Fiscal Fact. The Effects of Terminating Tax Expenditures and Cutting Individual Income Tax Rates. By Michael Schuyler, PhD

Similar documents
Special Report. Using Dynamic Analysis Makes Tax Reform 30 Percent Less Challenging. Key Findings. August 2013 No. 210

Feldstein Proposal Increases Federal Revenues but the Devil s in the Details

A Dynamic Analysis of President Obama s Tax Initiatives

Preliminary Details and Analysis of the Senate s 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

Preliminary Details and Analysis of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Written Testimony of Scott A. Hodge, President, Tax Foundation

Details and Analysis of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

CBO Overly Optimistic about Economic Growth and the Federal Debt

A Brief History of Tax Expenditures

FISCAL FACT No. 516 July, 2016 Director of Federal Projects Key Findings Embargoed

U.S. House of Representatives COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS

An Overview of Recent Tax Reform Proposals

How Do the Presidential Candidates Tax Plans Affect Taxpayers Marginal Tax Rates?

ESTATE TAXES, DEFICITS, AND BUDGET IMPLICATIONS

FISCAL FACT President s Deficit Commission Says Federal Government Should Be 21 Percent of GDP

1) The progressive, three-bracket tax system does not treat all taxpayers equally, leaving a degree of special treatment and complexity in the code.

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 2014

HOW THE TAX REFORM OF 1986 SUPERCHARGED THE AMERICAN ECONOMY

WebMemo22. The End of Pro-Growth Tax Policy: How the Rangel Tax Bill Could Affect the U.S. Economy. Published by The Heritage Foundation

ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF THE WYDEN-COATS TAX PLAN

Details and Analysis of Donald Trump s Tax Plan

ESTATE TAXES, DEFICITS and BUDGET IMPLICATIONS

BACKGROUNDER. After a 12-year hiatus, Congress and President Barack Obama. PEP and Pease Hurt Larger Families Most and Slow Growth.

Trends in Tax Expenditures, Allison Rogers and Eric Toder Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center September 16, 2011

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are tax expenditures and how are they structured?

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, all years are federal fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and are designated by the calendar year

The Changing Composition of Tax Incentives

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

Published by The Maine Heritage Policy Center Issue Eighteen. The Economic Impact of an Enterprise Value Tax on Maine. J.

And Jobs Act, November 14, 2017, %20chairman's%20modified%20mark.pdf.

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

What The New CBO Report Shows Budget And Economic Outlook Has Not Improved by James Horney and Richard Kogan

Making the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act Individual Income Tax Provisions Permanent

Statement on Tax Reform

Corporate Tax Integration: In Brief

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF THE FAMILY FAIRNESS AND OPPORTUNITY TAX REFORM ACT

Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden

Obama s Tax Hikes on High-Income Earners Will Hurt the Poor and Everyone Else

State Implications of Federal Tax Reform. National Conference of State Legislatures State Taxation Task Force November 2017

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects.

June 19, I hope this information is helpful to you. The CBO staff contacts are Frank Sammartino and Terry Dinan. Sincerely,

Distributional Impact of Social Security Reforms: Summary

REVIEW OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF TAX REFORM ON CONSUMERS NOVEMBER Commissioned by

Putting Capital Back to Work for America

Updating the American Tax System:

How Tax Reform Can Address America s Diminishing Investment and Economic Growth

Effects of the PPACA Health Insurance Premium Tax on Small Businesses and Their Employees

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE CBO The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2016 to 2026 Percentage of GDP 100 Actual Projected 80

Getting Real with Capital Gains Taxes by Adjusting for Inflation

Tax Code Connections: How Changes to Federal Policy Affect State Revenue Technical appendix

The Economic Effects of Canceling Scheduled Changes to Overtime Regulations

Equity Returns: Sources and Drivers for the First Decade of the 21 st Century

Fixing the American Income Tax System. Organized by: Jason M. Fields

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY COMPREHENSIVE TAX REFORM. The Time Is Now. Comprehensive Tax Reform The Time Is Now. July 2013

