The Binomial Model and Risk Neutrality: Some Important Details

Similar documents
The Mathematics Of Stock Option Valuation - Part Four Deriving The Black-Scholes Model Via Partial Differential Equations

Introduction to Black-Scholes Model

An Analytical Implementation of the Hull and White Model

Equivalent Martingale Measure in Asian Geometric Average Option Pricing

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Optimal Early Exercise of Vulnerable American Options

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Models of Default Risk

MA Advanced Macro, 2016 (Karl Whelan) 1

MAFS Quantitative Modeling of Derivative Securities

DYNAMIC ECONOMETRIC MODELS Vol. 7 Nicolaus Copernicus University Toruń Krzysztof Jajuga Wrocław University of Economics

A pricing model for the Guaranteed Lifelong Withdrawal Benefit Option

Tentamen i 5B1575 Finansiella Derivat. Måndag 27 augusti 2007 kl Answers and suggestions for solutions.

LIDSTONE IN THE CONTINUOUS CASE by. Ragnar Norberg

UCLA Department of Economics Fall PhD. Qualifying Exam in Macroeconomic Theory

Roger Mercken 1, Lisette Motmans 2, Ghislain Houben Call options in a nutshell

Black-Scholes Model and Risk Neutral Pricing

IJRSS Volume 2, Issue 2 ISSN:

Volatility and Hedging Errors

Pricing FX Target Redemption Forward under. Regime Switching Model

Matematisk statistik Tentamen: kl FMS170/MASM19 Prissättning av Derivattillgångar, 9 hp Lunds tekniska högskola. Solution.

On the Impact of Inflation and Exchange Rate on Conditional Stock Market Volatility: A Re-Assessment

Extended MAD for Real Option Valuation

FINAL EXAM EC26102: MONEY, BANKING AND FINANCIAL MARKETS MAY 11, 2004

Pricing formula for power quanto options with each type of payoffs at maturity

Pricing Vulnerable American Options. April 16, Peter Klein. and. Jun (James) Yang. Simon Fraser University. Burnaby, B.C. V5A 1S6.

You should turn in (at least) FOUR bluebooks, one (or more, if needed) bluebook(s) for each question.

Available online at ScienceDirect

Econ 546 Lecture 4. The Basic New Keynesian Model Michael Devereux January 2011

Money in a Real Business Cycle Model

Asymmetry and Leverage in Stochastic Volatility Models: An Exposition

Leveraged Stock Portfolios over Long Holding Periods: A Continuous Time Model. Dale L. Domian, Marie D. Racine, and Craig A.

Incorporating Risk Preferences into Real Options Models. Murat Isik

Market Models. Practitioner Course: Interest Rate Models. John Dodson. March 29, 2009

(1 + Nominal Yield) = (1 + Real Yield) (1 + Expected Inflation Rate) (1 + Inflation Risk Premium)

Single Premium of Equity-Linked with CRR and CIR Binomial Tree

Synthetic CDO s and Basket Default Swaps in a Fixed Income Credit Portfolio

On Monte Carlo Simulation for the HJM Model Based on Jump

An Incentive-Based, Multi-Period Decision Model for Hierarchical Systems

May 2007 Exam MFE Solutions 1. Answer = (B)

PARAMETER ESTIMATION IN A BLACK SCHOLES

Stock Index Volatility: the case of IPSA

Proceedings of the 48th European Study Group Mathematics with Industry 1

A Note on Forward Price and Forward Measure

Final Exam Answers Exchange Rate Economics

CURRENCY TRANSLATED OPTIONS

Estimating Earnings Trend Using Unobserved Components Framework

COOPERATION WITH TIME-INCONSISTENCY. Extended Abstract for LMSC09

Financial Markets And Empirical Regularities An Introduction to Financial Econometrics

Black-Scholes and the Volatility Surface

MORNING SESSION. Date: Wednesday, April 26, 2017 Time: 8:30 a.m. 11:45 a.m. INSTRUCTIONS TO CANDIDATES

This specification describes the models that are used to forecast

Available online at Math. Finance Lett. 2014, 2014:1 ISSN

Portfolio investments accounted for the largest outflow of SEK 77.5 billion in the financial account, which gave a net outflow of SEK billion.

