Evaluating Fiscal Policy with a Dynamic Simulation Model

Similar documents
Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Volume Title: Generational Accounting around the World. Volume Author/Editor: Alan J. Auerbach, Laurence J. Kotlikoff and Willi Leibfritz, editors

13 National Savings, Economic Welfare, and the Structure of Taxation

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Dynamic Macroeconomics

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

DYNAMIC TAX MODELS: WHY THEY DO THE THINGS THEY DO ERIC ENGEN,

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE MARGINAL EXCESS BURDEN OF DIFFERENT CAPITAL TAX INSTRUMENTS. Don Fullerton. Yolanda K. Henderson. Working Paper No.

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Comment. Jonathan A. Parker Princeton University and NBER. 1. Introduction

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Table of Contents. 1. Introduction

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT AS ORDERED REPORTED BY THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ON NOVEMBER 16, 2017

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Toshihiro Ihori. Principles of Public. Finance. Springer

Application: The Costs of Taxation

Department of Economics Course Outline

How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement?

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples

Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States

Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States

LECTURE 3 NEO-CLASSICAL AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight

LECTURE 3 NEO-CLASSICAL AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RULES AND THE MISMANAGEMENT OF MONETARY FLICY. Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. 122

Module 10. Lecture 37

Optimal Progressivity

14.41 Fall 2004 Mock Final Solutions T/F/U

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Department of Economics Course Outline

Public Good Provision Rules and Income Distribution: Some General Equilibrium Calculations

Tax Incentives for Household Saving and Borrowing

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

COMMENTS ON SESSION I: TAXATION AND THE LABOUR MARKET. Lucio R. Pench *

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

Factors that Affect Fiscal Externalities in an Economic Union

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

CURRICULUM VITAE John P. Laitner 12/31/17

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

Monetary Policy, Capital Flows, and Exchange Rates. Part 2: Capital Flows and Crises

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Ricardian Equivalence: Further Evidence

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

Annex: Alternative approaches to corporate taxation Ec426 Lecture 8 Taxation and companies 1

EC 762 Applied Public Finance

The Development and Use of Models for Fiscal Policy Analysis. Alan Auerbach September 23, 2016

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

ECO209 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Chapter 14

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Accrual vs Realization in Capital Gains Taxation

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

The Japanese Saving Rate

Public Finance: The Economics of Taxation. The Economics of Taxation. Taxes: Basic Concepts

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Evaluating Lump Sum Incentives for Delayed Social Security Claiming*

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

Endogenous labour supply, endogenous lifetime and economic growth: local and global indeterminacy

POLICY BRIEF: THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS

Mankiw, N. Gregory (2000) The Savers Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy, American Economic Review 90(2):

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

Social Security in an Overlapping Generations Economy with Land*

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Money, Output, and the Nominal National Debt. Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman (AER 1990)

Structural Reform of Social Security

Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

Prefunding Medicare. The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Transcription:

Evaluating Fiscal Policy with a Dynamic Simulation Model By ALAN J. AUERBACH AND LAURENCE J. KOTLIKOFF * Those schooled in the shifting curves of static and steady-state macro models may not fully appreciate the dynamic nature of fiscal policy. Simple blackboard models can convey neither the timing nor the magnitude of responses to short- and intermediate-term fiscal policies, nor can they isolate the impact of fiscal policies on transitional generations. There is also a range of issues, such as deficit finance and the relative efficiency of alternative tax structures, that cannot be properly addressed without solving for the economy's transition path. Recent experience has provided several experiments in dynamic fiscal policy, including the accumulation of large amounts of official government debt, expected future changes in the level of social security benefits, shifts in the tax structure, and increases and then reductions in investment incentives. Each of these policies has important transitional as well as long-term effects. The analysis of these effects is possible using a dynamic general equilibrium numerical simulation model. I. A Dynamic Simulation Model In a series of our papers (1983a,b,c,d; 1985a, b; and our paper with Jonathan Skinner, 1983), and in a book (1987), we have developed such a dynamic general equilibrium numerical simulation model. We have used the model to study a range of fiscal policies, including deficit finance, changes in the tax structure, changes in the degree of tax progressivity, increases in investment incentives, and Social Security reform. We have also used the model to study the incidence and efficiency of alternative fiscal policies * University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104, and Boston University and NBER, 1050 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA 02138, respectively. and to study the impact of demographics on saving and economic growth. Like other numerical simulation models, this model provides an alternative to comparative statics analysis. The practice of signing derivatives is replaced here with simulations of policy changes and sensitivity analysis of how policy changes depend on taste and technology parameters. The results obtained with such a model are no less general than those obtained using comparative statics. Simulation models have the additional advantage of applying to large changes in tax policy instead of the infinitesimal changes for which the derivatives of comparative statics are valid. This ability to study large changes is very important in the analysis of economic efficiency; one of the most basic results in public finance is that the deadweight loss of a tax rises in proportion not to the tax rate itself, but to its square. Such nonlinearities may be especially important when one is considering the simultaneous application of several policies. II. The Model The simulation model is described in detail in our book. However, a broad outline of its characteristics and the method of solution will provide a basis for interpreting the results presented below. The model is composed of households, firms, and the government. Households live for 55 periods (age 20 to 75). They are assumed to have rational expectations and to maximize a CES lifetime utility function of consumption and leisure subject to the budget constraint that the present value of consumption not exceed the present value of after-tax labor income plus transfers. There are also nonnegativity constraints on the labor supply of each individual in each cohort at each age. When the shadow wages associated with these constraints are positive, the individual is retired. 49

50 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1987 Our CES utility function has constant intertemporal elasticities of substitution, y and p, respectively. It also has a time preference rate 8, and a leisure share parameter, a. Based on empirical evidence about these parameters, we set a = 1.5, 8 =.015, p =.8 and y =.25. In all simulations reported here, a 1 percent annual population growth rate is also assumed. The budget constraint depends not only on the interest rate r and the wage profile w, (our cross-section age-wage profile is based on estimate of Finis Welch, 1979), but also on the average tax rates on capital income, labor income, and consumption, the payroll tax used to finance Social Security, and the level of Social Security benefits. In cases when the tax system is progressive, the average tax rates vary with the size of the tax base. This dependence is considered in the optimization decision, with both marginal and average tax rates affecting the household's choices. The model has a single output, produced by identical firms that are assumed to behave competitively and to have a CES production function in labor and capital. The production function is normalized so that the wage in the base case is 1.0. In the base case, we use a Cobb-Douglas production function with capital's income share equal to.25. Labor is assumed to be a variable factor of production, leading firms to set the marginal product of labor equal to the gross wage. Capital is assumed not to depreciate, and changes in the capital stock are subject to quadratic adjustment costs. This convex cost of adjustment leads to the smoothing of investment, so that outside of the steady state, the marginal product of capital will not necessarily equal the interest rate, and the value to the firm of an additional unit of capital may diverge from its replacement cost. The ratio of this market value to the replacement cost of capital is Tobin's "q" ratio (Fumio Hayashi, 1982). There are actually two sources of variation of the value of the firm per unit of capital: changes in the value of marginal q associated with the costs of adjusting to new investment and changes in the relative val- uation of old and new capital due to changes in the tax-based distinction between new and existing capital goods. For example, such a distinction arises when new capital receives investment incentives, such as the investment tax credit, for which existing assets do not qualify. Both adjustment costs and tax distinctions between new and old capital can produce significant changes in stock market values of capital. The government in this model has a main fiscal authority that raises taxes to pay for government spending on goods and services and a separate social security system which, like the actual U.S. Social Security system, is unfunded. The government's budget constraint is that the present value of taxes equals the present value of government spending plus the initial stock of debt. III. The Model's Solution The calculation of the equilibrium path of the economy given a particular parameterization typically proceeds in three stages: 1) solving for the long-run steady state of the economy before the assumed change in fiscal policy begins, 2) solving for the long-run steady state to which the economy eventually converges after the policy takes effect, and 3) solving for the transition path the economy takes between these two steady states. The perfect foresight assumption is critical only in this third state, since any model of expectations formation would predict correct expectations in a steady state. The solution method is one of iterating to find a fixed point. After solutions for the initial and final steady states of the economy are found, the economy's transition path is calculated by 1) providing the economy with 150 years to reach the new steady state (many more years than it actually takes for the model to reach a position indistinguishably close to the final steady state), and 2) solving for behavior during those 150 transition years fixing expectations for years after 150 at the final steady-state values that will, in fact, obtain. Variations in initial guesses and the number of years permitted for the transition to take

