Reference Dependence Lecture 3

Similar documents
Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Dynamic Principal Agent Models: A Continuous Time Approach Lecture II

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Online Appendix for The E ect of Diversi cation on Price Informativeness and Governance

Advanced Microeconomics

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Monopoly Pricing when Consumers are Antagonized by Unexpected Price Increases: A Cover Version of the Heidhues-Koszegi-Rabin Model

The role of asymmetric information

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Organizing the Global Value Chain: Online Appendix

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012)

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2011

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems

Lecture 10: Market Experiments and Competition between Trading Institutions

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

A Multitask Model without Any Externalities

Exercises - Moral hazard

Reference Dependence Lecture 1

E ciency Gains and Structural Remedies in Merger Control (Journal of Industrial Economics, December 2010)

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Lecture 6 Applications of Static Games of Incomplete Information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements

1. Monetary credibility problems. 2. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 3. Reputational solution to credibility problems

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version

Winners and Losers from Price-Level Volatility: Money Taxation and Information Frictions

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts

Optimal Progressivity

Endogenous Protection: Lobbying

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Experiments on Auctions

Cheap Talk Games with three types

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Principles of Optimal Taxation

Auction Theory - An Introduction

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

1 Unemployment Insurance

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Subsidization to Induce Tipping

Simple e ciency-wage model

Auction Theory for Undergrads

Security Design Under Routine Auditing

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Auctions with Resale and Bargaining Power

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Robustness of a Fixed-Rent Contract in a Standard Agency Model

Quantity Competition vs. Price Competition under Optimal Subsidy in a Mixed Duopoly. Marcella Scrimitore. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2012

Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks

E cient Minimum Wages

An Allegory of the Political Influence of the Top 1%

The Political Economy of Carbon Securities and Environmental Policy

Exclusive Contracts, Innovation, and Welfare

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Backward Integration and Collusion in a Duopoly Model with Asymmetric Costs

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

A New Regulatory Tool

Contagious Adverse Selection

Size and Focus of a Venture Capitalist s Portfolio

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BUYER INVESTMENT, PRODUCT VARIETY, AND INTRAFIRM TRADE. Yongmin Chen Robert C. Feenstra

Bargaining, Competition and E cient Investment

Arrow s theorem of the deductible: moral hazard and stop-loss in health insurance

The speed of technological adoption under price competition: two-tier vs. one-tier industries y

Rationalizing Time Inconsistent Behavior: The Case of Late Payments

Game Theory Solutions to Problem Set 11

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions

1 Two Period Production Economy

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Hold-up and the Evolution of Investment and Bargaining Norms

Long Term E cient Contracting with Private Information

A Systematic Presentation of Equilibrium Bidding Strategies to Undergradudate Students

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

No Trade. Abstract. Keywords: bilateral bargaining, common values, private information, no trade theorem, laboratory experiment.

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

EconS Games with Incomplete Information II and Auction Theory

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Liquidity and Spending Dynamics

Coordinating Monetary and Financial Regulatory Policies

Relational delegation

Transcription:

Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Mark Dean Princeton University - Behavioral Economics

The Story So Far De ned reference dependent behavior and given examples Change in risk attitudes Endowment e ect Status quo bias Discussed two models of reference dependent choice Prospect Theory Koszergi-Rabin [2006,2007] Latter introduced Stochastic reference points Personal equilibrium

Plan for Today Two applications Application: Pricing Heidues and Köszegi [2008] Speigler [2011] Contracting Hart and Moore [2008]

Two Pricing Puzzles Prices are unresponsive to changes in costs ( price stickiness ) Firms charge prices that are too similar across di erentiated products with di erent costs ( focal pricing )

Two Pricing Puzzles Existing theories (Rational Inattention, Menu Costs) can explain the former, but have trouble with the latter Aim Show loss aversion can explain the former May also be able to explain the latter Intuition: Consumers form expectations over prices that will be charged Loss aversion means that marginal disutility of price rises is high......while marginal bene t of price falls is not so high Causes kink in rm s demand function around expected price Makes prices unresponsive

Two Pricing Puzzles Two papers formalize this intuition Heidues and Köszegi [2008] (henceforth HK) Speigler [2011] (henceforth S) Speigler is a cover version But it is also simpler Will go through this model in detail Discuss Heidues and Koszegi afterwards

Modelling Choices - Consumer Side Over what are consumers loss averse? Does consumers expected action a ect reference point? How to deal with stochastic reference points?

Modelling Choices - Consumer Side Over what are consumers loss averse? HK: Money and consumption quality S: Money only Does consumers expected action a ect reference point? How to deal with stochastic reference points?