Li Gan Guan Gong Michael Hurd. April, 2006

Option pricing and hedging in jump diffusion models

Economic Growth Continued: From Solow to Ramsey

SMALL MENU COSTS AND LARGE BUSINESS CYCLES: AN EXTENSION OF THE MANKIW MODEL

Some Remarks on Derivatives Markets (third edition, 2013)

VaR and Low Interest Rates

Macroeconomics II A dynamic approach to short run economic fluctuations. The DAD/DAS model.

Supplement to Models for Quantifying Risk, 5 th Edition Cunningham, Herzog, and London

EMPIRICAL TESTS OF DURATION SPECIFICATIONS

Uzawa(1961) s Steady-State Theorem in Malthusian Model

Risk-Neutral Probabilities Explained

Option Valuation of Oil & Gas E&P Projects by Futures Term Structure Approach. Hidetaka (Hugh) Nakaoka

Market and Information Economics

A Note on Missing Data Effects on the Hausman (1978) Simultaneity Test:

Parameter Uncertainty: The Missing Piece of the Liquidity Premium Puzzle?

Aspects of Some Exotic Options

1 Purpose of the paper

Consumption Based Asset Pricing Models: Theory

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 11 Problem 4 / 15 Problem 5 / 24 TOTAL / 100

Jarrow-Lando-Turnbull model

Financial Econometrics (FinMetrics02) Returns, Yields, Compounding, and Horizon

Lecture: Autonomous Financing and Financing Based on Market Values I

RISK-ADJUSTED STOCK INFORMATION FROM OPTION PRICES

MODELLING THE US SWAP SPREAD

PART. I. Pricing Theory and Risk Management

Alexander L. Baranovski, Carsten von Lieres and André Wilch 18. May 2009/Eurobanking 2009

Fundamental Basic. Fundamentals. Fundamental PV Principle. Time Value of Money. Fundamental. Chapter 2. How to Calculate Present Values

Technological progress breakthrough inventions. Dr hab. Joanna Siwińska-Gorzelak

A Method for Estimating the Change in Terminal Value Required to Increase IRR

Optimal Portfolios when Volatility can Jump

FORECASTING WITH A LINEX LOSS: A MONTE CARLO STUDY

Pricing floating strike lookback put option under heston stochastic volatility

Valuation and Hedging of Correlation Swaps. Mats Draijer

Loss Functions in Option Valuation: A Framework for Model Selection

Applications of Interest Rate Models

VALUATION OF THE AMERICAN-STYLE OF ASIAN OPTION BY A SOLUTION TO AN INTEGRAL EQUATION

Monetary policy and multiple equilibria in a cash-in-advance economy

Dual Valuation and Hedging of Bermudan Options

Fair Valuation of Participating Policies in Stochastic Interest Rate Models: Two-dimensional Cox-Ross-Rubinstein Approaches

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell Midterm Winter 2011

A NOTE ON BUSINESS CYCLE NON-LINEARITY IN U.S. CONSUMPTION 247

A Theory of Tax Effects on Economic Damages. Scott Gilbert Southern Illinois University Carbondale. Comments? Please send to

A Simple Method for Consumers to Address Uncertainty When Purchasing Photovoltaics

On the multiplicity of option prices under CEV with positive elasticity of variance

Ch 6. Option Pricing When Volatility is Non-Constant

Measuring and Forecasting the Daily Variance Based on High-Frequency Intraday and Electronic Data

Transcription:

The Binomial Model and Risk Neuraliy: Some Imporan Deails Sanjay K. Nawalkha* Donald R. Chambers** Absrac This paper reexamines he relaionship beween invesors preferences and he binomial opion pricing model of Cox, Ross, and Rubinsein (CRR). I is shown ha he independence of he binomial opion pricing model from invesors preferences is a resul of a special choice of binomial parameers made by CRR. For a more general choice of binomial parameers, risk neuraliy canno be obained in discree ime. This analysis reveals he essenial difference beween he risk neural valuaion approach of Cox and Ross and he equivalen maringale approach of Harrison and Kreps in a discree ime framework. *Universiy of Massachuses, Amhers, MA 0100 **Lafayee College, Eason, PA 1804 This version December 1994 Elecronic copy available a: hp://ssrn.com/absrac=17177

