Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach

Similar documents
Trade Effects of the Central American Free Trade Agreement

Does monetary integration affect FDI between EU Member States?

The Effects of Common Currencies on Trade

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND MONETARY UNION (EMU)2 is an unprecedented and

The Gravity Model of Trade

CHAPTER 1: Partial equilibrium trade policy analysis with structural gravity 1

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Does the Gravity Model Explain Bangladesh s Direction of Trade? A Panel Data Approach

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

The Impact of U.S. Trade Agreements on Growth in Output and Labor Productivity of FTA Partner Countries

Abstract. Key words: Gravity equation panel data infrastructure integration. 1. Introduction

Evaluating Trade Patterns in the CIS

The Determinants of Bangladesh s Trade: Evidences from the Generalized Gravity Model

The Causative Factors of Bangladesh s Exports: Evidence from the Gravity Model Analysis.

A Panel Data Analysis of Jordan s Foreign Trade: The Gravity Model Approach

Preferential Trade Arrangements In Apparel Exports From The Caribbean To The U.S.: A Dynamic Investment Approach

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Financial Development and International Agricultural Trade: Is There a Connection? Dwi Susanto and C. Parr Rosson

Measuring the Effects of Endogenous Policies on Economic Integration

International Trade: Lecture 4

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

Tax Incentives, International Tax and FDI: Evidence from South-East Asia

Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better!

Offshore Financial Centers: Parasites or Symbionts? Andrew K. Rose and Mark M. Spiegel

International Trade Gravity Model

An Instrumental Variables Panel Data Approach to. Farm Specific Efficiency Estimation

Modelling International Trade

Import nexus of Pakistan

THE EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE VOLATILITY ON WHEAT TRADE WORLDWIDE. May Changyou Sun, Mina Kim, Won Koo, Guedae Cho, and Hyun Jin*

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Intra-European Trade of Manufacturing Goods: An Extension of the Gravity Model. Mark Vancauteren and Daniel Weiserbs ABSTRACT

Does Trade Liberalization Increase the Labor Demand Elasticities? Evidence from Pakistan

Monopolistic competition models

Gains from Trade 1-3

ECON* International Trade Winter 2011 Instructor: Patrick Martin

Potential Impacts of the TPP on Agricultural Trade in the Asia-Pacific Region Utilizing a Gravity Model Framework

Increasing Returns Versus National Product Differentiation as an Explanation for the Pattern of U.S. Canada Trade

A Gravity Model for Exports From Iceland.

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA

FS January, A CROSS-COUNTRY COMPARISON OF EFFICIENCY OF FIRMS IN THE FOOD INDUSTRY. Yvonne J. Acheampong Michael E.

THE IMPACT OF ASEAN FREE TRADE AREA ON INTRA- ASEAN MANUFACTURING TRADE

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Lecture 7-9 2/8-15/2016

THE UNEVEN ROLES OF FTAS: SELECTION EFFECT OR LEARNING EFFECT? Faqin Lin *

Intra-European Trade of Manufacturing Goods : An Extension of the Gravity model

Internal and External Effects of R&D Subsidies and Fiscal Incentives Empirical Evidence Using Spatial Dynamic Panel Models

International Trade. Lecture 3: the Krugman model of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 24

How might CAFTA change macroeconomic fluctuations in Central America? Lessons from NAFTA

The Impact of Mutual Recognition Agreements on Foreign Direct Investment and. Export. Yong Joon Jang. Oct. 11, 2010

1 The Solow Growth Model

Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Asymmetric Pattern of Intra-industry Trade Between the United States and Canada

On the Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements

ENDOGENEITY AND DYNAMICS IN THE IMPACT OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ON TRADE AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CRISTINA LIRA A DISSERTATION

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

Institutional Distance and Foreign Direct Investment

Income Convergence in the South: Myth or Reality?

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Using a thought experiment to explore models of relative prices and trade balance:

The Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) of the World Trade

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India

Determinants and Potentials of Foreign Trade in Ethiopia: A Gravity Model Analysis

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

TARIFF REDUCTIONS, TERMS OF TRADE AND PRODUCT VARIETY

The challenge of the international organic certification: a new opportunity for agricultural trading?

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Analysis of trade on El Salvador post dollarization

AN ANALYSIS OF ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL EXPORTS OF PAKISTAN WITH SAARC COUNTRIES: A PANEL DATA ANALYSIS. Sandeep KAUR,* Parmjit NANDA** I.

