Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Similar documents
Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Market Structure and Privatization Policy under International Competition

Privatization and government preference. Abstract

Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly Revisited: An Extension of Stackelberg Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Noncooperative Oligopoly

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Mixed Duopoly with Price Competition

Cournot-Bertrand competition in a unionized mixed duopoly

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Long run equilibria in an asymmetric oligopoly

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly under Uncertainty

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Does Timing of Decisions in a Mixed Duopoly Matter?

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ENDOGENOUS TIMING IN A MIXED DUOPOLY: WEIGHTED WELFARE AND PRICE COMPETITION

research paper series

Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Mark. De Ngo, Duc; Okura, Mahito. Economics Bulletin, 12(20), pp.1-9; Issue Date

Shigeo MUTO (Tokyo Institute of Technology, Japan)

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Relocation and Public Ownership of Firms

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Strategic Production Game 1

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Price Leadership in a Homogeneous Product Market

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models

Oligopoly. Johan Stennek

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Regional restriction, strategic commitment, and welfare

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Market

Cournot-Bertrand Comparison in a Mixed Oligopoly

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

Capacity precommitment and price competition yield the Cournot outcome

The Nightmare of the Leader: The Impact of Deregulation on an Oligopoly Insurance Market

Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment in. Mixed Oligopolies

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

HW Consider the following game:

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing innovation

Organizational Structure and the Choice of Price vs. Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly

Technology Licensing in a Differentiated Oligopoly

Mixed duopoly, privatization and the shadow cost of public funds

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Small Firms, their Growth and Product Differentiation

Strategic Managerial Delegation in a Mixed. Duopoly with Capacity Choice: Partial. Delegation or Full Delegation

Transcription:

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly Kangsik Choi Graduate School of International Studies. Pusan National University Abstract This paper investigates the simultaneous-move games in a mixed duopoly where firms are maximizers of either profits or relative profits. Contrary to previous results, if each firm has mixed motives about payoff in a simultaneous-move game, a private firm monopolizes whereas the public firm produces nothing. Citation: Choi, Kangsik, (2006) "Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 12, No. 14 pp. 1-7 Submitted: November 26, 2006. Accepted: December 29, 2006. URL: http://economicsbulletin.vanderbilt.edu/2006/volume12/eb-06l10054a.pdf

1 Introduction There has recently been much interest in a mixed oligopoly that analyze the competitive relationship between public and private firms. In reality, many public firms are placed in a situation where they have to compete against private firms. In many countries, there are competitive relationships between the public and private firms. Analyses on typical public firms only are conducted essentially within the paradigm of a monopoly where the public firm and the private firm operate as a monopolist ignoring strategic interactions among themselves. In pioneering work of the mixed oligopoply, De Fraja and Delbono (1989) made an important study on mixed oligopoly as a game theory. In particular, De Fraja and Delbono (1989) investigate the objective function and payoff patterns of the public firm as it is privatized in view of social welfare. In some cases a public firm should be privatized and maximize profits rather than social welfare. They also found that there exists a critical number of private firms such that privatization of the public firm improves social welfare. Thanks to the analysis by De Fraja and Delbono(1989), the analyses of the mixed oligopoly are actively tackled from various angles, such as private firms endogenous and exogenous market entry, product differentiation between public and private firms, partial privatization, under capacity of public firms and excess capacity of private firms 1. However, one of the most fundamental assumptions in mixed oligopoly is that all firms maximize absolute profits. From the viewpoint of mixed motives about profits, Schaffer (1989) and Vega-Redondo (1997) analyzed the relative payoff in terms of the firms level as they examine Cournot equilibrium in the evolutionary game theory. According to Schaffer (1989) and Vega-Redondo(1997), a unilateral deviation from Cournot equilibrium that decreases the profit of deviator, but decrease the other firms profit even more. Schaffer (1989) and Vega-Redondo (1997) argued that instability of Cournot equilibrium in the viewpoint of the evolutionary game theory as well as demonstrated that a Walrasian equilibrium forms as an evolutionary consequence resulting from the process where every firm tries to be ahead of every other one. According to Alos-Ferrer (2004), Riechmann (2002, 2006) and Schipper (2005), in case where firms aiming to maximize relative payoffs to win competitors and firms aiming to maximize absolute payoff coexist, the amount of production falls into the range between Cournot equilibrium and Walrasian equilibrium. That is, if firms do not care about their influence on the market price and behavior as price-taker, the equilibrium outputs result in Walrasian competitive market 2. Although some theoretical works have already succeeded in explaining a mixed oligopoly, 1 For pioneering work, see Beato and Mas-Collel (1984). For excellent surveys, see De Fraja and Delbono (1990), Nett (1993) and Bos (1991). For recent literature on mixed oligopoly, see Matsumura(1998), Matsumura and Matsushima (2003, 2004), Lu and Poddar (2005), Ogawa(2006), among others. 2 In other words, if the relative payoff is the measure, it pays to hurt in terms of absolute payoff as long as by hurting yourself you hurt your opponent even more. This class of game called spite effect in Riechmann (2002). 1

