There is poverty convergence

Similar documents
Effect of income distribution on poverty reduction after the Millennium

Financing Constraints and Employment Evidence from Transition Countries. Dorothea Schäfer (DIW Berlin), Susan Steiner (LUH)

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through

CESEE DELEVERAGING AND CREDIT MONITOR 1

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

GROWTH PROSPECTS OF EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES IN EUROPE

ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE AND THE GLOBAL CRISIS OF : THE CASE OF BALTIC COUNTRIES AND UKRAINE

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

The Eternal Triangle of Growth, Inequality and Poverty Reduction

CESEE DELEVERAGING AND CREDIT MONITOR 1

CESEE DELEVERAGING AND CREDIT MONITOR 1

CESEE DELEVERAGING AND CREDIT MONITOR 1

Does Leverage Affect Company Growth in the Baltic Countries?

Appendix for Beazer, Quintin H. & Byungwon Woo IMF Conditionality, Government Partisanship, and the Progress of Economic Reforms

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Spain France. England Netherlands. Wales Ukraine. Republic of Ireland Czech Republic. Romania Albania. Serbia Israel. FYR Macedonia Latvia

Growth and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in the CEECs: Some reflections on the catching up process

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

Comparing pay trends in the public services and private sector. Labour Research Department 7 June 2018 Brussels

CSO Research Paper. Econometric analysis of the public/private sector pay differential

Accelerating Poverty Reduction in a Less Poor World

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Bank Competition and the Lending Channel in Transition Countries. Fariz Huseynov 1. Rustam Jamilov 2. Wei Zhang 1. First draft: October 2013

New data from the Enterprise Surveys indicate that senior managers in Georgian firms devote only 2 percent of

Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil.

Determinants of the flows of foreign direct investments from Western to Eastern European countries. By Tomas Stanay

Mark Allen. Market power in CEE banking sectors and the impact of the global financial crisis. Discussion of Paper by Efthyvoulou and Yildirim

Macroeconomic Policy, Output, and Employment: Is There Evidence of Jobless Growth?

The gains from variety in the European Union

BETA CONVERGENCE IN THE EXPORT VOLUMES IN EU COUNTRIES

Performance of EBRD Private Equity Funds Portfolio 2003 year end data

A causal relationship between foreign direct investment, economic growth and export for Central and Eastern Europe Zuzana Gallová 1

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

MIND THE CREDIT GAP. Spring 2015 Regional Economic Issues Report on Central, Eastern and Southeastern Europe (CESEE) recovery. repair.

Financial Fragmentation and Economic Growth in Europe

CONVERGENCE REVISITED: CASE OF EU AND EASTERN EUROPE

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

2. SAVING TRENDS IN TURKEY IN INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON

Riding the global growth wave. Richard Grieveson. Press conference, 13 March New wiiw forecast for Central, East and Southeast Europe,

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Index. B Belarus health-care system, 107 Budget-based financing, 11 Bulgaria, corporatised hospitals,

Pro-Poor Growth in Turkey

CHAPTER 2. POVERTY AND INEQUALITY TRENDS AND PROFILE

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Performance of EBRD Private Equity Funds Portfolio to 31 st December 2011

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

The World Bank. Asia (ECA) Economic Update. Annual Meetings Istanbul October 3, 2009

Growth prospects and challenges in EBRD countries of operation. Sergei Guriev Chief Economist

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

On Minimum Wage Determination

THE IMPORTANCE OF MEASUREMENT ERROR IN THE COST OF CAPITAL. Austan Goolsbee University of Chicago, GSB American Bar Foundation, and NBER

Testing the predictions of the Solow model:

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Universal Properties of Financial Markets as a Consequence of Traders Behavior: an Analytical Solution

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period

Themes Income and wages in Europe Wages, productivity and the wage share Working poverty and minimum wage The gender pay gap

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Day of the Week Effect of Stock Returns: Empirical Evidence from Bombay Stock Exchange

Real Convergence of Western Balkan Countries to European Union in view of Macroeconomic Policy Mix 1

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

Is There a Relationship between Company Profitability and Salary Level? A Pan-European Empirical Study

Sources of Capital Structure: Evidence from Transition Countries

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Chinese Firms Political Connection, Ownership, and Financing Constraints

Accelerating Poverty Reduction in a Less Poor World: The Roles of Growth and Inequality

FINANCEABILITY OF INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Are Devaluations Contractionary in Emerging Economies of Eastern Europe?