Price Effects of Preferential Market Access: Caribbean Basin Initiative and the Apparel Sector

Foreign Direct Investment and Exports: the Experiences of Vietnam

Gravity Estimation Model and Trade Intensity

Investment Costs and The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment. In recent decades, most countries have experienced substantial increases in the

OPTIMAL TARIFFS FOR TRADE IN DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS: THE NORTH AMERICAN ONION TRADE

Building on CAFTA - Finance & Development, December 2005

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

The Euro Impact on FDI Revisited and Revised

Ethiopia s Export Performance with Major Trade Partners: A Gravity Model Approach

FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND EXPORTS. SUBSTITUTES OR COMPLEMENTS. EVIDENCE FROM TRANSITION COUNTRIES

World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Bilateral Free Trade Agreements. How do Countries Choose Partners?

Real Wages and Non-Traded Goods

Trade effects of ASEAN-plus-China and -Japan free trade agreements by production stage and industry

North-South FDI and Bilateral Investment Treaties (BITs) Neil Foster-McGregor

Journal of Eastern Europe Research in Business & Economics

Economic Perspectives for Central America after CAFTA: A GTAP-based Analysis

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

Preliminary draft, please do not quote

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

Gravity Redux: Structural Estimation of Gravity Equations with Asymmetric Bilateral Trade Costs

The Gravity Equation in International Trade

The Effect of Exchange Rate Uncertainty on Poland s Trade Flows

DATA BASE AND METHODOLOGY

Transcription:

Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach Osei-Agyeman Yeboah 1 Saleem Shaik 2 Victor Ofori-Boadu 1 Albert Allen 3 Shawn Wozniak 4 1 North Carolina A&T State University 2 North Dakota State University 3 Mississippi State University 4 Graduate Research Assistant at NCA&TSU A Selected Paper Prepared for Presentation at the Domestic and Trade Impacts of U.S. Farm Policy: Future Directions and Challenges," November 15-16, 2007 in Washington D.C.

Background Preferential trading is an important tool used by developed countries to expand trade with developing countries to initiate development in some developing countries, and in some cases, to protect their own domestic industries by securing demand for domestic primary and intermediate inputs for the final products. Caribbean Basin Initiative (CBI)- A unilateral preferential agreement

Background Outward processing programs in apparel and textiles under the Caribbean Basin Initiative (CBI) are some of the more successful preferential trade agreements. Have become an important part of U.S. apparel during the last two decades. In 1999, outward processing apparel trade from the Caribbean countries to the U.S. constituted 14% of US apparel imports, as compared to 9% in 1992.

Background The U.S. imported $55 billion worth of apparel in 1999, and accounted for 36% of world apparel trade (TRAINS 2001 and USITC 2000). U.S. outward processing firms have enjoyed significant preferences in the Caribbean. The average preference margin (the difference between MFN duties and preferential duties) in 1992-93 was 11.7% and went down to 9.9% in 1998-99.

Background As a result of such high preference margins, outward processing firms in the U.S. earned higher profits, increased their operations, and increased employment of foreign labor and the usage of intermediate textiles. The largest apparel producers in the region were Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, and Honduras.

Background Exports grew 145% between 1992-93 and 1998-99, from $3.4 billion to $8.4 Since then, the growth of FTAs has signaled a shift in the U.S. trade policy, raising questions about the future path for those few countries depended on trade preferences.

Objective of Study This study therefore, develops an econometric model that uses bilateral trade factors to estimate the trade potential of textile and apparel under these market access programs from 1990 to 2005.

Gravity Model for Bilateral Trade Potentials Gravity model has become a common knowledge in regional science for describing and analyzing spatial flows. Pioneered in the analysis of international trade by Tinbergen (1962). It yields sensible parameter estimates and explains a large part of the variation in bilateral trade. Recent applications - Anderson (1979); Bergstrand (195; 1989; 1990); Helpman (1987); and so on.

The Generalized Gravity Framework The generalized framework incorporates the Armington assumption that goods produced by different countries are inherently imperfect substitutes by virtue of their provenance. Framework assumes Cobb-Douglas expenditure system. Under the assumption of monopolistic competition, each country is assumed to specialize in different products and to have identical homothetic preferences.

