capuno, J. J. (1994) "Exogenous Shocks and Nonstationary Time Series: The Case of the Philippines." Manuscript. Engle, R. F. and C. W. J. Granger (1987): "Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing," Econometrica, 55, 251-276. Funke, M. and S. Hall (1992): "Is the Bundesbank Different from Other Central Banks: A Study Based on P*," London Business School, Centre for Economic Forecasting, Discussion Paper No. ii- 92. Hallman, J. J., R. D. Porter and D. H. Small (1989): "M2 per Unit of Potential GNP as an Anchor for the Price Level," Staff Study No. 157, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington DC, April.

6 Hallman, J. J., R. D. Porter and D. H. Small (1991): "Is the Price Level Tied to the M2 Monetary Aggregate in the Long Run?" American Economic Review 81, 841-858. Hoeller, P. and P. Poret (1991): "Is P-Star a Good Indicator of Inflationary Pressure in OECD Countries?" OECD Economic Studies No. 17 (Autumn). Kool, C. J. M. and J. A. Tatom (1994): "The P-Star Model in Five Small Economies." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (May/June). Reyes, C. M. and J. T. Yap (1993). "Money and Prices in the Philippines 1981-1992: A Cointegration Analysis." Journal of Philippine Development XX, 36 (First Semester).

250 Figure 1: P*I and PGDP 200 - #. 150.'" 100. 5O,,.;"" 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 P*I... PGDP I I

250 Figure 2:P*2 and PGDP 200 J'* "_,'" 150-100- J s _, i" _.1 II 50-0 I I _ I i I I i i _ i i. I I I I J I I _l I i I I-" I I'I IFV_I I i 1--'l"l'i I I I! F 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 -- P*2... PGDP I