VOL. 77 NO. 2 DYNAMIC MODELS OF TAXATION 51 place have never produced changes in the solutions obtained.' IV. Simulation Results Some selected simulations provide an indication of the surprising aspects of fiscal policy not evident from earlier static analyses. We focus on three issues that have been of particular interest to economists in recent years: the choice of tax base, the impact of investment incentives, and the effects of budget deficits. A. Income vs. Consumption Taxes Since the careful studies produced by the U.S. Treasury (1977) in the United States and the Meade Committee (Institute for Fiscal Studies, 1978) in the United Kingdom, and the influential papers by Martin Feldstein (1978) and Michael Boskin (1978), economists have wondered whether reducing or removing capital income taxation's discrimination against future consumption would increase economic efficiency. Since time invariant proportional taxation of consumption does not affect the rate of return available to saving, the discussion has often focused on switching from the income tax to 'Previous analyses of uniqueness with overlapping generations models (for example, Guillermo Calvo, 1978, and Timothy Kehoe and David Levine, 1985) have provided examples in which there is a continuum of transition paths to the new equilibrium. The nonuniqueness problem arises if there are more stable roots to the linearized version of the system in the neighborhood of the final steady-state equilibrium than initial conditions. The requirement of convergence eliminates only the unstable roots, leaving, in some cases, a continuum of feasible paths that satisfy the initial conditions. While we have not explicitly calculated the roots of a linearized version of our model, such analysis has been conducted for a similar model by John Laitner (1984). He found the transition path to be determinate, with the number of stable roots equal to the number of initial conditions. His results, together with our own findings that, in practice the solution calculated by our model does not depend on the initial guesses chosen for the transition path, strongly suggest to us that indeterminacv is not a problem. a personal consumption tax rather than simply removing capital income from the tax base (see, generally, Joseph Pechman, 1980). The basic efficiency argument is that the increased labor supply distortion of such a switch would be more than offset by the reduced saving distortion. As is well-known, this is a question of "second-best" economics to which there is no simple general answer, but the academic literature including papers mentioned above and, in particular, one by Lawrence Summers (1981), argued passionately that the efficiency gains from reducing capital income taxation would be quite large because of the relatively high elasticity of savings with respect to the interest rate. Static efficiency calculations ignore what is probably the most important issue in the switch from income to consumption taxation: the intergenerational redistribution of the tax burden. Since consumption tends to occur later in life than income, a switch to consumption taxation shifts each year's tax burden toward the elderly. The result is that the current elderly population pays more, while subsequent generations pay less by having their tax payments deferred to older age. This provides a substantial increase in the long-run utility of generations in the eventual steady state, equivalent, in our model, to a permanent increase in consumption and leisure of about 6 percent assuming an initial income tax rate of 30 percent. Removing capital income taxation directly from the proportional income tax base, that is, switching to a wage tax, while equivalent in a static model to adopting a proportional consumption tax, has quite different results in a dynamic model, since there is an opposite tax windfall. The existing elderly population gains from the shift in tax burden to wages, which occur earlier in life on average than income. This makes them better off, but makes all subsequent generations worse off; in the eventual wage-tax steady state welfare is reduced by over 4 percent of lifetime consumption and leisure. The very different intergenerational transfer effects of these two "equivalent" tax policies are shown in Figure 1.

