THE PEARSON SERIES IN ECONOMICS

Similar documents
The Pearson Series in Economics

THE PEARSON SERIES IN ECONOMICS

Principles of Macroeconomics

THE PEARSON SERIES IN ECONOMICS

The Pearson Series in Economics

Exercise Sheet 3: Short solutions.

Chapter 5. The Standard Trade Model. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Endowment differences: The Heckscher-Ohlin model

Chapter 6. The Standard Trade Model

Preview. Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Economics 181: International Trade Midterm Solutions

3. Trade and Development

MTA-ECON3901 Fall 2009 Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson or Model

This is The Heckscher-Ohlin (Factor Proportions) Model, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Trade (index.html) (v. 1.0).

14.54 International Trade Lecture 13: Heckscher-Ohlin Model of Trade (I)

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Lecture 12 International Trade. Noah Williams

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

Ricardian Model part 1

Chapter 4. Comparative Advantage and Factor Endowments. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

International Trade Glossary of terms

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions:

1/25/2011. Introduction to International Trade. Basic Theory of Trade

Econ 355: International Economics. Econ 355: International Economics. Econ 355: International Economics

Introduction. Countries engage in international trade for two basic reasons:

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher- Ohlin Model

Specific factors and Income Distribution

Introduction to Microeconomics

GLOBAL EDITION. Hubbard O Brien. Economics SIXTH EDITION. R. Glenn Hubbard Anthony Patrick O Brien

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

International Trade in Goods and Assets. 1. The economic activity of a small, open economy can affect the world prices.

Lesson 11: Specific-Factors Model (continued)

Examiners commentaries 2011

This is Factor Mobility and Income Redistribution, chapter 4 from the book Policy and Theory of International Economics (index.html) (v. 1.0).

14.54 International Trade Lecture 14: Heckscher-Ohlin Model of Trade (II)

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

Mathematical Economics

ECO101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS Notes. Consumer Behaviour. U tility fro m c o n s u m in g B ig M a c s

I. Basic Concepts of Input Markets

Chapter 3 Why Everybody Trades: Comparative Advantage

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Business Cycles II: Theories

Chapter 6. Production. Introduction. Production Decisions of a Firm. Production Decisions of a Firm

PubPol/Econ 541. Behind the Standard Model. Essential Features of Ricardian and Heckscher-Ohlin Models

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Macroeconomcs. Factors of production. Outline of model. In this chapter you will learn:

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

CHAPTER 2 *(Core Chapter) THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

Econ 633/733: Advanced Microeconomics Final Exam, Autumn 2004 Professor Kosteas

ECON Micro Foundations

Managerial Economics in a Global Economy 5/6 Edition

Heckscher Ohlin Model

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

File: ch03, Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility

ECON* International Trade Winter 2011 Instructor: Patrick Martin

3 General Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THEORY AND POLICY

MIDTERM Version A Wednesday, February 15, 2006 Multiple choice - each worth 3 points

Paul Krugman and Robin Wells. Microeconomics. Third Edition. Chapter 2 Economic Models: Trade-offs and Trade. Copyright 2013 by Worth Publishers

Lecture 19 Monday, Oct. 26. Lecture. 1 Indifference Curves: Perfect Substitutes. 1. Problem Set 2 due tomorrow night.

International Trade: Economics and Policy. LECTURE 5: Absolute vs. Comparative Advantages

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Consumption, Saving, and Investment. Chapter 4. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Substitution in Markusen s Classic Trade and Factor Movement Complementarity Models* Maurice Schiff World Bank and IZA

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Specific Factors Model (2/1/2012) Econ

Factor Endowments. Ricardian model insu cient for understanding objections to free trade.

Problem Set #1. 1) CD s cost $12 each and video rentals are $4 each. (This is a standard budget constraint.)

MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition ECON 322 INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMIC THEORY

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Budget Constraint Coffee ($2/cup)

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From And Where It Goes

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Reading map : Structure of the market Measurement problems. It may simply reflect the profitability of the industry

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Spring Semester

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Macroeconomics Review Course LECTURE NOTES

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

1.6 Dynamics of Asset Prices*

Econ 100B: Macroeconomic Analysis Fall 2008

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module I

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Answers (if you think you see an error, please contact me ASAP.