Modelling Choices - Consumer Side Over what are consumers loss averse? Does consumers expected action a ect reference point? HK: Yes: personal equilibrium S: No: reference point is what consumers to expect rms to charge How to deal with stochastic reference points?

Modelling Choices - Consumer Side Over what are consumers loss averse? Does consumers expected action a ect reference point? How to deal with stochastic reference points? HK: Evaluate action at each reference point in support, calculate expectation S: Consumer draws reference point from distribution and evaluates action

Modelling Choices - Supply Side HK: Salop style monopolistic competition Firm s type located equidistantly on a ring Consumer type drawn from a distribution. Value of product to consumer is distance between consumer and rm type S: monopolist Both models give price stickiness Result robust to these assumption S annot talk about focal pricing

Set Up - Firm Monopolistic rm, single good, measure 1 of consumers Marginal cost of rm c distributed uniformly over m possible values C 1 > c h > c l > 0 respectively highest and lowest prices in C Pricing strategy P : C! R Induces measure µ p over prices µ p (x) = jc 2 C jp(c) = xj m

Set Up - Consumer Consumer rst draws a reference price p e from distribution µ p Draws valuation of good u from U[0, 1] Buys product i where Consumer identi ed by 1 Valuation u 2 Reference price p e p u L(p, p e ) L(p, p e ) = maxf0, λ(p p e )g λ 0

Optimization Problem - Firm For any given price, consumer will buy if p + L(p, p e ) u With uniform distribution, this is probability 1 p L(p, p e ) For pricing strategy P, there is a 1 probability that prices will m 2 be P(c) and expectations will be P(c e ) for each c, c e 2 C Summing across all this states gives the valuation of a pricing strategy as Π(p) = 1 m 2 c2c [P(c) c] maxf0, 1 P(c) L(P(c), P(c e )) c e 2C

A Note on Timing Firm is assumed to announce strategy ex ante Not a simultaneous move game When we consider deviations in rm s strategy, we assume beliefs of agents adjust as well Unexpected price hike means relative to beliefs correctly conditioning on strategy, not due to change in strategy

Benchmark - No Loss Aversion Π(p) = 1 m 2 c2c [P(c) c] maxf0, 1 P(c) L(P(c), P(c e )) c e 2C Without loss aversion, expectations do not matter Π(p) = 1 m 2 For each c, FOC [P(c) c] maxf0, 1 P(c)g c2c 1 + c 2P(c) = 0 1 + c 2 = P 0 (c)

Characterizing Optimal Strategy Lemma Let P be an optimal pricing strategy. Then for every c 2 C, P(c) < 1 and consumer demand is strictly positive Proof: Assume P(c ) 1 for some c 2 C, then consumer demand is zero at P(c ) Consider P 0 which changes P only by setting P(c ) = 1 ε Consumer demand is now strictly positive in this state, as 1 P 0 (c ) L(P 0 (c ), P 0 (c )) = 1 P 0 (c ) = ε > 0 Pro t also strictly positive assuming ε st ε < 1 c

Characterizing Optimal Strategy Proof (cont) For all other c 2 C, consumer demand is unchanged Consider pair c c e. If c e 6= c this is clearly true If c e = c and P(c) = P 0 (c) 1 then demand is zero If c e = c and P(c) = P 0 (c) < 1 then for ε small enough Deviation is therefore pro table L(P(c), P(c e )) = L(P 0 (c), P 0 (c e ) = 0

Characterizing Optimal Strategy Lemma For every optimal pricing strategy, P(c) is increasing in c and P(c) c for all c Proof ( rst statement) Assume there is an optimal strategy such that c 1 > c 2 but P(c 2 ) > P(c 1 ) Consider the strategy P 0 that switches round the prices of c 2 and c 1 µ P is the same as µ P 0 Demand only changes with price Change in pro t therefore given by (P(c 2 ) c 1 ) D(P(c 2 )) (P(c 1 ) c 1 ) D(P(c 1 )) + (P(c 1 ) c 2 ) D(P(c 1 )) (P(c 2 ) c 2 ) D(P(c 2 )) = (c 2 c 1 )(D(P(c 2 )) D(P(c 1 ))) > 0 P(c 2 ) > P(c 1 ) and so D(P(c 2 ) < D(P(c 1 )) (strictly by lemma 1)

Two Results Loss aversion reduces price volatility Loss aversion induces price stickiness

