Equilibrium Asset Returns

Similar documents
Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Mean-Variance Analysis

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Microeconomics 3. Economics Programme, University of Copenhagen. Spring semester Lars Peter Østerdal. Week 17

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Ch. 2. Asset Pricing Theory (721383S)

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Basics of Derivative Pricing

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

One-Factor Models { 1 Key features of one-factor (equilibrium) models: { All bond prices are a function of a single state variable, the short rate. {

ECON Financial Economics

A note on the term structure of risk aversion in utility-based pricing systems

Optimal Portfolio Selection

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

PREPRINT 2007:3. Robust Portfolio Optimization CARL LINDBERG

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Robust portfolio optimization

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Introduction: A Shortcut to "MM" (derivative) Asset Pricing**

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

Answer Key Practice Final Exam

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Pricing in the Multi-Line Insurer with Dependent Gamma Distributed Risks allowing for Frictional Costs of Capital

ECON Micro Foundations

Risk Neutral Modelling Exercises

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Optimizing Portfolios

Lecture Notes 1

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

Extensions of the SABR Model for Equity Options

Markowitz portfolio theory

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Applications of Linear Programming

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

1 Unemployment Insurance

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

The Term Structure of Expected Inflation Rates

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Consumption and Portfolio Choice with Option-Implied State Prices

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Lecture 3: Return vs Risk: Mean-Variance Analysis

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

A.1. Verifying that the period-by-period household budget constraint (12) is satis ed and that the current account is zero, to rst order

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Econ Review Set 3 - Answers

Exercises on chapter 4

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

Option Pricing Models for European Options

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Quantitative Portfolio Theory & Performance Analysis

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

EconS Micro Theory I Recitation #8b - Uncertainty II

Transcription:

Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns 1/ 38

Introduction We analyze the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Robert Merton (1973). The standard single-period CAPM holds when investment opportunities are constant, but with changing investment opportunities, a multi-beta ICAPM results. Breeden (1979) shows that this multi-beta ICAPM can be written as a single consumption beta CAPM (CCAPM). We also analyze the general equilibrium production economy model of (Cox, Ingersoll and Ross,1985) that is useful for pricing contingent claims. Equilibrium Asset Returns 2/ 38

ICAPM Model Assumptions Individuals can trade in a risk-free asset paying rate of return of r (t) and in n risky assets whose rates of return are ds i (t) = S i (t) = i (x; t) dt + i (x; t) dz i (1) where i = 1; :::; n, and ( i dz i )( j dz j ) = ij dt. The k state variables follow the process: dx i = a i (x; t) dt + b i (x; t) d i (2) where i = 1; :::; k, and (b i d i )(b j d j ) = b ij dt and ( i dz i )(b j d j ) = ij dt. Equilibrium Asset Returns 3/ 38

Constant Investment Opportunities When r and the i s, i s, and ij s are constants, we showed previously that it is optimal for all individuals to choose the risky assets in the relative proportions k = nx kj ( j r) j=1 nx i=1 j=1 nx ij ( j r) This single risky asset portfolio s mean and variance is nx i i 2 i=1 nx i=1 j=1 (3) nx i j ij : (4) Equilibrium Asset Returns 4/ 38

CAPM Equilibrium Similar to our derivation of the single-period CAPM, we argue that in equilibrium this common risky-asset portfolio must be the market portfolio; that is, = m and 2 = 2 m. Moreover, the continuous-time market portfolio is exactly the same as that implied by the single-period CAPM. Thus, asset returns in this continuous-time environment satisfy the same relationship as the single-period CAPM: where i = im = 2 m. i r = i ( m r) ; i = 1; : : :, n (5) Equilibrium Asset Returns 5/ 38

CAPM Implications Thus, the constant investment opportunity set assumption replicates the standard, single-period CAPM. Yet, rather than asset returns being normally distributed as in the single-period CAPM, the ICAPM has asset returns that are lognormally distributed. While the standard CAPM results continue to hold for this more realistic intertemporal environment, the assumptions of a constant risk-free rate and unchanging asset return means and variances are untenable. Clearly, interest rates vary over time, as do the volatilities of assets such as common stocks. Equilibrium Asset Returns 6/ 38