52 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1987 LOG 1.06 _ 1.04 COKSUMPTION TAX 1.02 - F 98 wc.9b a WE\ WA TAX.96 _ I9 I I 1 I 1 -so -40-20 0 20 40 60 YEAR OF TRANSITION FIGURE 1. WEALTH EQUIVALENTS Thus a dynamic analysis shows that the long-run impacts of switching to consumption vs. wage taxation are quite different. So too are the efficiency impacts of the switches to consumption and wage taxation. By taxing the consumption financed by preexisting wealth, the consumption tax base equals the initial stock of wealth plus the present value of all future wages, rather than just the latter as under a wage tax (Christophe Chamley, 1983). This tax on initial wealth arising under the consumption tax is a lump sum tax and explains why the consumption tax is more efficient than the wage tax. To analyze the efficiency gains of switching tax bases our model includes a Lump Sum Redistribution Authority (LSRA) that transfers resources across generations in a lump sum fashion. In our efficiency transition calculations, the LSRA maintains the preexisting utility levels of generations initially alive at the time of the tax change, and any efficiency gains (losses) are allocated across subsequent generations in such a way that all subsequent generations enjoy a uniform increase (decrease) in utility. In these LSRA transitions, we found that switching from the 30 percent income tax to the equal revenue consumption tax permits an increase in utility for all subsequent generations which is equivalent in the initial steady state to a permanent increase in lifetime consumption and leisure of 1.7 percent, while abolition of capital income taxes, that is, switching to wage taxation, induces a decline of 2.3 percent. Hence, perhaps 60 percent of the difference between the non-lsra changes in long-run welfare under labor income taxation and consumption taxation is attributable to intergenerational transfers. It should be emphasized that certain policies that appear to resemble the consumption tax, such as expanding the limits on contributions to individual retirement accounts, do not offer the efficiency gains of consumption taxation because they share with the repeal of capital income taxes the crucial feature of exempting from taxation the consumption of existing wealth. The presence of progressivity reinforces these findings for two general reasons. First, since distortions are worse with higher marginal tax rates, any efficiency gains associated with a reduction in distortions will be magnified. Second, the fact that average as well as marginal tax rates under progressive taxation rise with the tax base reinforces the shift in the tax burden and its associated distortions to the elderly under a consumption tax and toward the working population under a labor income tax. Hence, the distinction between these two "equivalent" tax bases is even greater than indicated by the proportional tax simulations. B. Investment Incentives The increase in accelerated depreciation allowances under the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 was viewed by many as a windfall to corporations and the owners of corporate shares. More careful analysis suggests the opposite, and this is confirmed by our simulation results. First, consider the theoretical impact of investment incentives. The introduction or enhancement of investment incentives not only encourages investment, it also lowers the present value of taxes on new investment, while leaving unchanged the present value of taxes on old capital. Because old capital is at a tax disadvantage, its market value must fall. In the case of an investment tax credit, for example, the effect will be to drive the value of old capital down to the cost of new capital net of the investment tax credit, for which only new capital qualifies. The short-run impact of adjustment costs, on the other hand,

VOL. 77 NO. 2 DYNAMIC MODELS OF TAXATION 53 will be to mitigate this fall in the stock market value of old capital; with adjustment costs, old capital earns rents on the installation of new capital. A drop in the value of capital, combined with a cut in the tax burden on new investment, is good for savings but bad for old people, just like a consumption tax. In fact, investment incentives in the presence of an income tax are not only just like consumption taxes; they are consumption taxes. This equivalence is most easily seen for the ultimate acceleration of depreciation allowances, immediate expensing, though it is just as true in other cases. Under expensing, the firm pays taxes on income net of new investment, just as an individual would under a consumption tax, since income net of saving equals consumption. And, as under a consumption tax, all income net of saving is taxed, even though some of it may be income earned on preexisting assets. The only difference is that in this case the tax is collected at the firm level and capitalized into the value of existing capital goods, rather than paid by the individual upon consumption. It thus represents a firm-level rather than an individual-level consumption tax. Given this equivalence, it is somewhat surprising that a policy that in one form is seen as so unfair to the owners of capital is seen when presented in a different form as so unfair to everyone else. The fact that adjustment costs may offset the windfall loss to existing capital caused by the introduction of investment incentives does not change the equivalence. It would be present as an absolute increase in the value of assets under the direct consumption tax. Our simulations suggest that the windfalls associated with a move to investment expensing may be quite large. For an adjustment cost parameter of b =10 (on the low end of empirical estimates, but by no means small), we find that a move from a 15 percent income tax to the same tax with complete expensing (i.e., a consumption tax) reduces the value of the existing capital stock by nearly two-thirds the size of the tax rate cut on new investment, or about 9.5 percent. There are other results that may appear surprising but become less so when the equivalence of investment incentives and consumption taxes is remembered. For example, it is quite possible for an increase in investment incentives to raise revenue without the economy being on the wrong side of the Laffer curve. In our paper (1983b), we present a simulation in which investment incentives are introduced and financed, in the short run, by issuing debt. In the simulation the income tax rate is held constant at 30 percent for a period of 20 years. During this time the increase in the tax base associated with the investment incentives leads to an increase in revenue which is sufficient to retire the government debt issued at the beginning of the transition. After year 20, the income tax rate must be reduced to prevent accumulating an infinite surplus. Thus, the crowding in from switching towards a consumption tax base exceeds the crowding out from the short-run deficits. While the investment incentives are cuts in business taxes, not everyone in the model experiences a tax cut, and the distributional effects of the shift in the tax burden lead to the observed outcome. C. Deficits, Crowding Out, and Crowding In As recent experience suggests, most students of fiscal policies appear to believe that deficits arising from tax cuts will be associated with short- and long-run crowding out of capital and short- and long-run increases in interest rates. While our simulation studies of deficit policies confirm these long-run predictions, we find that, except for tax cuts of very long duration, deficits arising from tax cuts will be associated with short-run crowding in of capital and short-run declines in interest rates. The simple explanation is that tax cuts have substitution as well as income effects. In the short run, individuals take advantage of the temporarily low tax rate on wages and the return to capital by working and saving more. One response to this line of argument is that substitution elasticities are potentially small. While this may be true, our model assumes fairly small substitution elasticities. What is not, however, typically understood is that although substitution elasticities are small, the change

