Financial Literacy and the Demand for Financial Advice

Similar documents
Financial Literacy and the Demand for Financial Advice

FINANCIAL LITERACY AND THE DEMAND FOR FINANCIAL ADVICE

Financial Advisors: A Case of Babysitters?

Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise

To trust is good, but to control is better: how do investors discipline nancial advisors activity

Investment Competence and Advice Seeking

Pension Wealth and Household Saving in Europe: Evidence from SHARELIFE

Wealth, money, knowledge: how much do people know? Where are the gaps? What s working? What s next?

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

Voting in the aftermath of a Pension Reform: the Role of Economic Literacy

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

Individual Heterogeneity and Pension Choices: How to Communicate an Effective Message?

Wealth, Savings and Credit Compliance: Does Economic (and financial) Literacy Matter?

Endogenous financial literacy, saving and stock market participation

RETIREMENT DECISIONS, ELIGIBILITY AND FINANCIAL LITERACY

Economics Bulletin, 2014, Vol. 34 No. 1 pp Introduction

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Exploring differences in financial literacy across countries: the role of individual characteristics, experience, and institutions

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

On Minimum Wage Determination

How can trade, migration and sectoral policies be articulated into a coherent approach to economic transformation

MiFID questionnaire answers: stock market participation, appetite for information and investor s sentiment.

Credit counseling: a substitute for consumer financial literacy?

Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership

The Impact of Risk Attitudes on Financial Investments. Walter Hyll Maike Irrek. August 2015 No. 10 IWH-DISKUSSIONSPAPIERE IWH DISCUSSION PAPERS

ABSTRACT. Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): ISSN(p): DOI: /journal.aefr Vol. 9, No.

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Determinants of Households Savings in Central, Eastern and Southeastern Europe

Why so low for so long? A long-term view of real interest rates

IPO Underpricing and Information Disclosure. Laura Bottazzi (Bologna and IGIER) Marco Da Rin (Tilburg, ECGI, and IGIER)

MODELLING HOUSEHOLD BEHAVIOUR: RESPONSE TO MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN THE UK PAULO ARANA UNIVERSITY OF ESSEX 28 TH OF JUNE 2017

The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford

The relationship between the government debt and GDP growth: evidence of the Euro area countries

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Web Appendix Figure 1. Operational Steps of Experiment

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

How Do Client Trust and Financial Literacy Add to the Value of Financial Advice?

Financial Literacy and Savings Account Returns *

Financial Literacy and Financial Behavior among Young Adults: Evidence and Implications

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

Percentage of foreclosures in the area is the ratio between the monthly foreclosures and the number of outstanding home-related loans in the Zip code

Multi-destination Firms and the Impact of Exchange-Rate Risk on Trade Online Appendix (Not for publication)

Your Name (Please print) Did you agree to take the optional portion of the final exam Yes No. Directions

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

Recovery measures of underfunded pension funds: contribution increase, no indexation, or pension cut? Leo de Haan

How Robo Advice changes individual investor behavior

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

Swedish Lessons: How Important are ICT and R&D to Economic Growth? Paper prepared for the 34 th IARIW General Conference, Dresden, Aug 21-27, 2016

Pension fund s illiquid assets allocation under liquidity and capital constraints

Trust in the Central Bank and Inflation Expectations #

CFCM CFCM CENTRE FOR FINANCE AND CREDIT MARKETS. Working Paper 12/01. Financial Literacy and Consumer Credit Use. Richard Disney and John Gathergood

Problem Set 9 Heteroskedasticty Answers

Deposits and Bank Capital Structure

We follow Agarwal, Driscoll, and Laibson (2012; henceforth, ADL) to estimate the optimal, (X2)

Is Banks Cost of Equity Capital Different Across Countries? Evidence from G10 Countries Major Banks

HOW DO FIRMS FORM THEIR EXPECTATIONS? NEW SURVEY EVIDENCE

Information Acquisition and Portfolio Under-Diversification

Pension Awareness. Henriëtte Prast & Arthur van Soest, Tilburg University & Netspar. Funded by Stichting Instituut GAK through Netspar

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Intermediary Balance Sheets Tobias Adrian and Nina Boyarchenko, NY Fed Discussant: Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, UC Berkeley

Does pension awareness reduce pension concerns?