this study adds mixed behavioral motives on the payoff for a public firm and a private firm in simultaneous-move game. We focus on the mixed situations in which each firm aims to maximize its absolute payoff and attempts to maximize relative payoff which defined as the difference between firm s absolute payoff and average absolute payoff of all firms. 2 The Model Consider a mixed duopoly model with a public firm and a private firm, all producing a single homogenous product with inverse demand given by p = 1 Q where Q = q 0 + q 1 where p is a price for two firms (i = 0, 1), q 0 and q 1 denote the output of public firm and private firm, respectively. The price can not be equal to 1 Q for all values of Q, for then it would be negative for 1 < Q. Assume that total cost to firm i of producing quantity q i is C(q i ) = cq i. Assume that 1 > c > 0, so that there is some value for total output Q for which market price is greater than the firms common marginal cost c. That is, there is no fixed costs and common marginal cost is constant 3. The absolute payoff of each firm i is given by π a i = p(q i c). (1) Relative payoff to firm i is defined in the evolutionary game theory (Samuelson(1997, pp. 66) and Weibull(1995, pp. 71-74)) as the difference between i s absolute payoff and the average absolute payoff of all firms. The average absolute payoff is given by (1/2)πj a in our framework 4. Thus, the relative payoff to firm i is as follows: ( ) 2 1 πi r = πi a 1 2 2 πa j = 1 2 [p(q i c) p(q j c)]. (2) To distinguish notations, the superscript a and r are defined as the absolute-payoffmaximizer and relative-payoff-maximizer, respectively. Thus, the public firm 0 maximizes the social welfare W, given by W lm = Q2 2 + πl 0 + π m 1 where l = a, r, m = a, r (3) where Q 2 /2 is the consumer surplus and π m 1 is the profit of private firm. 3 To simplify the analysis, cost function is the same for both private and public firm in our paper. Thus, we rule out the possibility that privatization of the public firm reduces production cost. It turns out that it is impossible for political or economics reasons to nationalize the public firm. There are theoretical and empirical works for the equality of cost efficiency between the public firm and private firm, see Matsumura and Kanda (2005) for appropriate references. In the literature, the public firm is assumed to be less efficient than the private firm, e.g. Pal (1998). 4 In the case of n firms, the relative payoff to firm i will be defined πi r = [(n 1)/n]πa i (1/n)πa j. 2