The Generalized Gravity Framework Zero balance of trade is also assumed to hold in each period. Then the equilibrium trade flow from country i to j (X ij *) at any time period t can be expressed as: X ij * = θ i Y j (1) θ i denotes the fraction of income spent on country i s products. Y j denotes real GDP in importing country j

The Generalized Gravity Framework Production in country i must be equal to the sum of exports and domestic consumption of goods. Therefore country i's GDP is expressed as follows: Y i = X * ij = θ i Y j = θ i ( Y j ) (2) Where = Y j = Y w is world real GDP, which is constant across country pairs.

The Generalized Gravity Framework Equating equation (1) and (2) and rearranging yields: X YY YY * i j i j ij Tij Y Y j w (3) Therefore, this simple gravity equation relies only upon the adding-up constraints of a Cobb-Douglas expenditure system with identical homothetic preferences and the specialization of each country in one good.

The Generalized Gravity Framework The basic empirical gravity equation is obtained by taking a natural logarithm of both sides of (3) as follows: * ln X ij lnyi lnyj lntij (4) where α = (- lny j ), and T ij is a vector of time-invariant variables such as distance and border effects. In reality, countries do not have identical and homothetic taste, therefore coefficients should not be unity, but are not significantly different from unity in aggregate level trade (Anderson 1979).

The Econometric Specification Bilateral trade projection - Hamilton and Winters, 1992; Baldwin, 1994. Economic framework (cross-sectional analysis) - Wang and Winters, 1991; Hamilton and Winters, 1992; Brulhart and Kelly, 1999. Only few studies have made use of random effects panel models - Baldwin, 1994; Gros and Gonciarz, 1996; Egger, 2000.

The Econometric Specification According to the traditional concept of gravity equation, bilateral trade can be explained by GDP and GDP per capita figures. Both trade impediment (distance) and preference factors (common border, common language, and so on). Based on the endowment-based new trade model (Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977) Bilateral trade is an increasing sum of factor income G, relative size S, and the difference in relative factor endowments R.

The Econometric Specification Bilateral trade is affected by more traditional measures of transportation D ij and real bilateral exchange rate E ijt. Thus bilateral trade can be estimated by Y G S R D E it 0 1 ijt 2 ijt 3 ijt 4 ij 5 ijt ijt (5) where all variables are in real figures and expressed in natural logs, and the error term can be written as (6) u w ijt ij ijt μ ij as the (fixed or random) unobserved bilateral effect and v ijt as the remaining error.

The Econometric Specification Using the Helpman (1987) model, the Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) bilateral trade determinants can be formulated as follows: G log ijt GDPit GDPjt (7) S ijt GDP GDP jt it (8) R ijt GDP GDP it jt log log N it N jt (9) where, N denotes a country s population and GDP per capita is commonly used as a proxy for a country s capital-labor ratio.

The Econometric Specification For the panel econometric projection of potential bilateral trade, researchers have concentrated on random effects model (REM) Whereas the fixed effects model (FEM) is always consistent in the absence of endogeneity or errors in variables The REM is only consistent when the X ijt are independent of the u ij and v ijt for all crosssections (ij) and time periods (t).

The Econometric Specification If these conditions do hold, only the FEM is consistent since it wipes out all the time-invariant time-effects (u ij ). The decision between FEM and REM can be based on the Hausman (1978) test.

Data and Estimation Procedure Panel data from 1990 to 2005 were used Several variations across individual country are analyzed. one-way FEM one-way REM two-way FEM Apparel and textile export data from each CBI country were obtained from the USITC website (http://www.usitc.gov/) Real GDP data for each country and real exchange rate of each CBI country currency to the U.S. dollar were obtained from the Euromonitor International Database (2006). Distances, measured in meters were obtained using GDA Vincenty Calculation Results (inverse) from Australian Geodetic Datum. (http://www.ga.gov.au/bin/gda_vincenty.cgi)

Results of the Estimated Equations Table 1. Descriptive Analysis of the Variables (N=80) Units Standard Variable Mean Minimum Maximum Deviation Value of Exports Billion $ 1.244 0.753 0.69 2.752 Bilateral Trade GDP Differences in Endowment Size of the Economy Million $ Ratio Ratio 8.706 2.036 5.806 12.448 30.133 5.818 21.305 41.711 0.0014 0.00052 0.0005 0.0025 Distance Miles 2952.36 315.917 2580 3363 Exchange Rate Ratio 60.618 112.077 4.10 477.787