Openness and Inflation

Information and the Political Obstacles to Pension Reform

Incentives in Executive Compensation Contracts: An Examination of Pay-for-Performance

The data definition file provided by the authors is reproduced below: Obs: 1500 home sales in Stockton, CA from Oct 1, 1996 to Nov 30, 1998

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub

HOUSEHOLD WEALTH AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP: IS THERE A LINK? Silvia Magri * (January 2006) Abstract

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Non-compliance behavior and use of extraction rights for natural resources

Does Uniqueness in Banking Matter?

Gender Differences in Financial Literacy: Empowering Women

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Inequality at Work: The Effect of Peer Salaries on Job Satisfaction

Bank Liquidity and the Cost of Debt

Appetite for Information in Mandatory Profiling of Individual Investors

Inflation Expectations and Behavior: Do Survey Respondents Act on their Beliefs? October Wilbert van der Klaauw

Online Appendix for Why Don t the Poor Save More? Evidence from Health Savings Experiments American Economic Review

Financial Literacy and Household Wealth

Ludwig Maximilians Universität München 22 th January, Determinants of R&D Financing Constraints: Evidence from Belgian Companies

Internal and External Effects of R&D Subsidies and Fiscal Incentives Empirical Evidence Using Spatial Dynamic Panel Models

Trust in the central bank and inflation expectations

Shirking and Employment Protection Legislation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

Financial Literacy, Retirement Planning, and Investment Behavior - A comparative Study for Austria and Switzerland

The impact of credit constraints on foreign direct investment: evidence from firm-level data Preliminary draft Please do not quote

Is proprietary trading detrimental to retail investors?

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in Germany. Tabea Bucher-Koenen and Annamaria Lusardi

Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various

What is the duration of Swiss direct real estate?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCIAL LITERACY AND RETIREMENT PLANNING IN GERMANY. Tabea Bucher-Koenen Annamaria Lusardi

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model

Personalized Information as a Tool to Improve Pension Savings

CHAPTER 5 FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION

Transcription:

Financial Literacy and the Demand for Financial Advice Riccardo Calcagno EM Lyon CeRP-CCA Chiara Monticone OECD CeRP-CCA Netspar Financial Innovation and Market Dynamics. The Role of Securities Regulation Università Bocconi February 10, 2012 Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 1 / 37

Motivation Motivation Many households in the US and in Europe display low financial literacy. Concerns that these households may make poor financial decisions (Lusardi and Mitchell 2007; Lusardi and Tufano 2009; Monticone 2010; van Rooij et al. 2011) In principle, households can seek advice and guidance from qualified sources, compensating their lack of knowledge Professional financial advisors are often relied upon for advice Netherlands Italy US Is this sufficient to avoid the consequences of financial illiteracy? Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 2 / 37

Motivation This paper This paper analyzes the demand (and supply) of professional financial advice in relation to investors financial literacy. On the supply side, do advisors provide more informative advice to financially literate? According to our model, advisors provide better advice to the most knowledgeable customers On the demand side, who seeks advice? How much do households rely on experts advice? We find (theoretically and empirically) that more knowledgeable investors are more likely to consult advisors, while the least knowledgeable either invest by themselves or delegate Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 3 / 37

Motivation Background Literature on advice: Communication game (Dessein 2002) Investors strategic sophistication/naiveté (Ottaviani 2000) Effect of perceived financial capability and trust on propensity to rely on advice (Georgarakos and Inderst 2010) Effect of financial knowledge and perceived conflicts of interest on propensity to follow recommendations (Hackethal Inderst and Meyer 2010) Advice on pensions (Koenen and Bucher-Koenen 2011) Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 4 / 37

Motivation Outline Theoretical Model Data and descriptives Empirical analysis 1. Extent of reliance on the advice from professionals 2. Robustness checks Conclusions Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 5 / 37

Model Model Interaction between an informed advisor and a less informed investor The advisor sells a risky asset and provides information to the customer about the asset s return The advisor has an incentive to sell the asset but faces a penalty for giving deceptive advice The investor has to decide whether to buy the risky asset and how much to rely on the advisor Delegate Consult the advisor (without delegating) Invest based on her own information only Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 6 / 37

Model Timing t = 0 B receives signal s with given π t = 1 B decides whether to delegate, ask for advice, or invest by herself t = 2 If Advice, then A and B interact in a communication game, where A decides whether to reveal his information or not and B decides her portfolio allocation t = 3 r is realized Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 7 / 37

Model Setup Two assets Two agents One risky asset, with f ( r) = where r H > 0, r L < 0 and E f ( r) [ r] > 0 One riskless asset: r f = 0 { rh 1/2 r L 1/2 Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 8 / 37

