Bankers Liability and Risk Taking

Similar documents
For Richer, For Poorer

Chairman Frank, Ranking Member Bachus, and distinguished members of the Committee, thank you very much for inviting me to testify today.

The Lehman Shock Financial Disaster the Effects on Japan. found out an attractive and interesting article, which showed the world economic

Notes on Hyman Minsky s Financial Instability Hypothesis

For Richer, for Poorer. Bankers Liability and Risk-taking in New England,

EC248-Financial Innovations and Monetary Policy Assignment. Andrew Townsend

Did Poor Incentives Cause the Financial Crisis? Should Incentives and Pay Be Regulated?

Executive Compensation and Risk Taking. Lucian Bebchuk, Harvard university

Financial Crisis 101: A Beginner's Guide to Structured Finance, Financial Crisis, and Market Regulation

Answers to Questions: Chapter 5

Global Financial Crisis. Econ 690 Spring 2019

Chapter 10. The Great Recession: A First Look. (1) Spike in oil prices. (2) Collapse of house prices. (2) Collapse in house prices

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

The Run for Safety: Financial Fragility and Deposit Insurance

Chapter Fourteen. Chapter 10 Regulating the Financial System 5/6/2018. Financial Crisis

Lessons Learned? Comparing the Federal Reserve s Response to the Crises of and

CHAPTER 09 (Part B) Banking and Bank Management

Understanding Bank Runs: Do Depositors Monitor Banks? Rajkamal Iyer (MIT Sloan), Manju Puri (Duke Fuqua) and Nicholas Ryan (Harvard)

Executive pay and risk taking in banks

Social Security Planning Strategies

CEO Compensation and Firm Performance: Did the Financial Crisis Matter?

PAGE 42 THE STERN STEWART INSTITUTE PERIODICAL #10 JAMES GORMAN: NAVIGATING THE CHANGING LANDSCAPE OF FINANCE

COMPARING FINANCIAL SYSTEMS. Lesson 23 Financial Crises

Yves Mersch: Monetary policy and economic inequality

Bubbles and Central Banks: Historical Perspectives

Life Below Zero: Bank Lending Under Negative Policy Rates Florian Heider, Farzad Saidi, and Glenn Schepens

10.2 Recent Shocks to the Macroeconomy Introduction. Housing Prices. Chapter 10 The Great Recession: A First Look

Return Optimization Notes, Principal Protection Notes, and Other Remarkable Structured Investment Vehicles

Are Banks Special? International Risk Management Conference. IRMC2015 Luxembourg, June 15

An Enhanced Objective Financial Stability

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

The labour force participation of older men in Canada

RISK MANAGEMENT AND VALUE CREATION

2008 STOCK MARKET COLLAPSE

Why the Next US Recession Could Be Worse Than the Last

Printable Lesson Materials

Lecture 12: Too Big to Fail and the US Financial Crisis

STUDY GUIDE SHOULD GOVERNMENT BAIL OUT BIG BANKS? KEY TERMS: bankruptcy de-regulation credit bailout depression TARP

Marriage, Property and [In]Equality: Remedying ERISA s Disparate Impact on Spousal Wealth

Capital structure and the financial crisis

Bank Rescues and Bailout Expectations: The Erosion of Market Discipline During the Financial Crisis

Risks of Retirement Key Findings and Issues. February 2004

International Money and Banking: 10. Incentive Problems in Banking

The Financial Sector Functions of money Medium of exchange Measure of value Store of value Method of deferred payment

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 52

The Invisible Hand and the Banking Trade: seigniorage, risk-shifting, and more 1

Financial Markets and Real Economic Activity

Social Security Planning Strategies

What is the real rate of interest telling us?

