Some Formulas neglected in Anderson, Sweeny, and Williams, with a Digression on Statistics and Finance

Similar documents
Consumer Optimization Fundamentals

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Lecture Notes 1 Part B: Functions and Graphs of Functions

Chapter 4. Consumer Choice. A Consumer s Budget Constraint. Consumer Choice

GRAPHS IN ECONOMICS. Appendix. Key Concepts. A Positive Relationship

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Homework 3 Solutions

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

QR43, Introduction to Investments Class Notes, Fall 2003 IV. Portfolio Choice

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Quiz #3, Answers

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering

Money & Capital Markets Fall 2011 Homework #1 Due: Friday, Sept. 9 th. Answer Key

Characterization of the Optimum

3/24/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 12: Perfect Competition 2: Cost Minimization. The Story So Far. Today. The Case of One Input

Problem Set 2 Solutions

18-660: Numerical Methods for Engineering Design and Optimization

Session 8: The Markowitz problem p. 1

Business Statistics 41000: Homework # 2

Statistics for Business and Economics

Properties of Demand Functions. Chapter Six. Own-Price Changes Fixed p 2 and y. Own-Price Changes. Demand

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

CHAPTER 6: PORTFOLIO SELECTION

Mean-Variance Analysis

FINC 430 TA Session 7 Risk and Return Solutions. Marco Sammon

5 Profit maximization, Supply

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A

Analytical Problem Set

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Solutions to questions in Chapter 8 except those in PS4. The minimum-variance portfolio is found by applying the formula:

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Stats CH 6 Intro Activity 1

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Learning Objectives for Ch. 5

Lesson 6: Extensions and applications of consumer theory. 6.1 The approach of revealed preference

Economic Markets. The Theory of Consumer Behavior

Topics covered. ECON6021 Microeconomic Analysis. Convex Combination. Bundle of goods

Handout 4: Gains from Diversification for 2 Risky Assets Corporate Finance, Sections 001 and 002

Answer keys for PS 3

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS

Mean-Variance Portfolio Theory

Portfolio Management

Expenditure minimization

Duality & The Dual Simplex Method & Sensitivity Analysis for Linear Programming. Metodos Cuantitativos M. En C. Eduardo Bustos Farias 1

FINC3017: Investment and Portfolio Management

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is:

ECONOMICS 422 MIDTERM EXAM 1 R. W. Parks Autumn (25) Josephine lives in a two period Fisherian world. Her utility function for 2

This assignment is due on Tuesday, September 15, at the beginning of class (or sooner).

MATH362 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance. Topic 1 Mean variance portfolio theory. 1.1 Mean and variance of portfolio return

CHAPTER 1: What is Economics? Summary. Def. Scarcity

P s =(0,W 0 R) safe; P r =(W 0 σ,w 0 µ) risky; Beyond P r possible if leveraged borrowing OK Objective function Mean a (Std.Dev.

MATH4512 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance. Topic Two Mean variance portfolio theory. 2.1 Mean and variance of portfolio return

General Notation. Return and Risk: The Capital Asset Pricing Model

Introduction to Computational Finance and Financial Econometrics Introduction to Portfolio Theory

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Lecture 2 Basic Tools for Portfolio Analysis

Business Statistics 41000: Probability 3

Lecture 3: Return vs Risk: Mean-Variance Analysis

Portfolio Sharpening

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

Economics 386-A1. Practice Assignment 2. S Landon Fall 2003

Optimizing Portfolios

Chapter 7: Random Variables

Partial Fractions. A rational function is a fraction in which both the numerator and denominator are polynomials. For example, f ( x) = 4, g( x) =

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Econ Financial Markets Spring 2011 Professor Robert Shiller. Problem Set 2

Mean-Variance Portfolio Choice in Excel

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 9. Demand for Insurance

Representation of Preferences

Efficient Frontier and Asset Allocation

Mathematics in Finance

Application to Portfolio Theory and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

xyz Degree is 5. See last term.

Chapter 6 Efficient Diversification. b. Calculation of mean return and variance for the stock fund: (A) (B) (C) (D) (E) (F) (G)

TA Handout 2 What is a Derivative and How Can We Make Use of It?

Lecture 10-12: CAPM.