Model Setup Advisor A Knows the true state of r with certainty If consulted, sends a message σ = {r H, r L } Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 9 / 37

Model Setup Investor/Buyer B Mean-variance preferences Short-selling constraints Does not know the true state of r, but Receives a (private) signal s = {rh, r L } with precision π, where π = Pr(s = r i r i ) > 1/2, i.e. probability that the signal is correct Define π 0 > 1/2 such that π 0 r L + (1 π 0 )r H = 0. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 10 / 37

Model Communication game Information sets: the advisor A knows the true state of r and signal s precision π (see MiFID) but not necessarily its realization. The investor B knows π, the realization of s and the payoff function of the advisor. Strategies: the advisor decides which message σ = {r H, r L } to deliver given his type. The investor chooses her optimal portfolio allocation Payoffs: U A (r i, σ) = F {E[ r IB ]>0} [σ(r i ) r i ] 2 { U B (I B ) = E[U(W 3 ) I B ] = W 0 + 1 (E[ r I B ]) 2 2 γvar[ r I B ] if E[ r I B ] > 0 0 if E[ r I B ] 0 Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 11 / 37

Model Advisor s decision The equilibrium of the game depends on the information level π of the buyer whenever π [1/2, π0 ) there exists a unique pooling equilibrium σ (r H ) = r H ; σ (r L ) = r H the equilibrium is not informative whenever π [π 0, 1] there exists a unique fully revealing equilibrium σ (r H ) = r H ; σ (r L ) = r L the equilibrium is informative Implications - advisors are not useful to the investors who need them the most, and they fail to be a substitute to learning by one s self. - regressive effect on the distribution of information among investors Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 12 / 37

Model Investor s decision Given that investors are fully rational and know the payoff function of the advisor, and Given that under delegation the advisor buys a positive amount of risky asset on behalf of the customer for any value of the asset s return, inducing an expected loss to the investor when r = r L when π [1/2, π 0 ), the investor either decides without asking advice or delegates the portfolio choice to the advisor; when π [π0, 1] the investor strictly prefers to consult the advisor. Check whether these results (demand side) hold empirically Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 13 / 37

Empirical Analysis Data/Descriptives Data 2007 Unicredit Customers Survey (UCS) Sample: representative of bank customers with e10,000 in the bank. N = 1,686. Pre-crisis data Contains information on socio-demographics, income and wealth (also held outside Unicredit), financial literacy, investment attitudes, etc. but no administrative information on bank advisors Italy. Relevant setting to verify model results because banks are the main source of information/advice, while independent/fee-based advice is almost non-existent Beltratti 2007 Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 14 / 37

Empirical Analysis Data/Descriptives Financial literacy Percent 0 10 20 30 0 2 4 6 8 Financial literacy (Number correct) Financial literacy: test-based (number of correct answers to 8 questions on interest rate, inflation, risk diversification and riskiness of financial products, as in Guiso and Jappelli 2008) Example: Imagine that a saving account earns an interest of 2 percent per year (net of costs). If the annual inflation rate is 2 percent, after two years (with no withdrawals) do you think you could buy more than what you could buy today, less, the same, do not know? 34% Correct 55% Incorrect 11% Do not know Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 15 / 37

Empirical Analysis Reliance on financial advice How much to rely on financial advisors Table: Which of these statements best describes your behaviour in deciding how to invest your savings? Percent Financial literacy Mean Std. Dev. The advisor executes my decisions 12.03 4.97 1.33 I ask for advisor s opinion 30.21 4.98 1.25 I consider advisor s proposals 38.01 5.09 1.32 I mostly rely on advisor 16.1 4.63 1.48 Advisor decides everything 3.65 4.30 1.19 Total (N=1205) 100 4.94 1.34 Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 16 / 37

Empirical Analysis Reliance on financial advice How much to rely on financial advisors Table: Which of these statements best describes your behaviour in deciding how to invest your savings? Percent Financial literacy Mean Std. Dev. The advisor executes my decisions 12.03 4.97 1.33 I ask for advisor s opinion 30.21 4.98 1.25 I consider advisor s proposals 38.01 5.09 1.32 I mostly rely on advisor 16.1 4.63 1.48 Advisor decides everything 3.65 4.30 1.19 Total (N=1205) 100 4.94 1.34 Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 17 / 37