Results of the Estimated Equations Table 2. Results of the Fixed Effect Panel Estimation Procedure Variable Estimate Standard Error Intercept 2.499.*** 0.8184 Exchange Rate -0.9026*** 0.1635 Bilateral Trade GDP -0.5006*** 0.1643 Size of the Economy 3.4885*** 0.5952 Differences in Endowment 1.2052*** 0.1932 Distance 2.4434 1.7839 Costa Rica 3.2954*** 0.7000 Dominican Republic -0.3394 0.4623 El Salvador -1.1597*** 0.2466 Guatemala -1.7023 0.4078 R 2 0.92 F(19, 55) Test for No Fixed Effects 12.91 P < 0.0001 ***Indicates significance at 1% confidence level ** Indicates significance at 5% confidence level

Value ($'Million) Results of the Estimated Equations Figure 1. U.S. Imports of Textile and Apparel from CBI countries (1990-2005) 3,000 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500-1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Years Costa Rica Dominican Republic El Salvador Guatemala Honduras

Results and Discussions Table 2 presents the estimation results for the two-way fixed effect panel estimator. According to the test statistics, the cycle and cross-sectional effects cannot be ignored as the F-statistics for the time and cross-sectional effects are all significant. Besides Dominican Republic, all the four CBI countries have intercepts significantly different from 0 relative to Honduras as reported in Table 2. The intercepts of all the first fifteen years (i.e. 1990 to 2004) are negative and significant relative to 2005. This confirms that imports trend is positive and increasing as shown in Figure 1.

Results and Discussions The coefficients of resource factor endowment and the relative size of the economies are all positive and statistically significant (p < 0.0001). Thus, the larger the per capita GDP difference between U.S. and a CBI country, the larger the imports. The positive coefficients for relative factor endowment differences lends to support the (H-O) explanation of trade. Based on the H-O theory we expect that textile and apparel trade would be positively related to the exporter-to-importer per capita GDP differences. The elasticity of 1.2052 implies a 1 percent change in the level of resource endowment differences will raise imports by about 1.2 percent or $14.4 million.

Results and Discussions Similarly, the larger the ratio of a CBI economy relative to that of U.S., the larger the volume of exports. The elasticity of 3.4885 indicates that a percent increase in the GDP ratio raises a CBI country s exports of textiles and apparel to the U.S. by about 3.5 percent or $42 million. These results are consistent with the primary goal of the U.S. trade policy for the Caribbean Basin. The real exchange rate of a CBI currency relative to the dollar is statistically significant and shows the expected negative sign. Thus, as a CBI currency depreciates the volume of textiles and apparel exported to U.S. increases. The elasticity of the exchange rate is -0.9026. This shows that 1 percent appreciation of the U.S. dollar raises the value of textile and apparel imports into the U.S. by 0.9 percent or $10.8 million.

Results and Discussions Exchange rate is one of the most important factors affecting trade flows - Koo, Kamera, and Taylor (1994). If the real exchange rate rises, future trade appears relatively more profitable to exporters, so export supplies will vary directly with change in the exchange rate - Daly (1998). By contrast, the sum of the bilateral trade GDP is negative but statistically significant. The income of exporting countries represents the country s production capacity, and the income of importing countries represents the country s purchasing power, both of which are positively related to trade flows. A higher level of income in the exporting country indicates a high level of production of which increases the availability of products for export, while a high level of income in the importing country suggests higher imports.

Conclusion Economic theory shows that at individual country level, border relaxation reduces domestic prices and increases the profit for low-cost exporters through increased sales in the foreign market. At the global level, free trade causes demand and supply to expand, both of which improve price signals and improves world welfare. Furthermore, economic theory reveals that there are many other socioeconomic and political-institutional determinants of cross-border trade, including market size, resource endowments, geographical proximity, tastes and preferences, cultural ties, and financial linkages. This paper used the two-way fixed effect panel estimation to determine the influence of the various factors driving the volume of U.S. imports of textile and apparel from the CBI countries.

Conclusion One noteworthy finding is that the relative factor endowment differences matter. The per capita difference between the importer and exporter was positive and statistically significant. By contrast, the exchange rate relative to the U.S. dollar is negative. Thus, a stronger dollar expands imports of textile and apparel, which in turn causes an expansion of the operations in the exporting countries to be able to export more for development. This result is consistent with primary goal of the U.S. trade policy for the Caribbean Basin. The purpose of which is to stimulate the exports of these countries to promote economic growth and development. Another important finding was that the relative GDP of CBI country to that of U.S was shown to have had an appreciable effect on exports. By contrast, the bilateral trade GDP was negative but significant.