54 A EA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1987 TABLE 1-ECONOMIC IMPACT OF DEFICIT FINANCING S/Y W r L K Crowding Out under Alternative Deficit Policies Initial Steady State 0.037 1.000 0.067 19.10 95.1 1-Year Income Tax Reduction Year: 1 0.049 0.991 0.069 19.80 95.1 2 0.034 1.002 0.067 19.04 95.4 3 0.034 1.001 0.067 19.04 95.3 4 0.035 1.001 0.067 19.04 95.3 5 0.035 1.001 0.067 19.04 95.3 10 0.036 1.000 0.067 19.05 94.9 30 0.037a 0.998 0.067 19.07 94.2 60 0.037a 0.997 0.068 19.08 93.9 90 0.037a 0.997 0.068 19.08 93.9 Final Steady State 0.037a 0.997 0.068 19.08 93.9 5-Year Income Tax Reduction Year: 1 0.046 0.992 0.069 19.76 95.1 2 0.045 0.992 0.068 19.74 95.3 3 0.044 0.993 0.068 19.73 95.6 4 0.043 0.994 0.068 19.71 95.8 5 0.026 1.006 0.066 18.83 95.9 10 0.028 1.002 0.067 18.87 94.6 30 0.032 0.992 0.069 18.96 91.3 60 0.036 0.987 0.070 19.02 89.9 90 0.036 0.987 0.070 19.02 89.7 Final Steady State 0.036 0.987 0.070 19.02 89.7 20-Year Income Tax Reduction Yeair: 1 0.034 0.994 0.068 19.58 95.1 2 0.033 0.994 0.068 19.56 95.0 3 0.031 0.994 0.068 19.55 94.9 4 0.030 0.994 0.068 19.53 94.8 5 0.029 0.993 0.068 19.51 94.6 10 0.023 0.991 0.068 19.45 93.3 30-0.014 0.964 0.075 17.72 76.1 60 0.011 0.888 0.096 18.08 56.0 90 0.020 0.867 0.103 18.11 50.8 Final Steady State 0.023 0.856 0.107 18.13 48.5 Note: S= net national saving; Y =net national product; W = wage rate; r = interest rate; L = aggregate labor supply; K = capital stock. a This saving rate is below that in the initial steady state to the fourth decimal. in tax rates may be substantial and, therefore, have a substantial impact on relative prices of consumption vs. leisure, and consumption today vs. consumption tomorrow. Table I reports the simulation results of 33 percent cuts in the income tax rate lasting 1 year, 5 years, and 20 years. The table gives the saving rate, S/Y, the income tax rate, W, the pretax interest rate r, the level of labor supply, L, and the stock of capital, K. Note that in the 1- and 15-year tax cuts the saving rate is larger in year 1 and in years 1 to 14, respectively, than in the initial steady state; hence, crowding in occurs under these short-term tax cut policies until the tax rate is increased. After the tax rate is increased crowding out proceeds, but fairly slowly. The example of short-run crowding in arising from short-run tax cuts demonstrates that a policy that is ultimately detrimental to capital formation can appear, in the short run, to be increasing savings. Thus there is the potential to misread policy by focusing too strongly on the short-run impacts. V. Conclusion Dynamic simulation models can resolve a number of important issues that cannot be adequately considered in static or steadystate analyses. The results from dynamic analyses can be quite surprising. We, at least, were surprised to learn that deficits are most likely to cause short-run crowding in and lower short-term interest rates, that investment incentives are detrimental to capitalists, that business tax cuts may be self-financing, that the degree of tax progressivity is as important as the choice of tax base for issues of savings and efficiency, that official government debt is a highly unreliable measure of the government's true economic debt policy, and that while baby "busts" like those underway in the United States are bad for social security, they are, on net, likely to be beneficial to the economy. REFERENCES Auerbach, Alan J. and Kotlikoff, Laurence J., (1983a) "National Savings, Economic Welfare, and the Structure of Taxation," in Martin Feldstein, ed., Behavioral Simulation Methods in Tax Policy Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983. and, (1983b) "Investment Versus Savings Incentives: The Size of the Bang for the Buck and the Potential for Self-Financing Business Tax Cuts," in L. H. Meyer, ed., The Economic Conse-