Midterm Exam International Trade Economics 6903, Fall 2008 Donald Davis

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Principles of Macroeconomics. Twelfth Edition. Chapter 13. The Labor Market in the Macroeconomy. Copyright 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

14.54 International Trade Lecture 8: Ricardian Trade Model

ECON 442: Quantitative Trade Models. Jack Rossbach

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Transcription:

THE PEARSON SERIES IN ECONOMICS Abel/Bernanke/Croushore Acemoglu/Laibson/List Bade/Parkin Foundations of Berck/Helfand The Economics of the Environment Bierman/Fernandez Game Theory with Economic Applications Blanchard Boyer Principles of Transportation Economics Branson Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Bruce Public Finance and the American Economy Carlton/Perloff Modern Industrial Organization Case/Fair/Oster Principles of Chapman Environmental Economics: Theory, Application, and Policy Daniels/VanHoose International Monetary & Financial Economics Downs An Economic Theory of Democracy Farnham Economics for Managers Froyen Macroeconomics: Theories and Policies Fusfeld The Age of the Economist Gerber International Gordon Greene Econometric Analysis Gregory/Stuart Russian and Soviet Economic Performance and Structure Hartwick/Olewiler The Economics of Natural Resource Use Heilbroner/Milberg The Making of the Economic Society Heyne/Boettke/Prychitko The Economic Way of Thinking Hubbard/O Brien InEcon Money, Banking, and the Financial System* Hubbard/O Brien/Rafferty Hughes/Cain American Economic History Husted/Melvin International Economics Jehle/Reny Advanced Microeconomic Theory Keat/Young/Erfle Managerial Economics Klein Mathematical Methods for Economics Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy* Laidler The Demand for Money Lynn Economic Development: Theory and Practice for a Divided World Miller Economics Today* Miller/Benjamin The Economics of Macro Issues Miller/Benjamin/North The Economics of Public Issues Mishkin The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets* The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets, Business School Edition* Macroeconomics: Policy and Practice* Murray Econometrics: A Modern Introduction O Sullivan/Sheffrin/Perez Economics: Principles, Applications and Tools* Parkin Perloff Microeconomics* Microeconomics: Theory and Applications with Calculus* Perloff/Brander Managerial Economics and Strategy* Pindyck/Rubinfeld Microeconomics* Riddell/Shackelford/Stamos/ Schneider Economics: A Tool for Critically Understanding Society Roberts The Choice: A Fable of Free Trade and Protection Scherer Industry Structure, Strategy, and Public Policy Schiller The Economics of Poverty and Discrimination Sherman Market Regulation Stock/Watson Introduction to Econometrics Studenmund A Practical Guide to Using Econometrics Todaro/Smith Economic Development Walters/Walters/Appel/ Callahan/Centanni/Maex/ O Neill Econversations: Today s Students Discuss Today s Issues Williamson Macroeconomics *denotes availability of Pearson MyLab Economics titles denotes availability of Global Edition titles Log onto www.myeconlab.com to learn more.