What Federal Tax Reform Means for State and Local Tax and Fiscal Policies

Briefing Paper. Business Week Restates the Nineties. By Dean Baker. April 22, 2002

AUGUST 2012 An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2022 Provided as a convenience, this screen-friendly version is identic

GAO. TAX POLICY Puerto Rican Economic Trends. Report to the Chairman, Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate. United States General Accounting Office

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

The U.S. Current Account Balance and the Business Cycle

219 Dirksen Senate Office Building 219 Dirksen Senate Office Building Washington, D.C Washington, D.C

THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON FISCAL RESPONSIBILITY AND REFORM. The Moment of Truth

IRET Congressional Advisory

Options for Broadening the U.S. Tax Base

ATR Feedback on the Chairman s Mark of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

RE: AICPA Comments on Option 2 of Chairman Camp s Small Business Tax Reform Discussion Draft

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

TAX TREATMENT OF INTANGIBLES

The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary

A Retrospective on the Tax Law of 2017 and Prospective on the Next Tax Laws Note some estimates represent work in progress that is subject to revision

unusually small at the end of 2017 and the beginning of 2018 as a result of debt-ceiling constraints.

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

CONGRESS JANUARY Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (H.R. 1)

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT AS ORDERED REPORTED BY THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ON NOVEMBER 16, 2017

TECHNICAL ANALYSIS OF THE SPECIAL COMMISSION TO STUDY THE MASSACHUSETTS CONTRIBUTORY RETIREMENT SYSTEMS SUBMITTED OCTOBER 7, 2009

Dynamic Scoring and Tax Reform

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

THE FOREIGN INCOME TAX RATIONALIZATION AND SIMPLIFICATION ACT OF 1992

The Beacon Hill Institute

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Gauging Current Conditions:

The Better Way Tax Plan

Revised Senate Plan Would Raise Taxes on at Least 29% of Americans and Cause 19 States to Pay More Overall (State-by-State Figures in Appendix)

Obama Tax Hikes: Bad for All Americans

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

Distributional Impacts of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

Senate Proposal for Balanced Budget Amendment Would Require Extreme Budget Cuts By Richard Kogan and Cecile Murray 1

The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028

Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 39: Indexation and the Inflation Tax

In fiscal year 2016, for the first time since 2009, the

The Growth and Investment Tax Plan

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

2014 Annual Review & Outlook

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

Regulatory Announcement RNS Number: RNS to insert number here Québec 27 November, 2017

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in this report are fe

HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS OFFSET FOR REPEALING AFFORDABLE CARE ACT S TAX REPORTING REQUIREMENT WOULD WEAKEN HEALTH REFORM

Ending the Capital Gains Tax Preference would Improve Fairness, Raise Revenue and Simplify the Tax Code

Transcription:

September 30, 2013 No. 396 Fiscal Fact The Effects of Terminating Tax Expenditures and Cutting Individual Income Tax Rates By Michael Schuyler, PhD Leading members of the House and Senate tax writing committees are examining the possibility of trading a broader tax base for dramatically lower rates. Representative Dave Camp (R-MI), the chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee, is believed to be seeking enough revenue enhancers to lower the top corporate and individual income tax rates to 25 percent while maintaining revenue neutrality. Senators Max Baucus (D-MT) and Orrin Hatch (R-UT), the chairman and ranking member of the Senate Finance Committee, respectively, have proposed a "blank slate" approach, in which most "tax expenditures" income tax exclusions, deductions, and credits, and other provisions that the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) classifies as preferences would be abolished, except for those that could be convincingly defended, with the money dedicated to rate cuts and perhaps deficit reduction. One of the primary motivations for tax reform is a recognition that the U.S. income tax system is a serious drag on economic growth. Its anti-growth effects, which are inadvertent but powerful, hurt Americans' productivity and incomes, reduce their ability to compete in an increasingly global marketplace, and diminish their future opportunities. Many believe that these ill effects could be moderated through tax reform. In the words of Representative Camp and Senator Baucus, Tax reform provides an opportunity to spark economic growth, create jobs, and make U.S. businesses more competitive, both here at home and in the global marketplace. It can provide America a real shot in the arm. 1 Of course, as the congressman and senators have also noted, while growth is extremely important, it is not the only criterion by which to judge proposed tax changes. In response to the "blank slate" proposal, and in order better to understand which trade-offs of tax expenditures for lower rates would be most conducive to growth, we used our Taxes and Growth Model (TAG Model), which accounts for the impact taxes have on our economy, to examine eleven large tax provisions in the individual income tax that the JCT regards as tax expenditures. 2 The eleven provisions 1 Press Release, House Committee on Ways and Means, Camp, Baucus Highlight How Tax Reform Can Spark Innovation at Stop in Silicon Valley (Aug. 20, 2013), http://waysandmeans.house.gov/news/documentsingle.aspx?documentid=346344. 2 The U.S. Treasury also compiles a list of tax expenditures. The two government lists are similar, but they are far from identical because deciding what items constitute tax expenditures is a subjective process that requires many value judgments.

equal over half the total dollar amount of all tax expenditures. In each case, the TAG Model estimated the impact of abolishing the tax provision on gross domestic product (GDP), investment, and employment, as well as the static and dynamic revenue effects. 3 The model also estimated the outcome if the static revenue gain were used to finance an across-the-board rate cut. A key advantage of our TAG Model s dynamic revenue estimates is that they consider the growth effects that occur when tax changes alter marginal incentives to work, save, and invest. Conventional revenue estimates, such as those usually provided by the JCT and others, make the simplifying assumption that tax changes exert no impact on overall aggregates like total employment, investment, income, and production in the economy. (The JCT would describe its estimates as micro-dynamic because they permit shifts within the economy, such as fewer sales of heavily taxed products, provided those are precisely offset by more sales of other products so that total sales remain constant.) The conventional, static assumption is reasonable when estimating the consequences of tax changes that do not substantially alter marginal incentives, but misleading when trying to understand tax proposals that would have large incentive effects. Because Senators Baucus and Hatch focused on the individual income tax in their "blank slate" proposal, our case studies did likewise. The JCT does consider some provisions in the corporate income tax to be tax expenditures, but they are much smaller in dollar terms than those on the individual side about one-tenth the size. Notwithstanding popular rhetoric, the Tax Reform Act of 1986 removed most genuine corporate tax loopholes, and only a few have crept back in. In contrast, the dollar amount of tax expenditures on the individual side has grown enormously in recent years. 4 While the separate case studies were needed to distinguish between trade-offs that would speed growth and some that would actually slow the U.S. economy, a natural question is what would be the impact if the eleven tax expenditures were eliminated en masse. The revenue from that base broadening could finance dramatically lower income tax rates. Would the trade-off also lead to dramatically faster growth? Conventional Revenue Estimates Our eleven previous case studies considered the following tax deductions, exclusions, and credits: the mortgage interest deduction, the property tax deduction, reduced tax rates on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends, 3 For links to the earlier papers in the series, see Michael Schuyler & Stephen Entin, The Economics of the Blank Slate: Estimating the Effects of Eliminating Major Tax Expenditures and Cutting Tax Rates, TAX FOUNDATION FISCAL FACT NO. 378 (July 26, 2013), http://taxfoundation.org/article/economics-blank-slate-estimating-effects-eliminating-major-tax-expenditures-and-cuttingtax-rates. 4 For an overview of the relative sizes of tax expenditures in the individual and corporate income taxes, and their changes over time, see William McBride, A Brief History of Tax Expenditures, TAX FOUNDATION FISCAL FACT NO. 391 (Aug. 22, 2013), http://taxfoundation.org/article/briefhistory-tax-expenditures. 2