Stochastic Investment Opportunities For a single state variable, x, the system of n equations that an individual s portfolio weights satisfy are: 0 = A( i r) + nx ij! j W H i ; i = 1; : : : ; n (6) j=1 where A = J W =J WW = U C = [U CC (@C=@W )] and H = J Wx =J WW = (@C=@x) = (@C=@W ). Rewrite (6) in matrix form, and use the superscript p to denote the values for the p th person (individual): A p ( re) =! p W p H p (7) where = ( 1 ; :::; n ) 0, e is an n-dimensional vector of ones,! p = (! p 1 ; :::;!p n) 0 and = ( 1 ; :::; n ) 0. Equilibrium Asset Returns 7/ 38

Aggregate Asset Demands Sum (7) across all persons and divide by P p Ap : re = a h (8) where a P p W p = P p Ap, h P p Hp = P p Ap, and P p!p W p = P p W p is the average investment in each asset. These must be the market weights. The i th row (i th asset excess return) of equation (8) is Pre-multiply (8) by 0 to obtain i r = a im h i (9) m r = a 2 m h mx (10) where mx = 0 is the covariance between the market portfolio and the state variable, x. Equilibrium Asset Returns 8/ 38

Portfolio that Best Hedges the State Variable De ne 1, which are the weights of the portfolio that e 0 1 best hedge changes in the state variable, x. The expected excess return on this portfolio is found by pre-multiplying (8) by 0 : r = a m h x (11) where m and x are the hedge portfolio s covariances with the market portfolio and the state variable, respectively. Solving the two linear equations (10) and (11) for a and h, and substituting them back into equation (9) gives: i r = im x i m 2 m x mx m ( m r)+ i 2 m im mx 2 m x mx m r (12) Equilibrium Asset Returns 9/ 38

ICAPM It can be shown that (12) is equivalent to i r = im 2 i m 2 m 2 2 m ( m r) + i 2 m im m 2 2 m 2 m m i ( m r) + i r (13) where i is the covariance between the return on asset i and that of the hedge portfolio. i = 0 i i = 0. If x is uncorrelated with the market so that m = 0, equation (13) simpli es to r i r = im 2 m ( m r) + i 2 r (14) Equation (13) generalizes to multiple state variables with an additional beta for each state (c.f., APT). Equilibrium Asset Returns 10/ 38

Extension to State-Dependent Utility If an individual s utility is a ected by the state of economy, so that U (C t ; x t ; t), the form of the rst order conditions for consumption (C t ) and the portfolio weights (! i ) remain unchanged and equation (13) continues to hold. The only change is the interpretation of H, the hedging coe cient. Taking the total derivative of envelope condition J W = U C : @C J Wx = U CC @x + U Cx (15) so that H = @C=@x @C=@W U Cx U CC @C @W implying that portfolio holdings minimize the variance of marginal utility. (16) Equilibrium Asset Returns 11/ 38

Breeden s Consumption CAPM Substitute in for A p and H p in equation (7) for the case of k state variables and rearrange to obtain: U p C U p CC C p W ( re) =! p W p + C p x=c p W (17) where C p W = @C p =@W p, C p x = @C p 0, @x 1 ::: @C p @x k and is the n k asset return - state variable covariance matrix whose i,j th element is ij. Pre-multiplying (17) by C p W : U p C U p CC ( re) = W pc p W + Cp x (18) where W p is n 1 vector of covariances between asset returns and investor p s wealth. Equilibrium Asset Returns 12/ 38

Covariance between Asset Returns and Consumption Using Itô s lemma, individual p s optimal consumption, C p (W p ; x; t), follows a process whose stochastic terms for dc p are C p W!p 1 W p 1 dz 1 + ::: +! p nw p n dz n +(b1 d 1 b 2 d 2 :::b k d k ) C p x (19) The covariance of asset returns with changes in individual p s consumption are given by calculating the covariance between each asset (having stochastic term i dz i ) with the terms given in (19). Denoting C p as this n 1 vector of covariances: C p = W pc p W +Cp x (20) Equilibrium Asset Returns 13/ 38

Consumption Covariance The right-hand sides of (20) and (18) are equal, implying: C p = U p C U p CC ( re) (21) De ne C as aggregate consumption per unit time and de ne T as an aggregate rate of risk tolerance where T X p U p C U p CC (22) Then aggregate (21) over all individuals to obtain re = T 1 C (23) where C is the n 1 vector of covariances between asset returns and changes in aggregate consumption. Equilibrium Asset Returns 14/ 38