Result 1: Loss Aversion Reduces Price Volatility Theorem Let P be the optimal pricing strategy, and P 0 be the optimal pricing strategy without loss aversion, then P 0 (c l ) p(c l ) P(c h ) P 0 (c h ) Proof (P 0 (c l ) P(c l )) We know that P 0 (c l ) = 1 2 (1 + cl ) Assume p(c l ) < 1 2 (1 + cl ) De ne c 0 to be the highest cost c such that P(c) < 1 2 (1 + cl ) Implies P(c) < 1 2 (1 + cl ) for all c c 0 (by lemma 2)

Result 1: Loss Aversion Reduces Price Volatility Theorem Let P be the optimal pricing strategy, and P 0 be the optimal pricing strategy without loss aversion, then P 0 (c l ) p(c l ) P(c h ) P 0 (c h ) Proof (P 0 (c l ) P(c l )): Cont Consider deviation that sets P(c) = 1 2 (1 + cl ) for all c < c 0 Would improve pro t if no loss aversion, as moves closer to optimal price Four cases to consider loss aversion L(P 0 (c 1 ), P 0 (c 2 )) c 1, c 2 c 0 : L(P 0 (c 1 ), P 0 (c 2 )) = 0 as P 0 (c 1 ) = P 0 (c 2 ) c 2 c 0 c 1 : L(P 0 (c 1 ), P 0 (c 2 )) L(P(c 1 ), P(c 2 )) as P(c 1 ) = P 0 (c 1 ) and P(c 2 ) P 0 (c 2 ) c 0 c 1, c 2 : L(P 0 (c 1 ), P 0 (c 2 )) = L(P(c 1 ), P(c 2 )) as P(c 1 ) = P 0 (c 1 ) and P(c 2 ) = P 0 (c 2 ) c 1 c 0 c 2 : L(P 0 (c 1 ), P 0 (c 2 )) = 0 as P 0 (c 2 ) P 0 (c 1 )

Result 2: Price Stickiness Theorem Let C = fc, c + 2εg. When ε > 0 is su ciently small, the optimal pricing strategy is to charge constant price p = 1 2 (1 + c + e) Proof: First consider the case in which demand is zero when reference price is p l and actual price is p h. Pro ts equal 1 2 (p l c)(1 p l ) + 1 2 (p h c 2ε) 1 2 (1 p h) if ε < 3 4 we can show that this is lower than the payo of p for any p l,p h

Result 2: Price Stickiness Theorem Let C = fc, c + 2εg. When ε > 0 is su ciently small, the optimal pricing strategy is to charge constant price p = 1 2 (1 + c + e) Proof: (Cont); Now assume that demand is non-zero when reference price is p l and actual price is p h Pro t equals FOC 1 2 (p l c)(1 p l ) + 1 2 (p h c 2ε)(1 p h ) λ 2 (p h c 2ε)λ(p h p l ) 1 2 (1 + c 2p l ) + λ 2 (p h c 2ε) = 0 1 2 (1 + c + 2ε 2p λ h) 2 (p λ h c 2ε) 2 (p h p l ) = 0

Result 2: Price Stickiness Theorem Let C = fc, c + 2εg. When ε > 0 and c < 1 2 is su ciently small, the optimal pricing strategy is to charge constant price p = 1 2 (1 + c + ε) Proof: (Cont); Rearranging and using the fact that p h > p l gives λ(p h p l ) < 4ε 2λ(p h c 2ε) By theorem 1 we know p h > 1 2 (1 + c), thus we have λ(p h p l ) < 4ε 2λ( 1 2 1 2 c 2ε) Assuming c < 1 means that the RHS will be negative for ε small enough - contradiction

Heidues and Köszegi [2008] Embed a (similar) model in a monopolistic competition setting Firms product type is located on a ring ( xed) Consumers preferences located on a same ring (stochastic) Firms observe a cost and set prices

Heidues and Köszegi [2008] Consumers form stochastic reference point Distribution over prices paid and products bought based on Exogenous distribution over preferences Exogenous distribution over costs Pricing strategy of rm Own purchasing strategy Prices and preferences revealed, makes purchases to maximize utility given reference point

Heidues and Köszegi [2008] Strategies are an equilibrium if Purchasing strategy is a personal equilibrium for consumer given price distribution generated by rms Pricing strategy is optimal for rms given purchasing strategy of consumers and pricing strategies of other rms HK provide necessary and su cient conditions for Focal Equilibrium All rms charge the same price with probability 1 regardless of cost Intuition similar to S: If consumers expect to pay some price, a higher price is a loss Kink in the demand curve

Hart and Moore [2008] Contracts act as reference points Guide expectations about what parties feel they deserve Agents may underperform if they do not get what they expect Incomplete contracts may be ex-post ine cient Unlike standard contracting Sets up trade o between exibility and underperformance