The Effect of Economic Policy Uncertainty in the US on the Stock Market Performance in Canada and Mexico

Comparative Analysis of Concentration in Insurance Markets in New EU Member States

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

Performance of Private Equity Funds in Central and Eastern Europe and the CIS Data to 31 December 2008

NPLs in Hungary. a regional perspective. Budapest, March 3, 2015

Testing for Convergence from the Micro-Level

The Impact of International Patent Systems: Evidence from Accession to the European Patent Convention. November 2017

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

Has private sector credit in CESEE approached levels justified by fundamentals? A post-crisis assessment

Performance of EBRD Private Equity Funds Portfolio Data to 31 st December EBRD 2011, all rights reserved

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Equity Funds Portfolio Update. Data as of June 2012

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Depreciation shocks and the bank lending activities in the EU countries

A NONLINEAR MODEL TO ESTIMATE THE LONG TERM CORRELATION BETWEEN MARKET CAPITALIZATION AND GDP PER CAPITA IN EASTERN EU COUNTRIES

h Edition Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries

Discussion of Banks Equity Capital Frictions, Capital Ratios, and Interest Rates: Evidence from Spanish Banks

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

HOUSEHOLDS LENDING MARKET IN THE ENLARGED EUROPE. Debora Revoltella and Fabio Mucci copyright with the author New Europe Research

Exploring differences in financial literacy across countries: the role of individual characteristics, experience, and institutions

Transcription:

There is poverty convergence Abstract Martin Ravallion ("Why Don't We See Poverty Convergence?" American Economic Review, 102(1): 504-23; 2012) presents evidence against the existence of convergence in global poverty rates despite convergence in household mean income levels and the close linkage between income growth and poverty reduction. We show that this finding is driven by a specification that demands more than simple convergence in poverty headcount rates, and is additionally driven by poorly measured low poverty incidences. If we motivate the poverty convergence equation using an arguably superior semi-elasticity specification, we find highly significant and robust evidence of convergence in absolute poverty headcount ratios and poverty gaps in the developing world. Keywords: poverty convergence, economic growth, poverty trap, transition economies JEL Classifications: I32, D31, P36

In a recent contribution, Martin Ravallion (2012) raised the question of why we do not see convergence in poverty rates across the developing world. The argument is that one would expect poverty headcount ratios to converge across countries since higher mean household income tends to lower poverty ( advantages of growth ) and mean household incomes tend to converge across countries ( advantages of backwardness ). 1 Using a sample of household income data that covers about 90 developing countries between 1977 and 2007 2 and focusing on the conventional poverty headcount ratio at $2/day, Ravallion (2012) finds evidence that both of these individual channels are at work, but that we do not observe convergence in poverty headcount ratios across countries. The econometric specification used to assess poverty convergence is given by ln H it = α i + β i ln H i,t 1 + ε it, (1) where H it is the (absolute) poverty rate of country i at time t and ε it term. is a disturbance This somewhat puzzling finding is explained in Ravallion (2012) by the adverse direct effect of poverty on economic growth and by the fact that a high initial poverty rate makes it harder to reduce poverty through growth in mean household income. Countries with low poverty rates have thus seen faster mean income growth and a higher elasticity of poverty reduction to mean income growth, given by η i in the specification 1 He empirically finds evidence for unconditional as well as conditional household income convergence, i.e. without and with control variables, with conditional convergence being quantitatively more rapid. 2 The poverty and income dataset is obtained from survey data available at povcal.net. It has a median interval between surveys of 13 years. About three quarters of household surveys use consumption instead of income data, as is common in the literature. See Ravallion (2012) for more details. -2-