the state and local income tax deduction, accelerated depreciation, the exclusion from taxable income of employer provided health care, the earned income tax credit, education credits, the child tax credit, the partial exclusion from taxable income of social security benefits, and the charitable deduction. Chart 1. Static Revenue Estimates For Eliminating Eleven Large "Tax Expenditures" from the Individual Income Tax Combined Social Security Benefit Exclusion State & Local Inc. Tax Deduction Charitable Deduction Employer-Provid. Health Exclusion Education Credits Child Tax Credit Earned Income Credit Property Tax Deduction Mortgage Interest Deduction ADS (Non-Corporate Only) Cap Gain/Dividend Rate Cap $19 $39 $160 $9 $34 $7 $68 $47 $56 $101 $108 $574 The sum of individual components does not equal the combined effect because of interactions. In estimating for this study the combined effects of ending all eleven tax provisions, we first used the TAG Model to generate a conventional, static revenue estimate by artificially constraining growth effects to be zero. Our static estimate is that eliminating these eleven provisions would boost annual individual income tax collections by $574 billion. 5 Chart 1 shows this amount and the static revenue estimates for each of the eleven provisions. The three largest, in order, are the exclusion for employer-provided health care, the rate cap on capital gains and dividends, and the mortgage interest deduction. 5 The dollar amounts in the model are based on 2008 data, aged to 2012 dollars. The tax data come from a representative sample of 140,000 tax returns (the 2008 IRS Public Use File). The economic data in the baseline are from the National Income and Products Accounts (NIPA) prepared by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 3

Growth Effects and Dynamic Revenue Estimates In the next step, we dropped the artificial static assumption and reran the model. The separate case studies had previously revealed that tax expenditures can be grouped into three broad categories based on their growth effects: Some provisions, such as the rate cap on the taxation of capital gains and dividends, partially offset income tax biases against saving and investing. (If measured against a saving-consumption neutral tax system, they would not be considered tax expenditures at all.) Eliminating them would intensify income tax biases against capital formation and, because people s saving and investment decisions are extremely sensitive to the expected after-tax rate of return, lead to major drops in the capital stock, productivity, and the size of the economy. The repeal of some provisions, such as the tax exclusion for employer-provided health care and the deduction for state and local income taxes, would have a mild negative growth effect if used solely as tax increases because they would bump some taxpayers into higher marginal tax brackets. Some provisions, such as the Earned Income Credit (EIC), create positive work incentives at very low incomes but discourage additional work effort over a range of higher incomes because the benefits are clawed back as income rises. It is an empirical question which effect dominates. With the Earned Income Credit (EIC) and the Child Tax Credit, the TAG Model estimates that the negative effect is stronger, which implies that more labor would be supplied and growth would be slightly higher if the provisions and their clawbacks Chart 2. Effect on GDP of Eliminating Eleven Large "Tax Expenditures" from the Individual Income Tax Combined, -$1,582 The sum of individual components does not equal the combined effect because of interactions. Social Security Benefit Exclusion, $0 State & Local Inc. Tax Deduction, -$74 Charitable Deduction, -$40 Employer-Provid. Health Exclusion, -$108 Education Credits, $5 Child Tax Credit, $14 Earned Income Credit, $34 Property Tax Deduction, -$94 Mortgage Interest Deduction -$254 ADS (Non-Corporate Only), -$59 were repealed. Cap Gain/Dividend Rate Cap -$983 4