Excess Expected Returns on Risky Assets Multiply and divide the right-hand side of (23) by current aggregate consumption to obtain: re = (T=C) 1 ln C (24) where ln C is the n 1 vector of covariances between asset returns and changes in log consumption growth. Let a portfolio, m, have weights! m that pre-multiply (24): m r = (T=C) 1 m;ln C (25) where portfolio m s expected return and covariance with consumption growth is m and m;ln C. Portfolio m may or may not be the market portfolio. Equilibrium Asset Returns 15/ 38

Consumption CAPM Use (25) to substitute for (T=C) 1 in (24): re = ( ln C = m;ln C ) ( m r) = ( C = mc ) ( m r) (26) where C and mc are the consumption betas of all asset returns and portfolio m s return. The consumption beta for any asset is de ned as: ic = cov (ds i =S i ; d ln C) =var (d ln C) (27) Equation (26) says that the ratio of expected excess returns on any two assets or portfolios of assets is equal to the ratio of their betas measured relative to aggregate consumption. Hence, the risk of a security s return can be summarized by a single consumption beta. Equilibrium Asset Returns 16/ 38

A Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross Production Economy The ICAPM and CCAPM are not general equilibrium models since they take the form of equilibrium asset price processes as given. However, their asset price process can be justi ed based on the Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985) continuous-time, production economy model. The model assumes that there is a single good that can be either consumed or invested. This capital-consumption good can be invested in any of n di erent risky technologies that produce an instantaneous change in the amount of this good. Equilibrium Asset Returns 17/ 38

Model Assumptions If an amount i is physically invested in technology i, then the proportional change in the good produced is d i (t) i (t) = i (x; t) dt + i (x; t) dz i, i = 1; :::; n (28) where ( i dz i )( j dz j ) = ij dt. The rate of change in the invested good produced has expected value and standard deviation of i and i. Note that each technology displays constant returns to scale and i and i can vary with time and with a k 1 vector of state variables, x(t). Thus, the economy s technologies for transforming consumption into more consumption re ect changing (physical) investment opportunities. Equilibrium Asset Returns 18/ 38

Model Assumptions cont d The i th state variable is assumed to follow the process dx i = a i (x; t) dt + b i (x; t) d i (29) where i = 1; :::; k, and (b i d i )(b j d j ) = b ij dt and ( i dz i )(b j d j ) = ij dt. If each technology is owned by an individual rm, nanced entirely by shareholders equity, then the rate of return on shareholders equity of rm i, ds i (t) =S i (t), equals the proportional change in the value of the rm s physical assets (capital), d i (t) = i (t). Here, ds i (t) =S i (t) = d i (t) = i (t) equals the instantaneous dividend yield where dividends come in the form of a physical capital-consumption good. Equilibrium Asset Returns 19/ 38

Model Assumptions cont d CIR s speci cation allows one to solve for the equilibrium prices of securities other than those represented by the n risky technologies. This is done by imagining there to be other securities that have zero net supplies. Assuming all individuals are identical in preferences and wealth, this amounts to the riskless investment having a zero supply in the economy, so that r is really a shadow riskless rate. Yet, this rate would be consistent, in equilibrium, with the speci cation of the economy s other technologies. Equilibrium Asset Returns 20/ 38

Solving for the Equilibrium Riskless Rate An individual s consumption and portfolio choice problem allocates savings to rms investing in the n technologies. An equilibrium is de ned as a set of interest rate, consumption, and portfolio weight processes fr; C ;! 1 ; :::;! ng such that the individual s rst order conditions hold and markets clear: P n i=1! i = 1 and! i 0. Since the capital-consumption good is physically invested in the technologies, the constraint against short-selling,! i 0, applies. Because, in equilibrium, the representative individuals do not borrow or lend, the situation is exactly as if a riskless asset did not exist. Equilibrium Asset Returns 21/ 38

Optimization without a Riskless Asset Consider the individual s problem as before except that the process for wealth excludes a risk-free asset: Z T max E t U (C s ; s) ds + B(W T ; T ) (30) C s ;f! i;s g;8s;i subject to dw = t nx! i W i dt C t dt + i=1 nx! i W i dz i (31) and P n i=1! i = 1 and! i 0. The rst order condition for consumption is 0 = @U (C ; t) @C i=1 @J (W ; x; t) @W (32) Equilibrium Asset Returns 22/ 38