Empirical Analysis Reliance on financial advice How much to rely on financial advisors Empirical specification: generalized ordered probit (Terza 1985; Greene and Hensher 2010) P(D i = 1) = F ( X β 1 ) P(D i = j) = F (κ j X β j ) F (κ j 1 X β j 1 ), j = 2,..., J 1 P(D i = J) = 1 F (κ J X β J ) where J = 5, F (.) is the normal cdf, and D i is the delegation level of i: D i = 1 I decide completely autonomously, the bank executes my decisions. D i = 5 I let bank/advisor decide everything Explanatory variables: gender, age, years of education, occupational status, (macro) regions of residence, log individual income, financial wealth categories, experience, whether the respondent works in the financial sector, length of bank relationship, time preference, (objective) financial literacy, self-assessed financial knowledge and trust Observations where Unicredit is not the main bank are dropped Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 18 / 37

Empirical Analysis Reliance on financial advice How much to rely on financial advisors D i = 1 D i = 2 D i = 3 D i = 4 D i = 5 Financial literacy -0.012** -0.003 0.037*** -0.017** -0.005** Years school 0.004*** 0.008*** -0.004*** -0.007*** -0.001*** Self-employed 0.000 0.001-0.000-0.001-0.000 Retired 0.005 0.009-0.005-0.008-0.002 Log tot ind income -0.007-0.012 0.007 0.011 0.002 FinW 150-250 th -0.038*** -0.077** 0.030*** 0.068** 0.016* FinW 250-500 th -0.033** -0.064** 0.027*** 0.057* 0.013* FinW 500+ th -0.014-0.026 0.012 0.023 0.005 Self-ass knowledge 0.022*** 0.039*** -0.021*** -0.033*** -0.007*** Experience 0.000 0.001-0.000-0.001-0.000 Finance sector 0.104** 0.105*** -0.104** -0.091*** -0.014*** Trust advisor -0.085*** -0.018-0.009 0.086*** 0.026*** Patience -0.048-0.084 0.045 0.072 0.015 Years at UC: 6-10 0.023 0.036-0.022-0.030-0.006 Years at UC: 11-20 0.036* 0.056* -0.035* -0.048* -0.009* Years at UC: > 20 0.024 0.041-0.022-0.035-0.007 Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: probability of delegating financial decisions (D i = 1,..., 5). Model: Generalized Ordered Probit (marginal effects). Sub-sample of investors holding risky assets. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 19 / 37

Empirical Analysis Robustness checks Robustness checks Alternative indices of financial literacy Restrict to sample of respondents who do not have other bank or broker relationships Financial literacy endogeneity Trust endogeneity Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 20 / 37

Conclusions Concluding remarks Main result: Financial literacy increases the probability of asking for professional advice, but reduces that of delegating. In contexts where the supply of independent/fee-based financial advice is limited (as in Italy), this is the wisest choice Implications: Low financial literacy consumers may make sub-optimal decisions in relation to the choice and degree of reliance on sources of advice Investors who seek advice are those who need it relatively less. Non-independent advisors are not useful to the investors who need them the most, as they fail to be a substitute to lack of financial knowledge. Financial literacy is needed also in the presence of professional advisors Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 21 / 37

Conclusions Appendix Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 22 / 37

Appendix United States Which sources of information do households use for investment decisions? Friends, relatives Bankers, brokers Lawyers, accountants Internet Material in the mail Calling around Print media 2007 2004 2001 1998 0 10 20 30 40 % Source: Survey of Consumer Finances, various years Intro Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 23 / 37

Appendix The Netherlands The most important source of advice for financial decisions % 0 20 40 60 80 100 2005 2006 Source: Dutch Household Survey 2005-2006 Other Financial computer programs Ads Bank brochures Magazines/books Newspapers Internet Professional financial advisor Parents, friends Intro Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 24 / 37

Appendix Italy The main source of financial information % 0 20 40 60 80 100 2001 2003 2005 2007 Source: BNL/Centro Einaudi 2007 DK/refuse None Other TV Internet Newspapers Friends/family Broker Bank Intro Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 25 / 37

Appendix Frequency of cheating by bank/insurance company Germany Spain France Percent 0 20 40 60 80 0 20 40 60 80 UK Italy Netherlands Never 1 2 3-4 5+ Never 1 2 3-4 5+ Never 1 2 3-4 5+ Times cheated by bank/insurance company, last 5 yrs Source: ESS 2004 Intro Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 26 / 37