3 Results We consider firms choice of quantity in the following four cases. [Absolute payoff in mixed duopoly]: Following standard equilibrium concept, the public firm s absolute payoff objective is to maximize welfare defined as the sum of consumer surplus and profit all firms, and the private firm s absolute payoff objective is to maximize its own proftit as follows: and max W aa = Q2 q 0 2 + πa 0 + π1, a max π1 a = (1 q 0 q 1 )(q 1 c). q 1 The maximization problem of each firm yields q 0 = 1 c 2, (4) q 1 = 1 c q 0. (5) 2 By solving (4) and (5), we obtain the equilibrium output levels in simultaneous-move game as q0 = 1 c 2, (6) q1 = 1 c 4. (7) [Relative payoff in mixed duopoly]: Similarly, the maximization problems for the relative-payoff-maximizer of public firm and private firm, and private firm s objective function are given by and max q 1 π r 1 = 1 2 [p(q 1 c) p(q 0 c)], (8) max W rr = Q2 q 0 2 + πr 0 + π1, r (9) respectively. Given the relative-payoff-maximizer, the private firm maximizes (8) with respect to q 1. The maximization problem yields q 1 = 1 c 2. 3

However, the relative-payoff-maximizer of public firm maximizes (9) with respect to q 0, which yields W rr q 0 < 0 q 0 = q 1. Hence we obtain the equilibrium output levels as q0 = 0, (10) q1 = 1 c 2. (11) Notice that if both private and public firm are relative-payoff-maximizer in simultaneousmove game where welfare-maximizer public firm competes against the private firm, the private firm who is relative-payoff-maximizer can achieve the monopolistic position because the public firm s output becomes zero. Thus, in the point of public firm s view, welfare-maximizer public firm prefers absolute payoff function to relative payoff function. Thus, we will examine a case where mixed payoff motives exist for this reason. [Mixed motives of payoff in mixed duopoly]: In this case, given the private firm aims to maximize absolute(resp. relative) payoff and the public firm aims to maximize relative(resp. absolute) payoff, each objective function of public firm is as follows: and max W ra = Q2 q 0 2 + πr 0 + π1, a (12) max W ar = Q2 q 0 2 + πa 0 + π1. r (13) By maximizing (12) or (13) with respect to q 0, each first-order condition becomes W ar q 0 = W ra q 0 < 0 c < 1, (14) respectively. Given the assumption, 1 > c in basic model, we can verify that both W ar / q 0 and W ra / q 0 are negative. Consequently, at any given pair of relative-payoffmaximizers and absolute-payoff-maximizer of public firm, the public firm does not produce the output. There would be no output for the public firm at which the public firm could make any profit, because the market price never exceeds 1. On the other hand, we obtain the optimal output level of the private firm as q 1 = 1 c 2. The private firm wants to produce monopoly output whether there is absolute payoff function or relative payoff function in simultaneous-move game. 4

3.1 Implication for Simultaneous-move Game in Mixed Duopoly We have analyzed four cases in a simultaneous-move game. The result shows that if the public firm aims to maximize the absolute payoff, the private firm will produce less than when it aims to maximize the absolute payoff (see Equation (6) and (7)). Therefore, if the public firm attempts to maximize the absolute payoff, the private firm would not have an incentive to maximize the absolute payoff. In other cases, the public firm s production becomes zero, allowing the private firm s monopoly payoff and price set. In the case where each firm s payoff motives is mixed, the resulting equilibrium turns out to be an inefficient level with the monopoly of private firm even if the public firm participates in the productive activity. Therefore, the market price equals to the marginal cost of private firm, and public firm does not produce any positive output where the mixed payoff motives exist in the simultaneous-move game of a mixed oligopoly. The existence of the pubic firm never affects the equilibrium output in the simultaneous-move games discussed in mixed motives. Alos-Ferrer (2004), Reichmann (2002, 2006) and Schipper (2005) focused on only the private firms in the simultaneous-move game. They argued that a private firm that values relative payoff would not have an incentive to maximize the absolute payoff, whereas a private firm that values the absolute payoff would not pursue the maximization of relative payoff. Thus, they concluded that the evolutionary equilibrium is stable. In the case when the firms that pursue to maximize relative payoff and those that pursue to maximize absolute payoff to surpass competitors, Alos-Ferrer (2004), Reichmann (2002, 2006) and Schipper (2005) argued, the industry s production is determined between the range of Cournot equilibrium and Walrasian equilibrium output. If the public and private firms coexist in a simultaneous-move game, however, Alos-Ferrer (2004) and Reichmann (2002, 2006) s equilibrium would not be obtained. Our result derives from the fact that in the mixed oligopoly, the relative-payoffmaximizer of the private firm has a dominant strategy. In this regard, whether the public firm is payoff maximizer or not, the best payoff maximizer for the private firm is the absolute-payoff-maximizer. Therefore, investigating the sequential-move game in the mixed oligopoly is needed for future research 5. 4 Concluding Remarks In this paper, we investigate the simultaneous-move game in a mixed duopoly where firms are maximizers of either profits or relative profits. Contrary to previous results, if each firm has mixed motives about payoff in a simultaneous-move game, a private firm monopolizes whereas the public firm s amount of production becomes zero. However, our result might depend on the assumption that common marginal cost is constant regardless of who 5 For the sequential-move games in the mixed duopoly, it is available from author upon request. 5

