Midterm Exam No. 2 - Answers. July 30, 2003

Similar documents
Problem Set 4 - Answers. Specific Factors Models

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

Problem Set 7 - Answers. Topics in Trade Policy

Specific Factors Model (2/1/2012) Econ

Examiners commentaries 2011

~ In 20X7, a loaf of bread costs $1.50 and a flask of wine costs $6.00. A consumer with $120 buys 40 loaves of bread and 10 flasks of wine.

Topic 4: Analysis of Equilibrium.

Chapter 6. The Standard Trade Model

Lesson 11: Specific-Factors Model (continued)

Final Exam - Economics 101 (Fall 2009) You will have 120 minutes to complete this exam. There are 105 points and 7 pages

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher- Ohlin Model

The Ricardian Model. Rafael López-Monti Department of Economics George Washington University Summer 2015 (Econ 6280.

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

Problem Set #3 - Answers. Trade Models

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

University of Toronto November 28, ECO 100Y INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test # 2

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Lecture 4 2/5/2018. Instructor: Prof. Menzie Chinn UW Madison Spring 2018

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

11 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions:

Distortions and Government Policies as Determinants of Trade, unotes6. Motivation:

UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON Department of Economics

PubPol/Econ 541. The Standard Model. Elaboration of diagrams in Krugman, Obstfeld & Melitz textbook. by Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan 2016

1/25/2011. Introduction to International Trade. Basic Theory of Trade

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Lecture 15 - General Equilibrium with Production

SOLUTIONS. ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY Term Test 2 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto January 26, 2005 INSTRUCTIONS:

Problem Set 1: Ricardo s Principle of Comparative Advantage

Lecture 12 International Trade. Noah Williams

Midterm Exam International Trade Economics 6903, Fall 2008 Donald Davis

Chapter 7 Economic Growth and International Trade

Midterm 2 - Economics 101 (Fall 2009) You will have 45 minutes to complete this exam. There are 5 pages and 63 points. Version A.

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

1. Consider the aggregate production functions for Wisconsin and Minnesota: Production Function for Wisconsin

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

ANSWERS To next 16 Multiple Choice Questions below B B B B A E B E C C C E C C D B

L K Y Marginal Product of Labor (MPl) Labor Productivity (Y/L)

TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

ECON 102 Boyle Final Exam New Material Practice Exam Solutions

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

14.02 Quiz #2 SOLUTION. Spring Time Allowed: 90 minutes

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

MTA-ECON3901 Fall 2009 Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson or Model

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Lecture 6-7 2/12-2/14/2018

ADVERSE SELECTION AND SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

Answers to Questions: Chapter 8

Problem Set 5: Individual and Market Demand. Comp BC

International Trade: Economics and Policy. LECTURE 5: Absolute vs. Comparative Advantages

ECO 100Y L0101 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #2

Professor Bee Roberts. Economics 302 Practice Exam. Part I: Multiple Choice (14 questions)

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

PREFERENTIAL TRADE AREAS

Final Review questions

Consider the aggregate production function for Dane County:

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

Final Exam December 16, 2011 Answers

ECON 221: PRACTICE EXAM 2

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Specific factors and Income Distribution

This is The Heckscher-Ohlin (Factor Proportions) Model, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Trade (index.html) (v. 1.0).

Globalization. University of California San Diego (UCSD) Catherine Laffineur.

International Economics Lecture 2: The Ricardian Model

Economics 102 Fall 2015 Answers to Homework #4 Due Monday, November 9, 2015

MIDTERM Version A Wednesday, February 15, 2006 Multiple choice - each worth 3 points

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Chapter 2: Gains from Trade. August 14, 2008

Symmetric Game. In animal behaviour a typical realization involves two parents balancing their individual investment in the common

Chapter 7 Trade Policy Effects with Perfectly Competitive Markets

Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THEORY AND POLICY (HO)

Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model

Practice Problem Set 2 (ANSWERS)

Chapter 4. Consumer Choice. A Consumer s Budget Constraint. Consumer Choice

POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES

Problem Set #3 - Answers Analysis of Trade Barriers. P w

ECS2601 Oct / Nov 2014 Examination Memorandum. (1a) Raymond has a budget of R200. The price of food is R20 and the price of clothes is R50.