Appendix Sources of advice (UCS 2007) Bank Broker Friends/Relatives Percent 0 20 40 60 0 20 40 60 TV/Radio Press Internet Never Very often Never Very often Never Very often Frequency of use of various sources of info/advice (Source: UCS 2007) Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 27 / 37

Appendix Table: Probability of Delegating Financial Decisions (Ordered Probit) D i = 1 D i = 2 D i = 3 D i = 4 D i = 5 Selection Log tot ind income -0.008-0.010 0.007 0.009 0.002-0.003 FinW 150-250 th -0.051** -0.077** 0.037** 0.070** 0.021** 0.147*** FinW 250-500 th -0.046** -0.067** 0.034** 0.061** 0.018* 0.159*** FinW 500+ th -0.024-0.034 0.019 0.030 0.009 0.172*** Financial literacy -0.000-0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.045*** Self-confidence 0.026*** 0.032*** -0.022*** -0.029*** -0.008** 0.028* Experience 0.000 0.000-0.000-0.000-0.000 0.008*** Finance sector 0.110** 0.080*** -0.096** -0.078*** -0.016*** 0.056 Trust advisor -0.076*** -0.094*** 0.063*** 0.085*** 0.022*** 0.048*** Patience -0.064-0.079 0.053 0.071 0.018 0.312* Very risk tolerant 0.224*** Risk tolerant 0.127*** Risk averse 0.139*** Saving: 0% -0.138*** N 1581 ρ 0.175 ρ std. err. (0.169) Data: Unicredit 2007. Dependent variable: columns I-V, probability of delegating financial decisions (D i = 1,..., 5); Column VI, probability of holding risky assets. Model: Ordered Probit with selection. Exclusion restrictions (Column VI) are risk preferences; zero saving rate. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 28 / 37

Appendix Table: Investing autonomously or delegating Robustness on financial literacy index D i = 1 D i = 2 D i = 3 D i = 4 D i = 5 Financial literacy 1-0.0100** -0.0023 0.0298*** -0.0137** -0.0039** Financial literacy 2-0.0070* -0.0018 0.0207*** -0.0084-0.0035** Financial literacy 3-0.0032 0.0028 0.0141** -0.0096* -0.0040*** Financial literacy 4-0.0016 0.0023 0.0078-0.0054-0.0032** Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: probability of delegating financial decisions (D i = 1,..., 5). Model: Generalized Ordered Probit (marginal effects reported). Definition of financial literacy indices: Financial literacy 1: the baseline (Guiso and Jappelli 2008), re-scaled (10 (Inflation+Interest +Diversif 1+Diversif 2+Risk1+Risk2+ Risk3+Risk4)/8; Financial literacy 2: 10 [Inflation+Interest+Diversif 1+Diversif 2+(Risk1+Risk2+Risk3+ Risk4)/4]/5; Financial literacy 3: 10 [Interest +Diversif 1+Diversif 2+(Risk1+Risk2+Risk3+Risk4)/4]/4; Financial literacy 4: 10 [Interest + Diversif 1 + Diversif 2]/3. Sub-sample of investors holding risky assets. Standard errors reported in parentheses are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 29 / 37

Appendix Table: Investing autonomously or delegating D i = 1 D i = 2 D i = 3 D i = 4 D i = 5 Sample: Unicredit main or only bank (baseline) (N = 1,116) Financial literacy -0.012** -0.003 0.037*** -0.017** -0.005** Sample: Unicredit only bank (N = 802) Financial literacy -0.017** 0.005 0.033*** -0.017* -0.005 Sample: Unicredit main/only bank and use broker never/seldom/sometimes (N = 847) Financial literacy -0.012 0.002 0.032*** -0.016* -0.005** Sample: Unicredit main/only bank and use broker never/seldom (N = 705) Financial literacy -0.012 0.001 0.037*** -0.019* -0.007** Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: probability of delegating financial decisions (D i = 1,..., 5). Model: Generalized Ordered Probit. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 30 / 37

Appendix Robustness Financial literacy endogeneity Reverse causality: Financial literacy may be positively correlated with the tendency to consult advisors because individuals learn from them (and not because financially literate individuals choose to consult them) Spurious relation: Unobserved factor driving both decision to invest in acquisition of financial knowledge and demand for advice Instrument financial literacy (Control Function approach). Instruments: average financial literacy at regional level (SHIW) and experience with financial products (UCS). Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 31 / 37