Scenario No. 1: Eliminating Tax Expenditures Without Rate Reductions Taking all eleven provisions together, the TAG Model predicts that abolishing them without any offsetting rate reductions would result in serious economic damage. Faced with a harsher tax climate at the margin, people would respond by supplying less labor and capital. The model estimates that private capital stocks would plummet almost 23 percent, wages would fall more than 8 percent, and work hours would decline 2.6 percent the equivalent of roughly 2.7 million full time jobs. The tax-induced drop in production inputs, in turn, would cause production and incomes across the economy to fall. The model estimates that GDP would plunge by nearly $1.6 trillion over 10 percent if all the tax increases were enacted without offsets. Chart 2 depicts this finding, as well as the previously estimated GDP changes from removing each of the eleven provisions separately. Further, since the size and health of the economy are key determinants of tax receipts, the smaller economy would exert a negative feedback on tax collections. The model predicts that eliminating the eleven provisions would still lift federal revenue, but the dynamic revenue estimate of $179 billion is less than one-third of the conventional, static estimate. Chart 3 shows this amount and the dynamic revenue estimates for each of the eleven provisions separately. Box 1 summarizes the findings for Scenario 1. Chart 3. Dynamic Revenue Estimates for Eliminating Eleven Large "Tax Expenditures" from the Individual Income Tax Combined $179 State & Local Inc. Tax Deduction $50 Social Security Benefit Exclusion $20 Charitable Deduction $30 Employer-Provid. Health Exclusion $133 Education Credits $10 Child Tax Credit $50 Earned Income Credit $64 Property Tax Deduction $11 Mortgage Interest Deduction $39 ADS (Non-Corporate Only) -$6 Box 1. Estimated Effects if the Following Eleven "Tax Expenditures" were Eliminated from the Individual Income Tax The Eleven Provisions Mortgage interest deduction Property tax deduction Reduced tax rates on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends State and local income tax deduction Accelerated depreciation Exclusion for employer provided health insurance Earned income tax credit Education credits Child tax credit Partial income tax exclusion for social security retirement benefits Charitable deduction Economic And Budget Changes Versus 2013 Law (Dollar amounts in billions of 2012 dollars unless indicated otherwise) GDP, percent change -10.13% GDP, dollar change -$1,581.7 Private business GDP, percent change -10.56% Private business stocks, percent change -22.70% Wage rate, percent change -8.16% Private business hours of work, percent change -2.62% Full time equivalent jobs -2,680,000 Static federal revenue estimate, dollar change $574.2 Dynamic federal revenue estimate, dollar change $178.6 % Revenue reflow vs. static -68.9% Dollars of lost GDP per dollar of added federal revenue -$8.86 Weighted average service price (percent change) Corporate 20.85% Noncorporate 3.68% All business 15.70% Source: Tax Foundation calculations 5 -$122 Cap Gain/Dividend Rate Cap The sum of individual components does not equal the combined effect because of interactions.

It should be noted that the model is looking at the results after people have fully adjusted to the new tax rules. The model is not estimating the year-by-year changes during the transition. The adjustment requires time, particularly for modifications to the capital stock, but experience suggests that most of the adjustments in the stock of equipment will be completed within five years and most of the adjustments to structures within ten years. Of course, growth is not the only relevant criterion to use when evaluating a tax provision. Simplicity, predictability, fairness, transparency, and other factors should also be considered. That said, growth is extremely important and should not be ignored. Even if growth was not valued for its own sake, it matters when gauging the revenue consequences of tax changes. As the results here suggest, tax increases usually bring in fewer tax dollars than static revenue estimates predict, sometimes far fewer, while tax cuts are often less costly than foreseen by models that assume away growth. Scenario No. 2: Trading a Broader Income Tax Base for Lower Rates According to a conventional, static revenue estimate, repealing the eleven provisions we evaluated could pay for a huge, revenue-neutral, across-the-board cut in individual income tax rates. In static mode, our TAG Model estimates the across-the-board cut would be 36.5 percent. For example, the 10 percent rate would drop to 6.4 percent, the 25 percent rate to 15.9 percent, and the 39.6 percent rate to 25.1 percent. These are spectacular rate reductions, and they would be highly favorable to growth. However, the model's dynamic tax simulation estimates show that these reductions would not be sufficient to outweigh the harm done to growth by the base broadening. Chart 4. Using the Static Revenue Gain from Eliminating Eleven Large Tax Expenditures to Pay for an Across-The-Board Rate Cut Federal Revenue Change, Change, Static Dynamic GDP Change $0 $0 -$59 -$100 -$200 -$300 -$299 The explanation is that many of the revenue raisers, in dollar terms, would hit capital income, which is very responsive to after-tax rewards, producing a strong negative effect, while the majority of the rate cuts would apply to labor income, which is not as responsive to after-tax rewards, producing a smaller offsetting benefit. As illustrated in Chart 4, the TAG Model estimates that after people have adjusted to the new tax incentives, GDP would be $299 billion lower than otherwise and because of the smaller economic pie, federal revenue would be $59 billion lower. The model also estimates that, on net, private capital stocks would decline 5.4 percent, wages would fall 3.4 percent, and private-sector work hours would decline almost 1.7 percent (the equivalent of 1.7 million full time jobs.) 6