Inroducion Over a decade ago, he seminal work of Cox, Ross, and Rubinsein (CRR) [5] allowed he use of elemenary mahemaics in discree ime for opion valuaion. Since hen, he binomial model has been applied and exended in many ways. In general, he binomial model has made hree imporan conribuions o he opion lieraure. Firs, he binomial model has a considerable pedagogical value in demonsraing he economic inuiion behind he formaion of an arbirage-free hedge porfolio for opion pricing. Second, he binomial model allows simple coninuous ime numerical approximaions of complex opion valuaion problems where no analyical closed form soluions exis. Finally, he binomial model demonsraes how opion pricing can be done wihou any knowledge of he subjecive preferences of he invesors. Thus, according o CRR, he discree ime binomial model is consisen wih he risk neuraliy argumen of Cox and Ross [4]. This paper reexamines he consisency of he binomial opion pricing model wih he risk neuraliy argumen of Cox and Ross [4]. I is shown ha risk-neuraliy in discree ime is a consequence of a specific choice of binomial parameers by CRR. For a more general choice of binomial parameers (such as Jarrow and Rudd [7]) he discree ime binomial model is consisen wih he equivalen maringale approach of Harrison and Kreps [8], bu no wih he risk-neuraliy approach of Cox and Ross [4]. (The wo approaches become consisen in he coninuous ime limi of he binomial model.) 3 The above observaion underscores he necessiy of imposing sronger resricions on he asse reurn disribuions in discree ime, in order o obain risk neuraliy. Elecronic copy available a: hp://ssrn.com/absrac=17177

Specifically, he binomial opion pricing approach is consisen wih many binomial sock price disribuions, and only one ou of hese many disribuions (he one given by CRR) is consisen wih risk neuraliy. Furher, he above observaion is also consisen wih he discree ime coningen claims valuaion models of Rubinsein [11], Brennan [3], and Sapleon and Subrahmanyam [1], which require ha sronger disribuion specific resricions mus be imposed on asse reurns in order o obain risk neuraliy in he discree ime. 4 A General Se of Binomial Parameers and Risk Neuraliy This secion begins wih a review of he discree ime binomial model of CRR as follows. A ime = 0, le a call opion on a sock have T periods o expiraion. Le T be divided ino N number of sub-inervals. Le he curren ime be = (T/N) (N- 1). In oher words, a he curren ime he call is one sub-inerval or (T/N) periods from he expiraion dae. A his ime le he sock price equal S. In he nex period only wo saes can occur wih he upward movemen for he sock given by US and he downward movemen given by ds (where u d). The probabiliy of upward and downward movemens are q and 1 - q, respecively. Le C be he curren price of a call opion wih exercise price E. As shown by CRR he call price a he curren ime can be given as: C = [ p u! C u + p d! C d ] / r h (1) where: p u!! = r h d h, pd = u r, u! d u! d u C = Max[0, us! E ]

d C = Max[0, ds! E ] and r = 1 + riskless rae over a single period. h = T/N periods Now consider he binomial parameers specified by CRR as follows: u = exp(! " (T / N ) ) () d = exp(!" #(T / N ) ) (3) q = (1/ )![1+ (µ / " )! (T / N ) ] (4) where µ is he preference parameer and σ is he volailiy parameer. Since by definiion 0 < q < 1, i is implied ha σ (T/N) < µ (T/N) < σ (T/N). Obviously since u and d do no conain he preference parameer µ, he risk-neural probabiliies p u and p d, he fuure call prices C u and C d, and he curren call price C, are all independen of preferences. However, as shown by Jarrow and Rudd (JR) [7] and ohers, he above choice of binomial parameers is no unique. JR specify he following choice of binomial parameers for he call opion price in equaion (1): u = exp[µ!(t / N ) + "! (T / N ) ] (5) d = exp[µ! (T / N ) " #! (T / N ) ] (6) q = (1/ ) (7) JR argue in favor of he above parameers because he firs hree momens for he sock's log-reurn implied by he above parameers are consisen wih he respecive