110 PART ONE International Trade Theory even in the long run. We discuss the extent to which trade may be contributing to increases in wage inequality in developed countries. We then conclude with a further review of the empirical evidence for (and against) the predictions of the factor-proportions theory of trade. LEARNING GOALS After reading this chapter, you will be able to: Explain how differences in resources generate a specific pattern of trade. Discuss why the gains from trade will not be equally spread even in the long run and identify the likely winners and losers. Understand the possible links between increased trade and rising wage inequality in the developed world. See how empirical patterns of trade and factor prices support some (but not all) of the predictions of the factor-proportions theory. Model of a Two-Factor Economy In this chapter, we ll focus on the simplest version of the factor-proportions model, sometimes referred to as 2 by 2 by 2 : two countries, two goods, two factors of production. In our example, we ll call the two countries Home and Foreign. We will stick with the same two goods, cloth (measured in yards) and food (measured in calories), that we used in the specific factors model of Chapter 4. The key difference is that in this chapter, we assume that the immobile factors that were specific to each sector (capital in cloth, land in food) are now mobile in the long run. Thus, land used for farming can be used to build a textile plant; conversely, the capital used to pay for a power loom can be used to pay for a tractor. To keep things simple, we model a single additional factor that we call capital, which is used in conjunction with labor to produce either cloth or food. In the long run, both capital and labor can move across sectors, thus equalizing their returns (rental rate and wage) in both sectors. Prices and Production Both cloth and food are produced using capital and labor. The amount of each good produced, given how much capital and labor are employed in each sector, is determined by a production function for each good: Q C = Q C (K C, L C ), Q F = Q F (K F, L F ), where Q C and Q F are the output levels of cloth and food, K C and L C are the amounts of capital and labor employed in cloth production, and K F and L F are the amounts of capital and labor employed in food production. Overall, the economy has a fixed supply of capital K and labor L that is divided between employment in the two sectors. We define the following expressions that are related to the two production technologies: a KC = capital used to produce one yard of cloth a LC = labor used to produce one yard of cloth a KF = capital used to produce one calorie of food a LF = labor used to produce one calorie of food

CHAPTER 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model 111 These unit input requirements are very similar to the ones defined in the Ricardian model (for labor only). However, there is one crucial difference: In these definitions, we speak of the quantity of capital or labor used to produce a given amount of cloth or food, rather than the quantity required to produce that amount. The reason for this change from the Ricardian model is that when there are two factors of production, there may be some room for choice in the use of inputs. In general, those choices will depend on the factor prices for labor and capital. However, let s first look at a special case in which there is only one way to produce each good. Consider the following numerical example: Production of one yard of cloth requires a combination of two work-hours and two machine-hours. The production of food is more automated; as a result, production of one calorie of food requires only one work-hour along with three machine-hours. Thus, all the unit input requirements are fixed at a KC = 2; a LC = 2; a KF = 3; a LF = 1; and there is no possibility of substituting labor for capital or vice versa. Assume that an economy is endowed with 3,000 units of machine-hours along with 2,000 units of work-hours. In this special case of no factor substitution in production, the economy s production possibility frontier can be derived using those two resource constraints for capital and labor. Production of Q C yards of cloth requires 2Q C = a KC * Q C machine-hours and 2Q C = a LC * Q C work-hours. Similarly, production of Q F calories of food requires 3Q F = a KF * Q F machine-hours and 1Q F = a LF * Q F work-hours. The total machine-hours used for both cloth and food production cannot exceed the total supply of capital: a KC * Q C + a KF * Q F K or 2Q C + 3Q F 3,000. (5-1) This is the resource constraint for capital. Similarly, the resource constraint for labor states that the total work-hours used in production cannot exceed the total supply of labor: a LC * Q C + a LF * Q F L or 2Q C + Q F 2,000. (5-2) Figure 5-1 shows the implications of (5-1) and (5-2) for the production possibilities in our numerical example. Each resource constraint is drawn in the same way we drew the production possibility line for the Ricardian case in Figure 3-1. In this case, however, the economy must produce subject to both constraints, so the production possibility frontier is the kinked line shown in red. If the economy specializes in food production (point 1), then it can produce 1,000 calories of food. At that production point, there is spare labor capacity: Only 1,000 work-hours out of 2,000 are employed. Conversely, if the economy specializes in cloth production (point 2), then it can produce 1,000 yards of cloth. At that production point, there is spare capital capacity: Only 2,000 machine-hours out of 3,000 are employed. At production point 3, the economy is employing all of its labor and capital resources (1,500 machine-hours and 1,500 work-hours in cloth production, and 1,500 machine-hours along with 500 work-hours in food production). 1 The important feature of this production possibility frontier is that the opportunity cost of producing an extra yard of cloth in terms of food is not constant. When the economy is producing mostly food (to the left of point 3), then there is spare labor capacity. Producing two fewer units of food releases six machine-hours that can be 1 The case of no factor substitution is a special one in which there is only a single production point that fully employs both factors; some factors are left unemployed at all the other production points on the production possibilities frontier. In the more general case below with factor substitution, this peculiarity disappears, and both factors are fully employed along the entire production possibility frontier.