Chart 5. Eliminating Selected Tax Expenditures, Effects on and GDP $600 $300 $0 -$300 -$600 -$900 -$1,200 -$1,500 -$1,800 $574 $453 Change, Static 11 Large Tax Expenditures Excluding Cap Gains / Dividend Rate Cap $315 $179 GDP Change Change, Dynamic -$549 -$1,582 Box 2. Estimated Effects If The Following Ten "Tax Expenditures" Were Eliminated From The Individual Income Tax The Ten Provisions Mortgage interest deduction Property tax deduction State and local income tax deduction Accelerated depreciation Exclusion for employer provided health insurance Earned income tax credit Education credits Child tax credit Partial income tax exclusion for social security retirement benefits Charitable deduction Economic And Budget Changes Versus 2013 Law (Dollar amounts in billions of 2012 dollars unless indicated otherwise) GDP, percent change -3.51% GDP, dollar change -$548.77 Private business GDP, percent change -3.70% Private business stocks, percent change -5.49% Wage rate, percent change -2.54% Private business hours of work, percent change -1.18% Full time equivalent jobs -1,210,000 Static federal revenue estimate, dollar change $452.89 Dynamic federal revenue estimate, dollar change $315.49 % Revenue reflow vs. static -30.34% Dollars of lost GDP per dollar of added federal revenue -$1.74 Weighted average service price (percent change) Corporate 1.04% Noncorporate 3.89% All business 1.89% Source: Tax Foundation calculations Scenario No. 3: Eliminating Ten Tax Expenditures Without Rate Reductions; Less Harmful Results If the Current-Law Rate Cap On Capital Gains and Dividends Is Retained About 60 percent, by dollar amount, of the provisions on the tax expenditure list soften the income tax s anti-saving bias. 6 One of the largest and most crucial is the tax rate limitation on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends. We repeated the simulations and left these rates unchanged, as in current law. As seen in Chart 5, the elimination of the ten other tax expenditures being modeled produces a static revenue gain of $453 billion, which is $121 billion less than with the elimination of all eleven. However, the drop in GDP, at $549 billion, is only about one-third as severe as in Scenario 1, where the tax rates on capital gains and dividends rose sharply. Because output still declines, the dynamic revenue estimate falls short of the static estimate. However, the economic damage is not as extreme as in Scenario 1, with the result that the dynamic revenue estimate for eliminating the ten other tax expenditures, $315 billion, is 75 percent larger than if the rate cap on capital gains and dividends were also abolished. Box 2 presents the main findings for Scenario 3. 6 See McBride, supra note 4. 7