Basic Structure Buyer and a Seller meet in a competitive market at date 0 Many buyers and sellers May be uncertainty about (e.g.) preferences and costs Write contract at this stage Only some things are contractible Perfunctary Performance - e.g. price of trade But not Consumate Performance - e.g. quality Uncertainty resolves Contract re ned (i.e. perfunctory performance determined) Level of consummate performance decided

Reference Dependent Preferences Agents prepared to o er consummate performance only if they are well treated Well treated or not relative to contract they signed If only one contracted outcome, both parties think they have been treated fairly If more than one possible outcome, both judge outcome relative to the contracted outcome that was best for them

Reference Dependent Preferences Utility Where U B = u B σ s max[θ(u B u B ) σ B, 0] U S = u S σ B max[θ(u s u s ) σ S, 0] u i is utility of i from contractual outcome (assuming full consummate performance) σ i is the shading (i.e. reduction of consummate performance) by i ui is maximal value of u i over contracted outcomes (ui u i ) aggrievement of agent i Assume that u i known when σ i chosen, so always the case that θa i = θ(u i u i ) = σ i U i = u i θa j

Shading What is shading? Reductions in e ort that cannot be contractually punished skimping on ingredients low e ort at work bad reviews No direct cost to shading/non shading positive cost of shading can be incorporated, negative cost less easily so Why not shade all the time? Seen as a model of costly punishment?

Comments Preferences are combination of other regarding and reference dependent Agents dislike losses relative to expectations Expectations determined by contract Losses can be assuaged by reducing the utility of other party Why are expectations the best possible outcome? Self serving bias? Consider alternative assumptions in the paper Why fairness concerns only in period 1 Period 0 had choice of other people to contract with Market environment At period 1 locked in to dealing with this partner Market environment itslef no longer salient, just contract

Example 1: No Uncertainty B requires 1 unit of a standard good B 0 s value is 100 S 0 s costs are zero Contract speci es whether or not good is traded and a price if trade does and does not take place What is the optimal contract?

Standard Model No price specifying contact necessary to achieve e ciency Assume that Nash Bargaining takes place at period 1 Trade takes place at price 50 Competitive equilibrium achieved at period 0 by lump some transfers e.g. if there are many buyers and 1 seller then a buyer would o er 50 to seller in order to go to stage 2 Total surplus is 100

Hart-Moore Model No contract is ine cient Assume no price is speci ed at stage 0 Assume that trade takes place at price p in stage 1 Best outcome of those possible for buyer was pb = 0 Best outcome of those possible for seller was ps = 100 θ(u b u b ) = θp = σ b θ(u s u s ) = θ(100 p) = σ s

Hart-Moore Model Ex post utility given by U B = (1 θ)(100 p) U S = (1 θ)p Total surplus is (1 θ)100 Similar e ect if a mechanism is agreed upon at time 0 e.g. single take it or leave it o er However, if a contract specifying a price is agreed upon at time 0 then surplus is still 100.

Example 2; Ex Ante Uncertainty B requires 1 unit of a standard good B 0 s value is v S 0 s costs are c v and c unknown at time 0 - drawn from distribution Assume that trade only takes place at time 1 if both parties want to

Simple Contracts p 0 no trade price p 1 trade price Trade occurs if Normalize p 0 to 0 v p 1 p 0 p 1 c 0 Compare to rst best trade rule q = 1, v p 1 p 0 c q = 1, v c So a gap between p 1 and p 0 reduces trade relative to rst best

Flexible contracts p 0 no trade price [p L, p H ] region for trade prices Trade occurs if Normalize p 0 to 0 q = 1, 9 p 2 [p L, p H ] v p p 0 c q = 1, v c v p L, c p H

Given voluntary trade, best price for seller is And best price for buyer is p S = min(v, p H ) p B = max(c, p L ) Aggreivement for buyer (assuming trade) is v max(c, p L ) (v p) Entitlements and Shading Aggrievement for seller min(v, p H ) Total aggrievement c (p c) min(v, p H ) max(c, p L )

Optimal Contract Given lump sum transfers, optimal contract maximizes total surplus Z h i v c θ min(v, p H ) max(c, p L ) df (v, c) subject to Clear trade o v x v p L c p H More exible contract: more trade...... but also more shading Simple contracts achieves rst best if v or c degenerate, or if they are separated

Example State 1 State 2 v 9 20 c 0 10 No simple contract will achieve rst best, as no single price can guarantee trade Contract that speci es trading region [9, 10] does achieve 1st best In state 1 In state 2 min(v, p H ) max(c, p L ) = 9 9 = 0 min(v, p H ) max(c, p L ) = 10 10 = 0