ln H it = δ i + η i ln μ it + ν it, (2) where μ it denotes mean consumption (income) and ν it is the corresponding disturbance term. The parameter η i in equation (2) is usually referred to as the growth elasticity of poverty reduction. It is well-known from the seminal work of Bourguignon (2003) that this elasticity is a decreasing function of the development level of a country, i.e. it necessarily increases (in absolute terms) at lower initial levels of poverty under the assumption of log-normally distributed incomes and if income growth is distribution-neutral. 3 This increase per se has nothing to do with economic effects of poverty on income growth and convergence, which might certainly be at work, but is a mere identity reflecting the shape of the log-normal distribution and the associated fact that low initial poverty levels ceteris paribus lead to a high percentage reduction of poverty rates for a given growth rate. An additional problem associated with the use of the poverty elasticity of growth is its high sensitivity to low poverty incidence, when percentage changes are particularly large and influential. This can bias econometric results as measurement error is usually an important problem when low poverty incidence observations are present in the data. 4 Additionally, policymakers are usually interested in percentage point, not percentage changes of the poverty rate. As a result, Klasen and Misselhorn (2008) suggest to use a growth semi-elasticity of poverty reduction instead, based on the specification H it = δ i + η i ln μ it + ν it. (3) 3 For empirical evidence that the income share of lower-income deciles does not systematically vary among countries with different growth rates, see Dollar and Kraay (2002) and Dollar et al. (2016). 4 Even rounding issues introduce substantial measurement error at low levels of poverty incidence. For example, if poverty incidence fell from 4.4 to 1.6%, this is a decline of 64%. If rounded to 4 and 2% it is a decline of 50%. Similar rounding errors are much smaller at higher levels of poverty incidence. When using percentage point changes, such rounding errors introduce the same bias at all levels of poverty. -3-

The difference in results between specifications linking growth and poverty reduction is depicted in Figures 1 and 2, with an R squared of 37.7% and 51.5% for the elasticity and semi-elasticity, respectively. If we assume poverty dynamics given by equation (3) within the conceptual framework of Ravallion (2012), we obtain the poverty convergence equation H it = α i + β i H i,t 1 + ε it, (4) instead of Ravallion s (2012) log-specification in equation (1). Also note that β* < 0 in equation (4) is sufficient for poverty to converge, as countries with higher initial poverty rates would see faster percentage point reductions of poverty rates. Ravallion s equation (1) demands a much stronger concept of convergence, as it requires that a country should be more likely to reduce poverty from 60 to 30% than from, say, 4 to 2%, as both would imply a 50 percent reduction of the poverty rate. Figure 1: Poverty elasticity of growth Figure 2: Poverty semi-elasticity of growth -.3 -.2 -.1.1.2 10 0 Albania Russia Estonia Moldavia Lithuania Romania Ukraine Macedonia Latvia Belarus Poland -.2 -.1 0.1.2 Annualized growth in mean income -5 0 5 Bulgaria Slovakia Bosnia Czech Albania Slovenia and Lithuania Republic Estonia Herzegovina CroatiaHungary Macedonia Russia Belarus Latvia Moldavia Ukraine RomaniaPoland -.2 -.1 0.1.2 Annualized growth in mean income Estimating equation (4) making use of the data in Ravallion (2012) reveals highly significant convergence dynamics in poverty headcount rates, as illustrated in column 2 of Table 1 (as a comparison, column 1 in Table 1 shows the results of the original specification in Ravallion, 2012). This finding is robust to alternative -4-

measures of poverty such as the poverty gap and even for the headcount ratio at the lower $1.25/day line, where the problem of initially low and imprecisely measured poverty rates is more severe. 5 Table 1: Main results (1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Δln(H $2) Δ(H $2) Δ(H $1.25) Δ(PG $2) Note: Ravallion Semi-elasticity Semi-elasticity Semi-elasticity (2012) Headcount $2 Headcount $1.25 Poverty gap 2$ Log initial poverty 0.00590 ln(h i,t-1) (0.0100) Initial poverty -0.0163*** -0.0268*** -0.0295*** H i,t-1 (0.00368) (0.00474) (0.00459) Constant -0.0400 0.384* 0.366* 0.298** (0.0409) (0.206) (0.215) (0.138) Observations 89 89 89 89 R-squared 0.008 0.112 0.206 0.261 Notes: The initial poverty measure in columns (2)-(4) is the respective initial level corresponding to the dependent variable (i.e. the initial headcount at $2/day, at $1.25/day, and the initial poverty gap at $2/day, respectively). OLS results, heteroscedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Figure 1 further highlights that practically all of the most severe outliers for the growth elasticity of poverty reduction regression are Central and Eastern European (CEE) transition economies. 6 For these countries Ravallion (2012: 509) states that their experience is clearly not typical of the developing world. As shown in 5 Table A.1 in the appendix shows that these results are also robust to the inclusion of the control variables proposed by Ravallion (2012). 6 The 11 Central and Eastern European countries in the sample, with their corresponding time spans, are Poland (1996-2005), Ukraine (1996-2005), Belarus (2000-2005), Latvia (1998-2004), Romania (1998-2005), Russia (1993-2005), Albania (1996/97-2005), Estonia (1995-2004), Lithuania (1996-2004), Moldavia (1997-2004), and Macedonia (1998-2003). -5-