Scenario No. 4: Trading Ten Large Tax Expenditures for Lower Rates If the rate cap on capital gains and Chart 6. Using The Static Revenue Gain From dividends is retained and the static Eliminating Selected Tax Expenditures To Pay For revenue gain from the ten other An Across-The-Board Rate Cut provisions that were modeled is used Tax Foundation Calculations for an across-the-board rate cut, Change, individual income taxes could be Change, Static Dynamic GDP Change reduced by 33.3 percent. For $0 $0 $1 $10 example, the 10 percent rate would $0 -$59 drop to 6.7 percent, the 25 percent rate to 16.7 percent, and the 39.6 -$100 percent rate to 26.4 percent. 11 Large Tax Expenditures; Although this offset is not quite as -$200 36.5% Rate Cut large as the earlier one in Scenario 2, Excluding Cap Gains / the economic results are much better. -$299 Instead of an estimated GDP loss -$300 Dividend Rate Cap; 33.3% Rate Cut about $300 billion, there would be an estimated gain of $10 billion, as -$400 shown in Chart 6. And instead of an estimated dynamic revenue loss of about $60 billion, this more modest trade-off of a broader base for lower rates would be approximately revenue neutral on a dynamic basis. The TAG model only looks at one of the avenues through which higher tax rates on capital gains and dividends cause damage: the higher rates strongly discourage saving and investment, which hurts production and has an adverse feedback on tax collections. The model does not consider two other important channels. One is the realizations, or lock-in, effect: higher capital gains tax rates persuade investors to sell capital assets less frequently, which means fewer asset sales on which to assess capital gains tax and less flexibility in the allocation of capital. A corollary with dividends is smaller dividend payouts, with analogous damage to the economy and tax revenue. The other channel is the asset value effect. Because asset values are based on expected after-tax returns, a higher tax rate on capital gains and dividends depresses asset prices, causing future capital gains to be smaller than otherwise. If the model included these two additional pathways, Scenarios 1 and 2 would look even worse than they do now and the improvement from moving to Scenarios 3 and 4 would be greater still. Scenario No. 5: Eliminating Seven Tax Expenditures Without Rate Reductions; Harm Further Reduced by Retaining All Provisions Focused on Saving and Investing In addition to the tax rate cap on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends, three of the other provisions modeled in this study also affect capital. One is accelerated depreciation. The other two are the 8

Chart 7. Eliminating Selected Tax Expenditures, Effects on and GDP $750 $500 $250 $0 -$250 -$500 -$750 -$1,000 -$1,250 -$1,500 -$1,750 $574 Change, Static $347 $320 $179 Change, Dynamic 11 Large Tax Expenditures Excluding 4 Tax Expenditures Involving Saving and Investing GDP Change -$1,582 Box 3. Estimated Effects if the Following Seven "Tax Expenditures" were Eliminated from the Individual Income Tax The Seven Provisions State and local income tax deduction Exclusion for employer provided health insurance Earned income tax credit Education credits Child tax credit Partial income tax exclusion for social security retirement benefits Charitable deduction Economic And Budget Changes Versus 2013 Law (Dollar amounts in billions of 2012 dollars unless indicated otherwise) GDP, percent change -0.72% GDP, dollar change -$111.8 Private business GDP, percent change -0.77% Private business stocks, percent change -1.54% Wage rate, percent change -0.41% Private business hours of work, percent change -0.36% Full time equivalent jobs -364,000 Static federal revenue estimate, dollar change $347.4 Dynamic federal revenue estimate, dollar change $320.3 % Revenue reflow vs. static -7.8% Dollars of lost GDP per dollar of added federal revenue -$0.35 Weighted average service price (percent change) Corporate 0.75% Noncorporate 0.88% All business 0.79% Source: Tax Foundation calculations 9 -$112 mortgage interest deduction and the property tax deduction, where the type of capital is residential housing. We repeated the simulations leaving these four capitalrelated provisions as they are under current law. As seen in Chart 7, the elimination of the seven other tax expenditures produces a static revenue gain of $347 billion, which is 40 percent lower than in Scenario 1, where all eleven were ended. However, the drop in GDP, at $112 billion, is only 7 percent as severe as in Scenario 1. Because output suffers much less, the negative feedback on tax revenue is milder, with the result that the dynamic revenue estimate for eliminating the seven tax expenditures, $320 billion, is 75 percent larger than if all eleven were ended. Box 3 summarizes the findings for Scenario 5. Scenario No. 6: Trading Seven Large Tax Expenditures for Lower Rates If the estimated static revenue gain from eliminating the seven provisions is used for an across-the-board rate cut, individual income tax rates could be reduced 28.3 percent, a bit less than in the earlier cases. The 10 percent rate would drop to 7.2 percent, the 25 percent rate to 17.9 percent, and the 39.6 percent rate to 28.4 percent. Although this offset is not as breathtaking as the earlier ones, the economic results are much better. Instead of an estimated GDP loss of nearly $300 billion (Scenario 2, with eleven provisions ended) or essentially no change in GDP