momens of he lognormal process over every lengh of discree sub-inerval (T/N). These momens can be given as he mean =µ (T/N), variance = (σ (T/N), and skewness = 0. However, he hree momens of he log-reurn for he binomial process using he CRR parameers are no consisen wih he corresponding momens of he lognormal process. This can be seen from he following definiions of he momens using CRR parameers: he mean =µ (T/N), variance =σ (T/N)- µ (T/N), and skewness =µ [µ (T/N) 3 - σ (T/N) ]. The CRR parameers imply a non-zero level of skewness for log-reurns in discree ime. The variance and skewness of he binomial process implied by CRR parameers converge o he variance and he skewness of he lognormal process only in he coninuous ime limi (since (T/N) and (T/N) 3 become insignifican in comparison o (T/N) as N ends o infiniy). I can be shown ha he JR parameers are no consisen wih risk neural approach o opion valuaion in discree ime. Subsiuing Jarrow and Rudd's choice of u and d (given in equaions (5) and (6)) in equaion (1) implies ha he risk-neural probabiliies p u, and p d, he fuure call prices C u and C d, and he curren call price C, all depend on he preference parameer µ. Hence, he resuling risk-neural probabiliies and he call price are preference dependen. Now consider a general form of binomial parameers given as follows: u = exp[m! (T / N ) + "! (T / N ) ] (8) d = exp[m! (T / N ) + "! (T / N ) ] (9) q = (1 / )![1+ ((µ " m) / # )! (T / N ) ] (10) where -σ (T/W) < (µ- m) (T/N) <σ (T/N) (since 0 < q < 1).

Given he above choice of binomial parameers, he firs hree momens of he logreurn for he binomial process over a discree sub-inerval (T/N) can be given as: mean = µ (T/N), variance = σ (T/N) - (µ-m) (T/N), and skewness = (µ-m) [(µ-m) (T/N) 3 -σ (T/N) ]. The erms (T/N) and (T/N) 3 become insignifican in comparison o (T/N) as N ends o infiniy, and herefore he variance and skewness of he binomial process implied by he above parameers converge o he variance and skewness of he lognormal process in he coninuous ime limi. The above choice of binomial parameers (see equaions (8) and (9)) implies ha he erms p u, p d, C u, C d, and C in equaion (1) depend upon he parameer m. To obain a unique opion price, invesors may disagree abou he preference parameer µ (and hus, disagree on he acual probabiliies), bu all invesors mus agree on he parameer m. For he CRR model, all invesors agree ha he parameer m equals zero. For he JR model, all invesors agree ha he parameer m equals µ. In general, if he parameer m canno be uniquely deermined, he resuling binomial opion prices are no uniquely defined in discree ime. To preclude arbirage, addiional resricions mus be imposed on he binomial parameers. Specifically, a unique equivalen probabiliy measure mus exis such ha he sock price discouned a he riskless rae is a maringale wih respec o his measure (see Harrison and Kreps [8]). To saisfy he above condiion, he risk neural probabiliies p u and p d mus be greaer han zero in equaion (1). This implies ha for he CRR choice of parameers exp(-σ (T/N) ) < r h < exp(σ (T/N) ), for he JR parameers exp[µ (T/N) -σ (T/N) ] < r h < exp[µ (T/N) + σ (T/N) ], and for he revealed preference parameers exp[m (T/N) -σ (T/N) ] < r h < exp[m (T/N) + σ (T/N) ].

Two limiaions of he discree ime binomial approach can now be summarized wih respec o he general binomial parameers given in equaions (8), (9), and (10), as follows: 1. If m = µ, hen he binomial model is preference dependen and is inconsisen wih he risk-neuraliy argumen of Cox and Ross [4] in discree ime.. If m µ, hen risk neuraliy can sill be obained since invesors are allowed o disagree abou he preference parameer µ. However, he difficuly here is in deermining a unique value for m, eiher heoreically or empirically. 6 Differen values of m will resul in differen call opion prices in he discree ime. Forunaely, boh he above limiaions of he binomial approach can be resolved in he coninuous ime limi. I can be shown ha he dependence of he discree ime binomial opion pricing model on he parameer m diminishes as he number of subinervals N becomes large. Wih an infiniely large N, he Black and Scholes [] opion formula is obained as a limiing case of he binomial opion formula (see he Appendix). Thus, he binomial model is independen of he parameer m, only in he coninuous ime limi. This underscores he necessiy of coninuous ime porfolio rebalancing o guaranee risk neuraliy as originally noed by Black and Scholes [] and subsequenly formalized by Cox and Ross [4]. Conclusions This paper shows ha he consisency of he discree ime binomial opion pricing model of CRR wih he risk neuraliy argumen of Cox and Ross [4] depends upon a specific choice of binomial parameers. For a more general choice of binomial