columns (1) and (2) of Table 2 and in Figure 3 (dashed line), dropping these observations or accounting for their special dynamics with a dummy variable is sufficient to obtain statistically significant poverty convergence even in the demanding log-specification (1) used by Ravallion (2012). 7 This result is robust to alternative measures of poverty (poverty gap at $2/day and the headcount ratio at $1.25/day) and to the inclusion of control variables proposed by Ravallion (2012). 8 A detailed analysis of this finding poses more challenging data requirements and is beyond the scope of this note, whose focus is to show that poverty convergence only requires the specification of a growth semi-elasticity of poverty reduction and that under this specification poverty convergence is indeed present in the developing world. Our results, however, highlight several aspects that need to be taken into account when addressing global poverty dynamics. First, CEE transition economies had historically low poverty rates, so even small percentage point changes will be reflected in relatively high percent changes in the log specification and get a very high leverage in the corresponding least-squares regression. Figure 3 reflects this, as low poverty is the exception among developing countries, so the CEE observations are far off the sample mean. This might also explain the many outliers in Figure 1 and might point to measurement error in the case of economies with low poverty incidence. 9 Second, the fact that we do not have to control for the particular dynamics of poverty in CEE countries in our alternative specification in order to obtain evidence of convergence reflects the fact that the semi-elasticity 7 In particular, it is sufficient to take out the observations of Poland, Ukraine, Belarus, and Latvia, which are the most outlying points, to obtain poverty convergence at the 5 percent level of statistical significance. Excluding Romania and Russia in addition leads to poverty convergence at the 1 percent significance level (results not reported but available on request). Furthermore, it is worth mentioning that there are no significantly different convergence dynamics within the CEE group, as indicated by a statistically insignificant CEE-specific convergence parameter (results not reported but available on request). 8 See Table A.2 in the Appendix. 9 The mean initial poverty headcount in the CEE subsample is 5.6%, compared to 30.6% in the overall sample of Ravallion (2012). -6-

approach proposed by Klasen and Misselhorn (2008) is less susceptible to (sometimes arbitrary or poorly measured) developments at the very left tail of the income distribution. Third, however, there seem to be CEE-specific dynamics that cannot be fully explained by the analytical implications of the growth elasticity of poverty reduction as derived by Bourguignon (2003). Accordingly, the CEE dummy variable stays statistically significant in our specification of (absolute) poverty convergence (column (3) of Table 2), 10 without changing the overall results much (see Figure 4). Fourth, the two most promising channels to explain the specific CEE dynamics appear to be cyclical reversion effects for the mean income growth rate 11 and unique distributional effects that influence the growth elasticity of poverty reduction. 12 10 It seems also worth noticing in this context that dropping the 5 or 10 percent of Ravallion s (2012) sample that had the lowest initial poverty incidence, as is usual in many empirical assessments of the growth elasticity, does not lead to observing poverty convergence in the sense of equation (1). 11 Prior to the sample period, CEE transition economies suffered severe shocks to their output level. Most neoclassical convergence models suggest that such countries, which are far off their steady state, should see higher subsequent growth ( cyclical reversion ). Indeed, CEE countries saw significantly higher mean income growth rates than implied by a simple mean income convergence regression (results are available upon request). 12 Inequality levels increased substantially during the initial output collapse in transition economies, with a positive relationship between the size of the output collapse and the increase in inequality (see Ivashenko, 2003; Grün and Klasen, 2001). In subsequent years (which are those included in the sample) there was some decline of inequality in countries like Russia, Ukraine, and Belarus, moderating the massive inequality shock experienced earlier. As a result, the unconditional poverty elasticity of growth was larger in those countries, due to this decline in inequality, confirmed in Figure 1. -7-

Table 2: Transition economies results (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES Δln(H $2) Δln(H $2) Δ(H $2) Elasticity Elasticity Semi-elasticity Headcount $2 Headcount $2 Headcount $2 w/o CEE w/ CEE dummy w/ CEE dummy Log initial poverty -0.0228*** -0.0220*** ln(h i,t-1) (0.00463) (0.00631) Initial poverty -0.0208*** H i,t-1 (0.00413) CEE dummy -0.178*** -1.049*** (0.0421) (0.266) Constant 0.0803*** 0.0771*** 0.731*** (0.0195) (0.0249) (0.267) Observations 78 89 89 R-squared 0.230 0.420 0.148 Notes: OLS results, heteroscedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Figure 3: Log poverty convergence Figure 4: Absolute poverty convergence.1.2 10 Albania -.3 -.2 -.1 0 Estonia Macedonia Lithuania Belarus Latvia Russia Romania Ukraine Poland Moldavia -5 0 5 Bulgaria Czech Croatia Slovakia Slovenia Bosnia Estonia Albania Belarus Lithuania Macedonia Republic and Herzegovina Latvia Russia Ukraine Romania Poland Moldavia 0 1 2 3 4 5 Log initial poverty rate ($2/day) 0 20 40 60 80 10 Initial poverty rate ($2/day) overall sample of Ravallion withouth CEE overall sample of Ravallion withouth CEE -8-