Chart 8. Using the Static Revenue Gain from Eliminating Selected Tax Expenditures to Pay for an Across-The-Board Rate Cut $400 $300 $200 $100 $0 -$100 -$200 -$300 -$400 11 Large Tax Expenditures; 36.5% Rate Cut Excluding 4 Tax Expenditures Involving Saving and Investing; 28.3% Rate Cut $0 $0 $72 -$59 Change, Static Change, Dynamic -$299 $338 GDP Change (Scenario 4, with ten provisions ended), there would be an estimated gain of $338 billion. (See Chart 8.) Instead of an estimated dynamic revenue drop of $59 billion like in Scenario 2 or revenue neutrality like in Scenario 4, this more limited trade-off of a broader base for lower rates would add $72 billion to federal coffers on a dynamic basis. The dynamic simulation also estimates that before-tax wages would be essentially unchanged but after-tax wages would rise and that hours worked in the private sector would climb 2.2 percent (equivalent to 2.3 million full time jobs). Conclusion Pruning back tax expenditures could if done wisely pay for spectacular reductions in income tax rates and fuel economic growth. Care must be taken, though, to assess the merits of each provision individually rather than assuming that an item must be bad just because it is on the tax expenditure list. Exchanging some provisions for lower rates would be pro-growth and would be a move that pays for itself. However, with a number of other tax features notably those that affect the cost of capital dropping the items in return for lower rates would slow growth and collect much less revenue than a conventional revenue estimate would predict. Many so-called tax expenditures are not special favors to privileged groups but provisions that probably belong in the tax code because they soften tax biases that slow economic growth. In a conventional, or static, revenue estimate, which disregards growth effects, it appears that taking a machete to tax expenditures would produce a huge revenue gain and that the newly found money could readily finance radically lower income tax rates on a revenue neutral basis. A dynamic analysis that accounts for growth effects, however, tells a different story. This paper s look at repealing a collection of eleven large tax expenditures, as well as eleven earlier case studies that examined the provisions separately, highlights the value of the dynamic approach and the inadequacies of the conventional, static analysis. The Tax Foundation s Taxes and Growth Model predicts that the real-world consequences of indiscriminately slashing away at the tax expenditure list in return for lower rates would be less capital, less employment, lower incomes, reduced GDP, and less federal revenue. The rate cuts, even though enormous, do not guarantee a more prosperous economy. 10

The most damaging provisions to eliminate, according to the model, would be those that partially counteract income tax system penalties against saving and investment relative to immediate consumption. On the other hand, if one is careful which provisions are eliminated, the dynamic model predicts that base broadening could be traded successfully for lower rates and faster growth. 2013 Tax Foundation National Press Building 529 14th Street, N.W., Suite 420 Washington, DC 20045 202.464.6200 www.taxfoundation.org About the Tax Foundation The Tax Foundation is a 501(c)(3) non-partisan, non-profit research institution founded in 1937 to educate the public on tax policy. Based in Washington, D.C., our economic and policy analysis is guided by the principles of sound tax policy: simplicity, neutrality, transparency, and stability. 11