SECOND HOURLY EXAMINATION ECON 200 Spring 2006 STUDENT'S SOCIAL SECURITY NUMBER: DAY AND TIME YOUR SECTION MEETS:

Lecture 13. Trade in Factors. 2. The Jones-Coelho-Easton two-factor, one-good model.

ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring Lecture notes 03 Applications of Revealed Preferences

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Lecture 3: Consumer Choice

The Standard Theory of International Trade

Practice Problem Solutions for Exam 1

ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

File: Ch03; Chapter 3: The Standard Theory of International Trade

Aggregate Demand & Aggregate Supply

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Faculty of Arts and Science. August Examination 2006 ECO 209Y

Chapter 10 3/19/2018. AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND (Part 1) Objectives. Aggregate Supply

Economics 201 Fall 2010

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Demand Side: Community Indifference Curve (CIC) Shows various combinations of two goods with equivalent welfare

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM. Wanna Download D. Salvatore, International Economics for free? Gr8, visit now jblogger2016.wordpress.com

Transcription:

Page 1 of 9 July 30, 2003 Answer all questions, in blue book. Plan and budget your time. The questions are worth a total of 80 points, as indicated, and you will have 80 minutes to complete the exam. 1. [20 points] In the (standard) Specific Factors odel, analyze the effects on factor prices of an increase in the relative price of good. That is, a. [14 points] Show how a rise in the price of good, holding the nominal price of good constant, would change the market equilibrium values of the i. nominal wage ii. nominal rental on capital employed in iii. nominal rental on capital employed in iv. real wage v. real rental on capital employed in vi. real rental on capital employed in Use the usual Specific Factors diagram to help you get your results, together with other relationships that you know must hold, but also be sure to say explicitly what you have found and why. [It has been pointed out to me that 14+4 20, and I have confirmed this with my calculator. I have therefore given everyone a free 2 points on this question.] Holding the price of good constant, the rise in price of good shifts the VP L =p P L curve upward, as shown below: w w w 3 w 2 w 1 p P L p 'P L O L L ' p P L O Thus, the rise in p causes more labor to be employed in the sector (L rises) and less in the sector (L falls). These changes in turn, since capital stocks in the sectors are fixed in the specific factors model, mean that the ratios of capital to labor, on which marginal products depend, change as follows: K /L falls K /L rises.

Page 2 of 9 It follows, since in each sector P L rises with K/L and P K falls with K/L, that P L falls P L rises P K rises P K falls From the figure we see immediately that the nominal wage rises, from w 1 to w 2, as does the nominal rental price of capital in the sector (since the triangle above w 2 and below VP L ' is larger, meaning that payments to -sector capital increase, while the quantity of capital there has not changed), while the nominal rental price of capital in the sector falls (the triangle for it gets smaller). As for real factor prices, these can be inferred from their ratios to goods prices, which are equal to marginal products, as shown in the list below. w = p P L = p P L rises, from figure r = p P K rises, from figure, or because p and P K both rise r = p P K falls, from figure, or because P K falls w/p = P L falls w/p = P L rises hence effect on real wage is ambiguous r /p = P K rises r /p = (r /p )(p /p ) rises, since both terms rise hence real rental on -sector capital rises r /p = P K falls r /p = (r /p )/(p /p ) falls, since numerator falls and denominator rises hence real rental on -sector capital falls b. [4 points] Which of your answers would be changed if it were the nominal wage that were fixed, instead of the nominal price of? The figure would be harder to draw, since now in addition to what is shown above, we would need to lower both goods prices in the same proportion to get w back where it started. But you don t need to do this. Rather, just note that real variables are unaffected by nominal ones, so the answers for real factor prices must be the same as above. (Each ratio of a factor price to a goods price depends just on a real marginal product and, in some cases, the relative prices of the goods, never on any nominal prices alone.) Since w = p P L = p P L, and since the shift of labor has caused P L to fall and P L to rise, the constant wage requires that p rise while p falls. Thus r =p P K rises, since both p and P K rise. And r =p P K falls, since both p and P K fall.