Information Revelation and Market Crashes

Math 250A (Fall 2008) - Lab II (SOLUTIONS)

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

CHAPTER 14 BOND PORTFOLIOS

The Spiffy Guide to Finance

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions, Modern Portfolio Theory

Session 9: The expected utility framework p. 1

Neoclassical Growth Models. Solow Model

Adjusting discount rate for Uncertainty

Chapter 4 Probability and Probability Distributions. Sections

14.1 The Cost Minimization Prolem We ask, which is the cheapest wa to produce a given level of output for a rm that takes factor prices as given and h

Section 7.4 Transforming and Combining Random Variables (DAY 1)

Econ 422 Eric Zivot Summer 2004 Final Exam Solutions

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Markowitz portfolio theory

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS

Symmetric Game. In animal behaviour a typical realization involves two parents balancing their individual investment in the common

Models of Asset Pricing

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS

Optimal Portfolio Selection

SDMR Finance (2) Olivier Brandouy. University of Paris 1, Panthéon-Sorbonne, IAE (Sorbonne Graduate Business School)

Sample Midterm Questions Foundations of Financial Markets Prof. Lasse H. Pedersen

Question # 4 of 15 ( Start time: 07:07:31 PM )

23.1. Assumptions of Capital Market Theory

Transcription:

Some Formulas neglected in Anderson, Sween, and Williams, with a Digression on Statistics and Finance Transformations of a Single Random variable: If ou have a case where a new random variable is defined as a linear transformation of a another random variable, there is an eas wa to get the mean and variance of the new random variable. Assume ou are given Y = a+ bx, where a and b are constants, and Y is a new random variable being defined as this linear transformation of the random variable X. If we know the mean and variance of the random variable X, we can easil find the mean and variance of the random variable Y using the following two formulas. µ = a+ bµ. = b A word of warning: this shortcut onl works if Y is a linear transformation of X. For instance, if Y = X it is not true that µ = µ. If Y = X (or for an non-linear transformation) we must use the equation that Eg = gf. An Eample of a Non-Linear Transformation c bgh bgbg Suppose the random variable X has the following distribution: f() 0.4 1.441.189.07 It is easil verified (we did the eample in class) that the mean of the random variable is E( X) = f ( ) = 0.9. Suppose g( ) ( ) E( ) E = 0 =. One might epect that = = 0.9 = 0.81 --- However, this is WRONG. The correct calculation is f() f() 0 0.4 0 1 1.441.441 4.189.756 9.07.4 ( ( )) ( ) E g = f = 1.440 Wh is this important? It is central in the economics of uncertaint. When an agent s utilit depends on an uncertain outcome (a ver common case in the real world) the utilit achieved becomes random, so the agent can t be thought of as maimizing utilit. The simpliest generalization of utilit theor that can cover this case is to assume that under uncertaint, agents maimize epected utilit. If utilit, U, depends on a 1

random variable X which for concreteness ou can think of as wealth then the agent maimizes EU ( ( ) ) = U( f ) ( ). The fact that E( g( ) ) g( E( ) ) has important implications in economic theor. For instance, it implies that when wealth is uncertain, an epected utilit maimizer ma not wish to select a strateg that maimizes epected wealth. A concrete eample of this phenomenon is given as additional problem number one in the chapter 5 homework. The covariance of two random variables defined: In an earlier chapter, ou were introduced to the covariance and correlation coefficient, both of which measure the degree of linear association between two variables X and Y. If ou have a joint probabilit distribution of two random variables, fb, g, ou can define a population covariance and population correlation coefficient between these two random variables, in a wa that is ver similar to the definition ou saw before. The formulas (for discrete random variables) are: = µ µ f, and ρ =. b gd i b g One of the important uses of the covariance is to give us a generalization of the formula above to the case where a random variable Z is defined as a linear combination of two random variables, X and Y. A simple eample. Suppose the joint distribution of X and Y is given b 4 1.... Where X takes on the values and 4, and Y takes on the values 1 and. It is eas to calculate that µ =, µ =. Therefore, using the formula above, we discover that = ( )( 1 )(.) + ( 4 )( 1 )(.) + ( )( )(.) + ( 4 )( )(.) =... +. =. The marginal distributions of X and Y are both ver simple. The are f() f().5 1.5 4.5.5 In both cases it is eas to compute the standard deviation of both X and Y, and each is equal to one. So in this special case the correlation coefficient is also equal to.0. Linear Combinations of two random variables: an application: This eample introduces the formulas for the mean and variance of a linear combination of two random variables, and shows how the plas an important role in finance theor. The formulas I am referring to sa that if a random variable Z is defined as a linear combination of two other random variables, X and Y, so that Z = ax + by