Optimal Portfolio Weights with Short Sale Constraints Let be the Lagrange multiplier for P n i=1! i = 1. Then the rst order conditions for! i is i @J @W i W + @2 J @W 2 np ij! j W 2 P + k j=1 j=1 @ 2 J @x j @W ijw 0 0 = i! i i = 1; : : : ; n (33) Kuhn-Tucker conditions (33) imply that if i < 0, then! i = 0, so that i th technology is not employed. Assuming (28) and (29) are such that all technologies are employed so i = 0 8i, then the solution is! i = J W J WW W np ij j j=1 kp m=1 j=1 np J Wxm J WW W ij jm + J WW W 2 np ij j=1 (34) Equilibrium Asset Returns 23/ 38

Equilibrium Portfolio Allocation Using matrix notation, (34) becomes! = A W 1 A J W W 2 1 e+ kx j=1 H j W 1 j (35) where A = J W =J WW, H j = J Wxj =J WW, and j = ( 1j ; :::; nj ) 0. The weights are a linear combination of k + 2 portfolios. The rst two portfolios are mean-variance e cient portfolios: 1 is the portfolio on the e cient frontier that is tangent to a line drawn from the origin (a zero interest rate) while 1 e is the global minimum variance portfolio. The last k portfolios, 1 j, j = 1; :::; k, hedge against changes in the technological investment opportunities. Equilibrium Asset Returns 24/ 38

Equilibrium Consumption and Portfolio Weights The proportions of these k + 2 portfolios chosen depend on the individual s utility. An exact solution is found in the usual manner of substituting (35) and C = G (J W ) into the Bellman equation. For speci c functional forms, a value for the indirect utility function, J (W ; x; t) can be derived. This, along with the restriction P n i=1! i = 1, determines the speci c optimal consumption and portfolio weights. Since in the CIR economy the riskless asset is in zero net supply, portfolio weights in (35) must be those chosen by the representative individual even if o ered the opportunity to borrow or lend at rate r. Equilibrium Asset Returns 25/ 38

Portfolio Allocation with a Riskless Asset Recall that portfolio weights for the case of including a risk-free asset are! = A kx W 1 H j ( re) + W 1 j ; i = 1; : : : ; n (36) j=1 (35) and (36) are identical when r = = (J W W ). Hence, r = WJ W (37) =! 0 W A!0! + kx j=1 H j A!0 j (37) is the same as (10) extended to k state variables. Hence, the ICAPM and CCAPM hold for the CIR economy. Equilibrium Asset Returns 26/ 38

Valuing Contingent Claims in Zero Net Supply The CIR model also can be used to nd the equilibrium shadow prices of other contingent claims. Suppose the payo of a zero-net-supply contingent claim depends on wealth, time, and the state variables, so that P (W ; t; fx i g). Itô s lemma implies where dp = updt + P W W P n i=1! i i dz i + P k i=1 P x i b i d i (38) up = P W W! 0 C + P k i=1 P x i a i + P t + P WW W 2! 0! 2 + P k i=1 P Wx i W! 0 i + 1 2 P k i=1 P k j=1 P x i x j b ij (39) Equilibrium Asset Returns 27/ 38

Expected Return under ICAPM The ICAPM relation (9) extended to k states is u = r + W A Cov (dp=p; dw =W ) P k i=1 H i A Cov (dp=p; dx i ) (40) Noting that the representative agent s wealth is the market portfolio: up = rp + 1 A Cov (dp; dw ) P k H i i=1 A Cov (dp; dx i ) = rp + 1 P W W 2! 0! + P k i=1 A P x i W! 0 i P k i=1 H i A P W W! 0 i + P k j=1 P x j b ij (41) Equilibrium Asset Returns 28/ 38

Equilibrium Partial Di erential Equation Equating (39) and (41) and recalling the value of the equilibrium risk-free rate in (37), we obtain a partial di erential equation for the contingent claim s value: 0 = P WW W 2! 0! + 1 P k P k i=1 j=1 2 2 P x i x j b ij + P k i=1 P Wx i W! 0 i + P W (rw C) + P t P k i=1 P W x i a i A!0 i + P k H j b ij j=1 rp (42) A Equilibrium Asset Returns 29/ 38