parameers, he resuling opion prices may be preference dependen. This preference dependence diminishes as he number of sub-inervals N becomes large and disappears compleely only in he coninuous ime limi as he binomial model converges o he Black and Scholes model. The implicaions of hese resuls perain o one of he cenral issues of modern finance: he risk neural pricing of coningen claims. In order o obain risk neuraliy, he CRR model mus assume very specific behavior regarding he price changes of underlying asses. However, boh heoreically and pracically speaking, alernaive price behavior models are reasonable. This paper demonsraes a binomial opion pricing model using an alernaive and reasonable specificaion of behavior in underlying asse price changes and demonsraes ha risk neuraliy does no obain in he model. Thus, his paper provides an addiional demonsraion of he failure of risk neuraliy o obain in discree ime in paricular cases.

Appendix This appendix shows ha he binomial opion pricing model converges o he Black-Scholes model for a general choice of binomial parameers given by equaions (8), (9), and (10), as he number of sub-inervals N becomes infiniely large. Though i is possible o demonsrae he acual convergence of he binomial call opion price o he Black-Scholes call opion price, a much easier and inuiive proof follows from Cox and Rubinsein [6], page 09. Using he alernaive approach, he Black-Scholes P.D.E. is derived from he binomial equaion for he general choice of binomial parameers. Reconsider he call opion defined in he second secion a ime (0 T). The call price a ime can be given as follows: C = [ p! C u + p! C d ] / r h (A1) u + h d + h where he parameers p u, p d, r h, and h are defined in equaion (1), and he general binomial parameers u and d are defined in equaions (8) and (9). Following Cox and Rubinsein, he call price a ime is assumed o be a coninuously differeniable funcion of he sock price a ime, and he ime remaining o he expiraion dae. Thus, C = C(S, T- ), C u +h = C(u S, T - ( + h)), C u +h = C(d S, T - ( + h)), where subscrip implies he ime price of a given securiy. By appropriae subsiuions equaion (Al) can be rewrien as:

h r " exp[ m# h "! #( h )] [ ]# C(exp[ m# h +! #( h )]# S, ( )) T " + h exp[ m# h +! #( h )]" exp[ m# h "! #( h )] h exp[ m# h +! #( h )]" r [ ] C(exp[ m h! ( h )] S, ( )) T h + # # " # # " + exp[ m# h +! #( h )] " exp[ m# h "! #( h )] h " r # C( S, T " ) = 0 (A) By Taylor series expansions of he expressions C m" h + " h " S T # + h and (exp[! ( )], ( )) C m" h # " h " S T # + h around (exp[! ( )], ( )) he poin (S, T-): " C C(exp[ m# h +! #( h )]# S, T $ ( + h)) = C + [exp[ m# h +! #( h )] $ 1] # S # " S 1 " C 1 " C " C + #[exp[ m# h +! #( h )] $ 1] # S # + #[exp[ m# h +! #( h )] $ 1] # S # + h # +... " S " S " (A3) and a similar expression for replaces! "( h ). C m" h # " h " S T # + h, excep (exp[! ( )], ( )) "! # ( h ) By Taylor series expansions of he expressions exp[ m h! ( h )] " + " and exp[ m h! ( h )] " # " : 1 " + " = + " + " + " " + " + + (A4) exp[ m h! ( h )] 1 [ m h! ( h )] [ m h! ( h )]... and a similar expression for exp[ m h! ( h ) " # ", excep "! #( h ) replaces! "( h ). Finally, by a Taylor series expansion of r h : 1 r h r h r h r h = exp(! log ) = 1+! log +!(! log ) +... + (A5) By subsiuion of he appropriae values from equaions (A3), (A4), and (A5) ino equaion (A) and simplifying:

" C " C " C " S " S " S 1 #! # S # # h + (log r) # S # # h + # h $ (log r) # C # h + Z = 0 (A6) where Z conains all erms of higher orders of h (i.e. Z = [erms wih (h) 1 (h),, ]). Dividing equaion (A6) by h: " C " C " C " S " D " 1 #! # S # + (log r) # S # + $ (log r) # C + Z / h = 0 (A7) I can be seen from he above equaion ha he revealed preference parameer m (see equaion (A)) is conained only in he erm Z/h. For non-infiniesimal values of h, he magniude of Z/h will be significan, and he soluion o equaion (A7) will depend upon he revealed preference parameer. However, as he number of sub-inervals N ends o infiniy, he erm Z/h goes o zero (as h goes o zero), bu oher erms do no. Thus, in he coninuous ime limi, equaion (A7) converges o he Black-Scholes parial differenial equaion, which is independen of he revealed preference parameer m. 7 Q.E.D.