then the mean and variance of Z are given b: EZ b g = aex b g + bey b g. z = a + b + ab For eample, suppose ou are investing, and have two stocks to choose between. The first stock is a "safe" stock. Its return is a random variable, X, with a mean return of 10% and a variance of 4. The second stock is a "risk". Its return is a random variable, Y, with a mean return of 15% and a variance of 5. The returns on the two stocks are correlated, with a correlation coefficient of.0. That implies the covariance of the returns is: ρ =. 0 = = 0. 5 You don't have to hold all our wealth in a single stock, however. You can divide our wealth between X and Y, putting a fraction ω in stock X and a fraction 1 ω in stock Y. If ou divide our wealth in this wa, the return on our portfolio will be a random variable, Z, equal to Z = ωx + b1 ωg Y. The mean and variance of the return on our portfolio, then, depend on ω, the fraction of our wealth ou put in the safe stock, and can be calculated from the two formulas given above. For instance, if ou put 0% of our wealth in the safe stock, our average return is 1.5%. EZ bg= aex bg+ bey bg 15. = b. 10g+ b. 7 15g The variance of our return is = a + b + ab z c h c h b g 1. 45 =. 4 +. 7 5 +.. 7 We can find a sort of "production possibilities frontier" b considering all the different choices of ω and repeatedl using these formulas. I have done that in a spreadsheet program, with these results.

ω E( Z ) Z 0.00 15.00 5.00 0.10 14.50 0.65 0.0 14.00 16.80 0.0 1.50 1.45 0.40 1.00 10.60 0.50 1.50 8.5 0.60 1.00 6.40 0.70 11.50 5.05 0.80 11.00 4.0 0.90 10.50.85 0.9 10.40.84 1.00 10.00 4.00 What's especiall interesting about this is that the safest portfolio, that is, the one with the smallest variance, is not the one in which ou hold onl the safest stock! In fact, the safest possible portfolio is the one with 9% of our wealth in the safe asset, and 8% in the risk asset. 1 All portfolio choices with more than 9% of our wealth in the safe asset are dominated and can never be optimal, because ou can alwas achieve a higher return without accepting an more risk. Plotting the points that can be achieved through different portfolio choices traces out a sort of production possibilities frontier of risk and return. 1 The variance of return, for an arbitrar fraction ω in the safe asset, is given b: ( ) 4 5( 1 ) 4 ( 1 ) ω ω ω ω ω = + +. We can use calculus to find the share, ω, that minimizes the variance of the portfolio return. d ( ω) = 8ω 50( 1 ω) + 4 8ω = 0 dω 50 = 46 ω ω =.9 4

The Risk-Return Frontier (Data Labels show portfolio fraction in safe asset) Epected Return 15 14 1 1 11 10 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 0.40 0.45 0.50 0.55 0.60 0.65 0.70 0.75 0.80 0.85 0.90 0.95 1.00 Standard Deviation of Return 4 5 Strictl speaking, the points showing more than 9% of assets in the safe securit are not part of the risk-return frontier, but the are shown here nonetheless for purposes of illustration. One useful result of the analsis is to show that some portfolios are inefficient, and should never be selected. In looking at the diagram, ou might feel that this is of little practical importance, since onl a small fraction of all portfolios are ruled out in this wa. However, this is because we onl have two assets in the model. In a more complicated version of this model, with several assets, the fraction of all portfolios that are ruled out as inefficient can be quite large. Having derived the risk return frontier that can be achieved b different portfolio choices, we onl need to introduce agent s preferences towards risk and return to identif their preferred portfolio. 5

We can summarize an agent s preferences with an indifference map. The map will look different from those ou usuall see in Econ 01, since risk as measured b the standard deviation of return is considered a bad. The individual will want to move to the northwest in the diagram; that is, to an area of high return and low risk. The optimal portfolio can be found b superimposing the indifference map and the production possibilities frontier pictured above. As in Econ 01, the optimum is found at the tangenc of an indifference curve with a production possibilities frontier. Determining the Optimal Portfolio 15 R E T U R N 14 1 1 11 Risk-Return Frontier Optimal Portfolio Indifference Curves 10 RISK 4 5 The optimal portfolio for this individual ields a return of about 1.75%, which (judging from the table) corresponds to a portfolio where 45% of the agent s wealth is in the safe asset, and 55% is in the risk asset. 6