An Example with Log Utility Let U(C s ; s) = e s ln (C s ) and B (W T ; T ) = e T ln (W T ). Then we previously showed that J (W ; x; t) = d (t) e t ln (W t ) + F (x; t) where d (t) = 1 1 (1 ) e (T t), so that Ct = W t =d (t). Since J Wxi = 0, H i = 0, and A = W, the portfolio weights in (35) are! = 1 ( re) (43) where r = = (J W W ). Equilibrium Asset Returns 30/ 38

Market Portfolio Weights Market clearing requires e 0! = 1, and solving for r(t): r = e0 1 1 e 0 1 e (44) Substituting (44) into (43),the equilibrium portfolio weights are: e! = 1 0 1 1 e 0 1 e (45) e Equilibrium Asset Returns 31/ 38

Square Root Process State Variable Assume that a single state variable, x (t) ; a ects all production processes: d i = i = b i x dt + b i p xdzi, i = 1; :::; n (46) where b i and b i are assumed to be constants and the state variable follows the square root process where dz i d = i dt. dx = (a 0 + a 1 x) dt + b 0 p xd (47) If a 0 > 0 and a 1 < 0, x is a nonnegative, mean-reverting random variable. Equilibrium Asset Returns 32/ 38

Equilibrium Interest Rate Process Write the technologies n 1 vector of expected rates of return as = bx and their n n matrix of rate of return covariances as = b x. Then from (44), the equilibrium interest rate is r = e0 b 1 b 1 e 0 b x = x (48) 1 e where e 0 b 1 b 1 =e 0 b 1 e is a constant. Thus, the risk-free rate follows the square root process: dr = dx = (r r) dt + p rd (49) where a 1 > 0, r a 0 =a 1 > 0, and b 0 p. When 2r 2, if r (t) > 0 it remains positive at all future dates, as would a nominal interest rate. Equilibrium Asset Returns 33/ 38

Valuing Default-Free Discount Bonds Consider the price of a default-free bond that matures at T t. P W, P WW, and P Wx in (42) are zero, and since r = x, the bond s price can be written as P (r; t; T ). The PDE (42) becomes 2 r 2 P rr + [ (r r) r] P r rp + P t = 0 (50) where b! 0. b b! equals the right-hand side of equation (45) but with replaced by b and replaced by, b while b is an n 1 vector whose i th element is b i i. r =! 0 is the covariance of interest rate changes with (market) wealth, or the interest rate s beta. Equilibrium Asset Returns 34/ 38

Solution for Bond Prices Solving PDE (50) subject to P (r; T ; T ) = 1 leads to where = T P (r; t; T ) = A () e B()r (51) q t, ( + ) 2 + 2 2, " 2e (++ ) 2 A () ( + + ) (e 1) + 2 B () # 2r = 2 2 e 1 ( + + ) (e 1) + 2 (52) (53) Note that the bond price is derived from an equilibrium model of preferences and technologies rather than the absence of arbitrage (c.f., Vasicek). Equilibrium Asset Returns 35/ 38

Equilibrium Bond Price Process Note that Itô s lemma implies the bond price follows dp = P r dr + 1 2 P rr 2 rdt + P t dt (54) 1 = 2 P rr 2 r + P r [ (r r)] + P t dt + P r p rd From (50) 1 2 P rr 2 r + P r [ (r dp=p = r r)] + P t = rp + rp r, so that 1 + P r dt + P r P P p rd (55) = r (1 B ()) dt B () p rd where from (51) we substituted P r =P = B (). Equilibrium Asset Returns 36/ 38

Equilibrium Market Price of Interest Rate Risk Hence, p (r; ) p (r; ) r = rb () p rb () = p r (56) Thus we see that the market price of interest rate risk is proportional to the square root of the interest rate. When < 0, which occurs when the interest rate is negatively correlated with the return on the market portfolio (and bond prices are positively correlated with the market portfolio), bonds will carry a positive risk premium. Equilibrium Asset Returns 37/ 38

Summary The Merton ICAPM shows that when investment opportunities are constant, the expected returns on assets satisfy the single-period CAPM In general, an asset s risk premia include the asset s covariances with asset portfolios that hedge against changes in investment opportunities. The multi-beta ICAPM can be simpli ed to a single consumption beta CCAPM. The Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross model shows the ICAPM results are consistent with a general equilibrium production economy. The model also is used to derive the equilibrium interest rate and the shadow prices of securities in zero net supply. Equilibrium Asset Returns 38/ 38