Appendix Robustness Financial literacy endogeneity Table: First stage Dependent Variable: Financial Literacy (UCS) Experience 0.018*** Regional Fin Lit (SHIW) 0.424** N obs 1116 F excl instr 17.90 Hansen J 1.892 Hansen J p-value 0.169 Endog test 0.240 Endog test p-value 0.624 Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: Financial Literacy (baseline). Model: linear model estimated by GMM (first stage). Standard errors robust to heteroskedasticity and clustering on regions. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 32 / 37

Appendix Robustness Financial literacy endogeneity Table: Investing autonomously or delegating (controlling for financial literacy endogeneity) D i = 1 D i = 2 D i = 3 D i = 4 D i = 5 Financial literacy -0.017-0.024 0.084** -0.030-0.014 Residuals 0.006 0.027-0.056 0.014 0.010 Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: probability of delegating financial decisions (D i = 1,..., 5). Model: Generalized Ordered Probit, controlling for financial literacy endogeneity via control function approach (marginal effects reported). Instruments for financial literacy: average financial literacy at regional level (SHIW) and experience with financial products (UCS). Bootstrapped standard errors (200 repetitions) are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustering at regional level. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 33 / 37

Appendix Table: Dep Var: trust in own financial advisor (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) Female 0.185*** 0.182*** 0.183*** 0.178*** 0.181*** 0.178*** Years school 0.003 0.003 0.006 0.006 0.004 0.005 Financial literacy -0.013-0.009-0.013-0.008-0.009-0.006 Self-confidence 0.053 0.053 0.050 0.042 0.050 0.043 Experience 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.002 0.002 0.002 Finance sector -0.332* -0.309* -0.293* -0.278-0.291* -0.279 Years at UC: 6-10 -0.126* -0.121-0.136* -0.137* -0.130* -0.132* Years at UC: 11-20 -0.124* -0.126* -0.128* -0.120* -0.128* -0.121* Years at UC: > 20-0.146** -0.134** -0.140** -0.129* -0.126* -0.120* Generalized trust 0.181*** Trust in banks (reg) 2.287** 1.767* 1.409 GDP growth 0.016 0.012 0.016 0.012 Referendum 2006 (prov) 0.022*** 0.017** Senate 2006 (prov) 0.041*** 0.035*** Constant 3.838*** 3.811*** 2.795*** 0.567 3.036*** 1.078 N obs 1581 1581 1581 1581 1581 1581 Adj. R-Squared 0.051 0.051 0.052 0.058 0.056 0.060 Data: Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: Trust in own financial advisor/bank official. Model: linear model estimated by OLS. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustering on provinces. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 34 / 37

Appendix Table: Dependent Variable: Pr(D i 4) Sub-sample: Unicredit customers for 5 years Unicredit customers for > 5 years Trust advisor 0.102*** 0.114*** (0.04) (0.02) N obs 82 1034 Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: Probability of Delegating Financial Decisions (Pr(D i 4)). Model: Generalized Ordered Probit. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 35 / 37

Appendix Table: Delegating financial decisions (controlling for trust endogeneity) First Stage Second Stage Dep Var: Trust Pr(D i 4) D i Model: Probit LPM LPM (I) (II) (III) (IV) Trust in banks 1.784* Referendum 2006 0.019*** Trust advisor 0.089-0.024 0.096 Fitted residuals 0.025 N obs 1116 1116 1116 1116 F excl instr 4.629 4.629 Hansen J 0.516 0.342 Hansen J p-value 0.472 0.559 Unicredit 2007. First column: first stage regression, dep var: trust towards advisor, model: OLS. Second column: second stage regression, dep var: probability of delegating (D i 4), model: probit with CF (Bootstrapped standard errors with 200 repetitions). Third column: second stage regression, dep var: probability of delegating (Pr(D i 4)), model: linear probability model by GMM. Fourth column: second stage regression, dep var: delegation (D i ), model: GMM. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustering on provinces. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 36 / 37

Appendix Table: Dep Var: Pr(D i 4) Sub-sample: Financial Literacy Financial Literacy Below average ( 4) Above average (> 4) Trust advisor 0.109*** 0.109*** (0.03) (0.02) N obs 384 732 Unicredit 2007. Dep Var: Probability of Delegating Financial Decisions (Pr(D i 4)). Model: Generalized Ordered Probit. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Calcagno & Monticone (EM Lyon OECD) Financial Literacy and Financial Advice 37 / 37