Page 3 of 9 2. [22 points] Consider a small open economy that, in the absence of any policy, would export good. a. [4 points] Of the following four policies, i. A production tax on ii. A consumption tax on iii. A production tax on iv. A consumption tax on which policy, if large enough, could cause the country to export good instead of exporting? Note: ou do not necessarily need to draw any diagrams for this part, unless you find that it helps you to find the answer. A production tax on causes less of it to be produced, and thus more of it to be imported, not less. A consumption tax on would cause less of it to be consumed, and thus more of it to be exported, not less. But a consumption tax on would causes less of it to be consumed, thus less imported, and if large enough could reduce consumption below production and cause to be exported. Likewise, a production tax on would reduce production of, and thus reduce exports of, and if the tax were large enough could also reverse the pattern of trade. So it is policies ii and iii that have the potential to reverse the pattern of trade: a consumption tax on and a production tax on. b. [6 points] Let the relative price of on the world market be, and the country s relative price of in autarky be. For just one of the policies you ve identified in part (a) (if there were more than one), suppose it were set equal to the percentage difference between and. Show that this would not be enough to reverse the pattern of trade. -Production Tax = / -Consumption Tax = / P P'=P C' P'=A C C' A C A production tax on of this size will lower the price received by -producers to its autarky level, and thus raise the relative price of to producers to. A consumption tax on will raise the price of to consumer to its autarky level,

Page 4 of 9 and thus raise the relative price to consumers to. We show these changes in the figures above, while leaving the untaxed group facing the world price. That is, a production tax on of this size would move production to the autarky point, but since consumers would still face the lower world price of, they would still consume more than is being produced, and thus the country would still import, as shown above. A consumption tax of this size on would confront consumers with the autarky prices, but since producers now will still face world prices, they would continue to produce at free-trade levels. Thus, again, production of would be less than consumption of, and the country would import, as also shown above. c. [6 points] For the same policy you chose in part (b), draw and explain an equilibrium in which the policy does reverse the pattern of trade. -Production Tax >> / -Consumption Tax >> / C' P A C P' =P A C C' P' A sufficiently large production tax on will lower the price received by - producers sufficiently below the world price (and thus raise producers relative price of ) to reduce its output of below consumption, perhaps even to zero. It produces at P' in the figure, and consumes at C', exporting. A sufficiently high consumption tax on will raise the price paid by consumers sufficiently above the world price to reduce its consumption below production, also perhaps to zero if preferences permit that. With consumption at C' and production at P', it too now exports. d. [6 points] Without doing any formal analysis for this part of the question, but drawing on what you know from our various models, who gains and who loses from the policy that you ve illustrated in part (c)? Production tax on : Because this changes prices received by producers, it also changes factor prices. The rise in relative price of to producers will raise the real return either to the factor used intensively in the industry (in the HO model) or the specific factor(s) in the industry (in the Specific Factors odel), while lowering the real return to the other (or other specific) factor. Thus the

Page 5 of 9 owners of these factors, if that is their only source of income, gain and lose correspondingly. However, the tax revenue must also be used, and if as usual we assume that it is redistributed to somebody, that gives them an additional gain. Nonetheless, we know from the move to a lower indifference curve above that the country as a whole is worse off, so the losers just mentioned must surely lose. Consumption tax on : As shown above, this leaves prices faced by producers unchanged at their world levels, and therefore does not change factor prices relative to world prices. However, all residents of the country now pay a higherthan-world price for as consumers, by the amount of the tax, while perhaps getting a share of the redistributed tax revenue. If all persons are alike as consumers and share in this redistribution in proportion to their income, then we know from the lower indifference curve reached by the country as a whole that all of them must lose. If they are not alike, and/or if they share unequally in the redistribution, some may gain who don t want to consume much anyway, and/or who share disproportionately in the redistribution. 3. [18 points] We have argued that when an industry in a country is imperfectly competitive, then trade can provide an additional, pro-competitive benefit, over and above the gains from comparative advantage, to the extent that it forces producers to behave more like perfect competitors. But what if trade drives them out of business? Are there still gains from trade? And if there are, how do these compare to what would have happened with perfect competition? To answer this question, first a. [4 points] show and explain an autarky equilibrium in which one sector is a monopolist, and then The figure below depicts autarky equilibrium in an economy in which the sector is a monopoly, and therefore charges consumers a price higher than marginal cost. This is reflected in a price line to consumers, p C, tangent to an indifference curve that is steeper (higher relative price of ) than the slope of the PPF. u m p C