End Noes 1. Recenly, he economic inuiion behind he binomial approach has been exended o a mulivariae-mulinomial approach by He [9] using he dynamic complee marke framework. The argumens given in his paper apply o he mulivariae-mulinomial models, as he binomial model can be considered as a special case of hese models.. See Meron [10], pp. 337-347, for he applicaion of he risk-neuraliy argumen of Cox and Ross [4] o he binomial model of CRR. 3. Recenly, Beck [1] demonsraed ha he radiional derivaion of Black-Scholes opion formula is mahemaically unsaisfacory. Specifically, Beck shows ha he hedge porfolio used in Black-Scholes is neiher riskless nor self-financing. Beck presens an alernaive derivaion of he Black-Scholes formula ha avoids hese inconsisencies. Though he issues analyzed in his paper are quie differen, i is similar o he Beck s paper in spiri. 4. For example, assume ha invesors preferences are given by CPRA uiliy. Then, i is only necessary ha he underlying asse and he marke porfolio be bivariae lognormally disribued o obain risk-neuraliy in he discree-ime. Of course, he above assumpion is no necessary in he coninuous-ime analog of he above model (i.e., Black and Scholes []). 5. Jarrow and Rudd [7], pp. 179-190, show heir binomial parameers o be consisen wih risk-neuraliy in he coninuous ime limi. This is consisen wih he Appendix A of his paper, which obains a similar resul. 6. CRR do no provide any heoreical jusificaion or empirical evidence for choosing zero as he appropriae value for m. 7. A he firs glance, equaion (A7) looks slighly differen from he Black-Scholes parial differenial equaion. However, noe ha r equals 1 plus he discree-ime single period riskless rae (see equaion (1)). However, Black-Scholes use he coninuous-ime riskless rae, which can be defined as R. From he basic rules of compounding over ime, he relaionship beween r and R over any lengh of ime h is given as r h = exp(r h), which in urn implies logr = R.

References [1] Beck, Thomas M. Black-Scholes Revisied: Some Imporan Deails. The Financial Review 8(February 1993): 77-90. [] Black, Fischer, and Myron S. Scholes. The Pricing of Opions and Corporae Liabiliies. Journal of Poliical Economy (May-June 1973): 637-54. [3] Brennan, Michael J. The Pricing of Coningen Claims in Discree Time Models. Journal of Finance 34.1(1979): 53-68. [4] Cox, John C., and Sephen A. Ross. The Valuaion of Opions for Alernaive Sochasic Processes. Journal of Financial Economics (January-March 1976): 145-66. [5] Cox, John C., Sephen A. Ross, and Mark Rubinsein. Opion Pricing: A Simplified Approach. Journal of Financial Economics (Sepember 1979): 9-63. [6] Cox, John C., and Mark Rubinsein. Opion Markes. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prenice Hall, 1985. [7] Jarrow, Rober A., and Andrew Rudd. Opion Pricing. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, 1983. [8] Harrison, J. Michael, and David M. Kreps. Maringales and Arbirage in Muliperiod Securiies Markes. Journal of Economic Theory 0(1979): 381-408. [9] He, Hua. Convergence from Discree o Coninuous-Time Coningen Claim Prices. The Review of Financial Sudies 3.4(1990): 53-546. [10] Meron, Rober C. Coninuous-Time Finance. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1990. [11] Rubinsein, Mark. The Valuaion of Uncerain Income Sreams and he Pricing of Opions. Bell Journal of Economics 7(1976): 407-45. [1] Sapleon, Richard C., and Mari G. Subrahmanyam. The Valuaion of Mulivariae Coningen Claims in Discree Time Models, Journal of Finance 39(1984): 07-8.