Do our findings imply that the argument in Ravallion (2012) about the adverse effect of high initial poverty on growth and on poverty reduction through growth in mean income are mistaken? On the one hand, despite finding robust poverty convergence, we still confirm the finding in Ravallion (2012) that countries with higher initial poverty see lower mean income growth rates 13 and experience a lower growth elasticity of poverty reduction after controlling for CEE-specific poverty dynamics (see columns (1)-(3) of appendix Table A.3). On the other hand, this is purely driven by the log specification of the dependent variable, as the growth semielasticity of poverty reduction is no longer dependent on the interaction with the initial poverty level, which is far from being statistically significant in either levels or logs. 14 This suggests that there is not necessarily a relevant economic effect of initial poverty slowing down subsequent poverty reduction but that it is by definition more difficult to obtain higher percent reductions in poverty rates at higher initial poverty levels, as shown by Bourguignon (2003). However, either specification suggests that poverty reduction strategies that are based exclusively on growth will only see very limited and slow effects on poverty reduction in countries where poverty is the most pressing problem. In the log specification, the significant interaction term implies that the positive effect between growth and poverty reduction practically vanishes for the majority of developing countries which face high initial poverty rates (see Figure 5 in the Appendix). In the semi-elasticity specification, this results from the implied economic magnitudes: based on Table 1, column (2), assuming a country with a poverty headcount index (at $2 a day) of 41.1 percent (which is the mean at the final period of the sample) would imply an annual poverty reduction of 0.29 percentage 13 The negative effect of initial log poverty decreases from -0.02 (significant at the 1% level, Ravallion, 2012: Table 2, model 1) to -0.01 (significant at the 10% level) when including the CEE dummy. It is also significant (at the 10 % level) when it enters as the absolute headcount index (instead of logs). Results are available on request. 14 See columns (4)&(5) of Table A.3 in the Appendix. -9-

points, which is rather low and implies that reaching the international target of eliminating poverty by 2030 is unlikely. Of course, higher growth can make a difference. Based on column (6) in appendix Table A.3, moving from the average sample mean income growth rate of 1.3 % p.a. to the 75th percentile of 3.5 % p.a. would increase the annual percentage point reduction of poverty from 0.31 to 0.88 percentage points still certainly too low for most developing countries to reduce poverty fast enough. 15 Clearly, higher poverty reduction can only be achieved if inequality is also reduced which, as shown by Bourguignon (2003) and Klasen and Misselhorn (2008), not only reduces poverty directly, but also increases the elasticity (and semi-elasticity) of growth to poverty reduction and might even, following Deininger and Squire (1998), increase growth. 15 Similar quantitative impacts apply to the $1.25 poverty line, which is the measure that was originally targeted. -10-

References Bourguignon, Francois (2003): The growth elasticity of poverty reduction: Explaining heterogeneity across countries and time periods. In: Eicher, Theo S. and Stephen J. Turnovsky (eds.) Inequality and Growth: Theory and policy implications. Cambridge: MIT Press. pp 3-26 Deininger, Klaus and Lyn Squire (1998): New ways of looking at old issues: inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics 57(2): 259-287 Dollar, David and Aart Kraay (2002): Growth is good for the poor. Journal of Economic Growth 7(3): 195-225 Dollar, David, Tatjana Kleineberg, and Aart Kraay (2016): Growth Still Is Good for the Poor. European Economic Review 81(1): 68-85. Gruen, Carola and Stephan Klasen (2001): Growth, income distribution and well-being in transition countries Economics of Transition, 9(2): 359-394. Iveshenko, Oleksiy (2003): Growth and Inequality: Evidence from Transition Economies. In: Eicher, Theo S. and Stephen J. Turnovsky (eds.) Inequality and Growth: Theory and policy implications. Cambridge: MIT Press. pp 155-194 Klasen, Stephan and Mark Misselhorn (2008): Determinants of the growth semi-elasticity of poverty reduction. Ibero-America Institute for Economic Research Discussion Paper 176. Milanovic, Branko (1996): Income, inequality and poverty during the transition: A survey of the evidence. Economic Policy in Transitional Economies, 6(1): 131-147. Ravallion, Martin (2012): Why don t we see poverty convergence? American Economic Review, 102(1): 504-523. -11-