Page 6 of 9 b. [4 points] open to free trade at a world price such that all production in that sector ceases. This will happen if the world relative price of is smaller than the slope of the PPF at it -axis intercept. The result, shown below, is zero output of at P f and consumers consuming at, and trading to C f, the tangency shown of the world price line,, to an indifference curve. P f C f u f u m c. [4 points] Show whether there are gains from trade, and p C Clearly, from the figure above, there are gains from trade, since we move from the indifference curve u m to u f d. [6 points] show how these gains or losses compare to what would have happened with trade if the sector had been perfectly competitive. With perfect competition we would have started from the undistorted autarky equilibrium, which is found at point A below as the tangency between the PPF and an indifference curve. Adding this to the figure above, and labeling it as u a, we see that the gains from trade are larger when we start with the monopoly, and trade moves us from u m to u f, than they would have been if we had started from A, moving from u a to u f. This is true even though the monopoly has been driven completely out of business by the low priced competition from free trade. P f A u m C f u a u f p C

Page 7 of 9 4. [20 points] Use the External Increasing Returns to Scale (EIRS) odel, from lecture and the handout, to answers the questions below. Use, for each, both the tools of the model and an explanation in words. As in the handout and in lecture, let the increasing returns good be =machines and the constant returns good be F=food, and let the Home country have a larger labor force than the Foreign country. a. [6 points] Why, if two countries are otherwise identical, does the one with the larger labor force have a lower relative autarky price of machines? The too simple, but correct, answer is that the larger country is better able to take advantage of the increasing returns to scale and it thus enjoys a lower relative price in autarky for the IRS good. But to show this you must show not just that it can produce more, but that it will, using demand conditions. p D* D AC* AC A A * A * Formally (and easy for me, since I can copy the diagram from the handout), the picture is as appears below. The two countries share the same AC curve out to the limit of their output permitted by their labor forces. This limit in this case is higher for the home country,, than for the foreign country, *. They have different demand curves, however, because of their different sizes. At any < *, the Home country has more labor left over to produce the other good, Food, and so produces a lower ratio of /F and requires a higher relative price, p=p /p F, to get consumers to demand this low ratio. This places its demand curve above (and to the right) of Foreign s, as shown. But with D to the right of D*, the intersection with AC (and AC*) occurs to the left for Foreign and thus at a higher price. This proves that the relative price of machines (the IRS good) is lower in the country with more labor. b. [6 points] Why, if these two countries open to free trade, will the larger country expand production of machines, and the other contract production of machines? When they open to free trade, if we assume that initially that outputs do not change, then the market will have to clear with the outputs they are currently producing. Initially, as indicated by its low relative price, Home is producing a higher ratio of to F than Foreign. When their outputs combine, the ratio available in the world lies between these two, higher than in but lower than in F, so the world price settles between the two autarky prices, rising in Home and

Page 8 of 9 falling in Foreign. But this means that producers in Home find themselves facing a price that is higher than their average cost, and they now make a profit. At the same time, Foreign producers face a world price lower than their average cost and make a loss. We therefore expect Home producers to expand, and/or new firms to enter the market in Home, so that output of in the Home economy expands. And we expect the opposite to happen in Foreign, since they are making a loss, and Foreign output of contracts. c. [8 points] Assume a new free trade equilibrium in which the larger country does indeed produce more than does the smaller country, as they started to do in part (b). In fact, assume that Home produces only and Foreign produces only F, and further that the equilibrium relative price of is above the autarky price in Foreign. Which of these countries gains more from trade, and why? The free trade equilibrium is found by constructing an AC W curve for the world p p W AC D W AC* A A* AC W that duplicates that of the large country, followed by the small country, as follows: I have placed the world demand curve so as to create an equilibrium with the properties listed in the question: Both countries completely specialize, and the price is above the autarky price of Foreign (see the point marked A*, below the p W line on AC*). To see what happens to welfare, however, we need to look at the PPFs and F p W F* P* u* f u* A A u A C P u f C* p W A* A *

Page 9 of 9 indifference curves. These are drawn below for the two countries. These show first the two autarky equilibria, at points A and A*, prices and A with corresponding utility u A and u* A. Because Home specializes completely in, it produces at the corner of its PPF on the axis, point P, and consumers are able to trade from there at the price p W that is well above its average cost. Foreign, on the other hand, produces only F at P*, at the other corner of its PPF, and trades at a price that is higher (steeper) than its autarky price. As shown, Home gains quite a lot, while Foreign actually loses from this trade. Given the configuration of production and price stated in the question, this is the way that it has to turn out, since Foreign must import at a price that is higher than it produced it itself in autarky.