VOL. 77 NO. 2 D YNA MIC MODELS OF TA XA TION 55 quences of Government Deficits, Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff, 1983. and, (1983c) "Social Security and the Economics of the Demographic Transition," in H. Aaron and G. Burtless, eds., Retirement and Economic Behavior, Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1983. and, (1983d) "An Examination of Empirical Tests of Social Security and Savings," in Elhanan Helpman et al., eds., Social Policy Evaluation: An Economic Perspective, New York: Academic Press, 1983. and, (1985a) "Simulating Alternative Social Security Responses to the Demographic Transition," National Tax Journal, June 1985, 38, 153-68. and, (1985b) "The Efficiency Gains from Social Security Benefit-Tax Linkage," NBER Working Paper No. 1645, June 1985. and, Dynamic Fiscal Policy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987. _, and Skinner, Jonathan, "The Efficiency Gains from Dynamic Tax Reform," International Economic Review, February 1983, 24, 81-100. Boskin, Michael J., "Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of Interest," Journal of Political Economy, April 1978, 86, S3-27. Calvo, Guillermo, "On the Indeterminacy of Interest Rates and Wages with Perfect Foresight," Journal of Economic Theory, December 1978, 19, 32-37. Chamley, Christophe, "Efficient Tax Reform in a Dynamic Model of General Equilibrium," mimeo., World Bank, 1983. Feldstein, Martin, "The Welfare Cost of Capital Income Taxation," Journal of Political Economy, April 1978, 86, S29-51. Hayashi, Fumio, "Tobin's Marginal and Average q: A Neoclassical Interpretation," Econometrica, January 1982, 50, 213-24. Kehoe, Timothy J. and Levine, David, "Comparative Statics and Perfect Foresight in Infinite Horizon Economies," Econometrica, March 1985, 53, 433-53. Laitner, John, "Transition Time Paths for Overlapping-Generations Models," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, May 1984, 7. Pechman, Joseph A., What Should Be Taxed: Income or Expenditure?, Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1980. Summers, Lawrence H., "Capital Taxation and Accumulation in a Life Cycle Growth Model," American Economic Review, September 1981, 71, 533-44. Welch, Finis, " Effects of Cohort Size on Earnings: The Baby Boom Babies' Financial Bust," Journal of Political Economy, October 1979, 87, S65-97. Institute for Fiscal Studies, The Structure and Reform of Direct Taxation, Report of a Committee Chaired by Professor J. E Meade, London: Allen and Unwin, 1978. U.S. Treasury, Blueprints for Basic Tax Reform, Washington: USGPO, 1977.