Appendix Table A.1: Robustness of semi-elasticity specification to control variables (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES Δ(H $2) Δ(H $1.25) Δ(PG $2) Note: Semi-elasticity Semi-elasticity Semi-elasticity Headcount $2 Headcount $1.25 Poverty gap 2$ Initial poverty -0.0330*** -0.0396*** -0.0427*** H i,t-1 (0.00660) (0.00496) (0.00493) Log primary -0.409 0.132 0.0686 schooling (0.410) (0.309) (0.227) Log life expectancy -4.178** -3.618** -2.493** (1.793) (1.416) (1.043) Log relative price of 0.477** 0.574** 0.440** investment goods (0.199) (0.227) (0.169) Constant 18.03** 12.49** 8.603* (7.881) (5.951) (4.355) Observations 88 88 88 R-squared 0.371 0.451 0.497 Notes: The table is equivalent to columns (2)-(4) of table 1 but includes the control variables proposed by Ravallion (2012). OLS results, heteroscedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1-12-

Table A.2: Robustness of log poverty convergence specification with CEE dummy (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES Δln(H $2) Δln(H $1.25) Δln(PG $2) Note: $2 a day (headcount) $1.25 a day (headcount) Poverty gap ($2 a day) Log initial poverty -0.0312*** -0.0211* -0.0247*** ln(h i,t-1) (0.00960) (0.0112) (0.00516) CEE dummy -0.173*** -0.184*** -0.184*** (0.0440) (0.0671) (0.0392) Log primary schooling -0.0280 (0.0171) Log life expectancy -0.0734 (0.0613) Log relative price of 0.0107 investment goods (0.0109) Constant 0.488* 0.0484 0.0577*** (0.293) (0.0411) (0.0181) Observations 88 82 89 R-squared 0.486 0.188 0.361 Notes: The log initial poverty measure is the respective initial level corresponding to the dependent variable (i.e. the initial log headcount at $2/day, at $1.25/day, and the log initial poverty gap at $2/day, respectively). OLS results, heteroscedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1-13-

Table A.3: Effects of initial poverty on the poverty (semi-)elasticity of growth VARIABLES (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) % poverty % poverty % poverty % point % point % point change change change poverty change poverty change poverty change Log(initial poverty) -0.00529-0.0137*** -0.0130*** -0.24049 (0.00498) (0.00417) (0.00432) (0.18309) Initial poverty -0.00942-0.0112** (0.00679) (0.00430) Mean income growth -2.587*** -2.103*** -2.905*** -34.96*** -18.20-25.59*** (0.366) (0.342) (0.690) (9.747) (14.94) (7.423) Initial poverty 0.0281*** 0.0222*** 0.136 Mean income growth (0.00479) (0.00450) (0.210) Log(initial poverty) 0.563*** -2.448 Mean income growth (0.170) (5.635) CEE dummy -0.0694** -0.0673 0.853* 0.1637 (0.0347) (0.0408) (0.492) (0.374) Constant 0.00869 0.0445*** 0.0443*** 0.302 0.773 0.483*** (0.0204) (0.0161) (0.0164) (0.192) (0.470) (0.156) Observations 89 89 89 89 89 89 R-squared 0.680 0.721 0.675 0.585 0.573 0.566 Notes: Poverty is measured as the $2/day headcount ratio. Column (1) reproduces Ravallion (2012: Table 4, specification 1). Column (2) uses the same specification with the CEE dummy. Column (3) estimates the same model in a full logspecification, with the results used to obtain the parameters in Figure 6. Columns (4)-(6) show these estimates for absolute poverty levels and changes. As the CEE dummy in column (4) is only significant when the (insignificant) interaction term is included, we drop both in specification (6). OLS results, heteroscedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1-14-

Figure 5: Growth elasticity of poverty reduction by initial poverty level Note: Figure 6 displays the implied effect through the interaction between log initial poverty and mean income growth on log changes in poverty as estimated in Appendix Table A.3, specification (3) -15-