produces the output in mixed duopoly. Thus, extending our formulation to encompass a different marginal cost and endogenous the number of entry firms are further subjects for future research. References [1] Alos-Ferrer, C, 2004, Cournot versus Walras in Dynamic Oligoplies with Memory, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22, 193-217. [2] Beato, P. and Mas-Colell, A., 1984, Marginal Cost Pricing as a Regulation Mechanism in Mixed Markets, in M. Marchand, P. Pestieu and H. Tulkens, (eds.), The Performance of Public Enterprises, pp. 81-101, North-Holland, Amsterdam. [3] Bos, D., 1991, Privatization: A Theoretical Treatment, Oxford University Press. [4] De Fraja, G. and Delbono F., 1990, Game Theoretic Models of Mixed Oligopoly, Journal of Economic Surveys, 4,1-17. [5] De Fraja, G. and Delbono F., 1989, Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly, Oxford Economic Papers, 41, 302311. [6] Lu, Y, and S. Poddar, 2005, Mixed Oligopoly and the Choice of Capacity, Research in Economics, 59, 365-374. [7] Matsumura. T, 1998, Partial Privatization in Mixed Duopoly, Journal of Public Economics. 70, 473-48. [8] Matsumura, T, and O, Kanda, 2005, Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets, Journal of Economics, 84, 27-48. [9] Matsumura, T., and N. Matsushima, 2004, Endogenous Cost Differentials between Public and Private Enterprises: A Mixed Duopoly Approach, Economica, 71, 671-688. [10] Matsumura, T., and N. Matsushima, 2003, Mixed Duopoly with Product Differentiation: Sequential Choice of Location, Australian Economic Papers, 42, 18-34. [11] Nett, L., 1993, Mixed Oligopoly with Homogeneous Goods, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 64, 367-393. [12] Ogawa, H, 2006, Capacity Choice in the Mixed Oligopoly with Product Differentiaion, Economic Bulletin, 8, 1-6. [13] Pal, D., 1998, Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly, Economics Letters, 61, 181-185. [14] Riechmann, T, 2006, Mixed Motives in a Cournot Game, Economic Bulletin, 4, 1-8. [15] Riechmann, T, 2002, Cournot or Walras? Agent Based Learning, Rationality, and Long Run Results in Oligopoly Games, Universitat Hannover, Disucssion Paper. Nr. 261. forthcoming in Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. [16] Samuelson, L. 1997, Evolutionary Games and Equilibrium Selection, MIT Press. [17] Schaffer, M. E. 1989 Are Profit Maximisers the Best Survivors? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 12, 29-45. [18] Schipper, B, C, 2005, Imitators and Optimizers in Cournot Oligopoly, SFB/TR 15, Discussion Paper 2005-53. 6

[19] Vega-Redondo, F, 1997, The Evolution of Walrasian Behavior, Econometrica, 65, 375-384. [20] Vega-Redondo, F, 1996, Evolution, Games, and Economic Behavior. Oxford University Press. 7