112 PART ONE International Trade Theory Quantity of food, Q F 2,000 Labor constraint slope = 2 1,000 1 Production possibility frontier: slope = opportunity cost of cloth in terms of food 500 3 Capital constraint slope = 2/3 750 2 1,000 1,500 Quantity of cloth, Q C FIGURE 5-1 The Production Possibility Frontier without Factor Substitution: Numerical Example If capital cannot be substituted for labor or vice versa, the production possibility frontier in the factor-proportions model would be defined by two resource constraints: The economy can t use more than the available supply of labor (2,000 work-hours) or capital (3,000 machine-hours). So the production possibility frontier is defined by the red line in this figure. At point 1, the economy specializes in food production, and not all available work-hours are employed. At point 2, the economy specializes in cloth, and not all available machine-hours are employed. At production point 3, the economy employs all of its labor and capital resources. The important feature of the production possibility frontier is that the opportunity cost of cloth in terms of food isn t constant: It rises from 2 3 to 2 when the economy s mix of production shifts toward cloth. used to produce three yards of cloth: The opportunity cost of cloth is 2 3. When the economy is producing mostly cloth (to the right of point 3), then there is spare capital capacity. Producing two fewer units of food releases two work-hours that can be used to produce one yard of cloth: The opportunity cost of cloth is 2. Thus, the opportunity cost of cloth is higher when more units of cloth are being produced. Now let s make the model more realistic and allow the possibility of substituting capital for labor and vice versa in production. This substitution removes the kink in the production possibility frontier; instead, the frontier PP has the bowed shape shown in Figure 5-2. The bowed shape tells us that the opportunity cost in terms of food of producing one more unit of cloth rises as the economy produces more cloth and less food. That is, our basic insight about how opportunity costs change with the mix of production remains valid. Where on the production possibility frontier does the economy produce? It depends on prices. Specifically, the economy produces at the point that maximizes the

CHAPTER 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model 113 Quantity of food, Q F PP Quantity of cloth, Q C FIGURE 5-2 The Production Possibility Frontier with Factor Substitution If capital can be substituted for labor and vice versa, the production possibility frontier no longer has a kink. But it remains true that the opportunity cost of cloth in terms of food rises as the economy s production mix shifts toward cloth and away from food. value of production. Figure 5-3 shows what this implies. The value of the economy s production is V = P C * Q C + P F * Q F, where P C and P F are the prices of cloth and food, respectively. An isovalue line a line along which the value of output is constant has a slope of -P C >P F. The economy produces at the point Q, the point on the production possibility frontier that touches the highest possible isovalue line. At that point, the slope of the production possibility frontier is equal to -P C >P F. So the opportunity cost in terms of food of producing another unit of cloth is equal to the relative price of cloth. Choosing the Mix of Inputs As we have noted, in a two-factor model producers may have room for choice in the use of inputs. A farmer, for example, can choose between using relatively more mechanized equipment (capital) and fewer workers, or vice versa. Thus, the farmer can choose how much labor and capital to use per unit of output produced. In each sector, then, producers will face not fixed input requirements (as in the Ricardian model) but trade-offs like the one illustrated by curve II in Figure 5-4, which shows alternative input combinations that can be used to produce one calorie of food. What input choice will producers actually make? It depends on the relative costs of capital and labor. If capital rental rates are high and wages low, farmers will choose to produce using relatively little capital and a lot of labor; on the other hand, if the

114 PART ONE International Trade Theory Quantity of food, Q F Isovalue lines Q PP slope = P C /P F Quantity of cloth, Q C FIGURE 5-3 Prices and Production The economy produces at the point that maximizes the value of production given the prices it faces; this is the point on the highest possible isovalue line. At that point, the opportunity cost of cloth in terms of food is equal to the relative price of cloth, P C >P F. FIGURE 5-4 Input Possibilities in Food Production A farmer can produce a calorie of food with less capital if he or she uses more labor, and vice versa. Capital input per calorie, a KF Input combinations that produce one calorie of food II Labor input per calorie, a LF