Foreign Currency Debt, Financial Crises and Economic Growth : A Long-Run Exploration

Causes of the Great Depression

EVALUATING THE PERFORMANCE OF COMMERCIAL BANKS IN INDIA. D. K. Malhotra 1 Philadelphia University, USA

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

In this alert we want to address some very specific questions for our clients:

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

An Updated Look at Personal Goodwill

Credit Booms Gone Bust

I. Learning Objectives II. The Functions of Money III. The Components of the Money Supply

What Is Risk? (Part II)

Why Regulate Shadow Banking? Ian Sheldon

Lessons from the Subprime Crisis

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 55

Who Borrows from the Lender of Last Resort? 1

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 15. Money, Banking, and Central Banking

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

Banking, Liquidity Transformation, and Bank Runs

Economic Uncertainty and Fertility: Insights from Japan. James M. Raymo 1. Akihisa Shibata 2

Unit 9: Money and Banking

Name: Class: U.S. History 2 Date:. Mr. Wallace. 1. is buying stocks with loans from brokers. (Buying on margin/buying short)

Part Two: The Details

Planning a Confident Retirement: The Top 5 Mistakes that Wealthy Families Make

Saving, Investment, and the Financial System

The Great Depression: An Overview by David C. Wheelock

The Federal Reserve and Monetary Policy 1

Why Regulate Shadow Banking? Ian Sheldon

PAPER No. 8: Financial Management MODULE No. 27: Capital Structure in practice

Market Discipline Beats Regulatory Discipline

JA Worldwide. Understanding the Financial Crisis: Origin and Impact

ISSUES RAISED AT THE ECB WORKSHOP ON ASSET PRICES AND MONETARY POLICY

A Guide to Understanding Social Security Retirement Benefits

The International Financial Crises of the 1990s: Analytics

Panel Data Research Center at Keio University DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Does a Bank s History Affect Its Risk-Taking?

Chapter 10: Money and Banking Section 2

Analysis Of A Bank s Balance Sheet. Suresh Sankaran

Great Depression Economic history Timing and severity

How Curb Risk In Wall Street. Luigi Zingales. University of Chicago

Wealth Preservation and Estate Planning for 21 st Century Families One Size Does Not Fit All

Stulz, Governance, Risk Management and Risk-Taking in Banks

Can Happiness Data Help Evaluate Economic Policies?

The Failure of US Neoliberalism: Financial Panic, Economic Stagnation and What We Can Do About It

ROUNDTABLE COMMENTS ON MONETARY AND REGULATORY POLICY IN AN ERA OF GLOBAL MARKETS

*Corresponding author: Lawrence J. White, The NYU Stern School of Business.

Why this is the worst time for deficitfinanced

Should we fear derivatives? By Rene M Stulz, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 2004

b. Financial innovation and/or financial liberalization (the elimination of restrictions on financial markets) can cause financial firms to go on a

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions

The Insurance Role of Household Labor Supply for Older Workers: Preliminary Results

Based on a Joseph Stiglitz lecture delivered 26th of July 2010 at the University of Queensland in Australia. Extensively modified.

Transcription:

Bankers Liability and Risk Taking Vox EU By Peter Koudijs, Laura Salisbury, Gurpal S. Sran Saturday, October 06, 2018 In order to protect the financial system from excessive risk-taking, many argue that bank managers need to have more personal liability. However, whether the liability of bank managers has a significant effect on risk-taking is an open question. This column studies a unique historical episode in which similar bankers, operating in similar institutional and economic environments, faced different degrees of personal liability, depending on the timing of their marriages, and finds that limited liability induced bankers to take more risks. In 2015, seven years after the failure of Lehman Brothers brought the financial world to the brink of collapse, Dick Fuld, the former CEO, sold his Idaho mansion for around $30 million dollars, setting a record for private home auctions. It seems he was ready to leave his private troutfishing stream and return to the world of high finance. Naturally, Dick Fuld lost significant sums of money when his bank collapsed. Bebchuk et al. (2010) calculate that, in 2000, Fuld owned about $200 million of Lehman Brother stock, which would eventually become worthless. Nevertheless, Fuld withdrew about $520 million from the bank between 2000 and 2008 in the form of cash bonuses and equity sales, none of which was accessible to Lehman s creditors. This raises the question of whether bank managers incentives are set appropriately to protect the financial system from excessive risk-taking. Managers can cash in on a bank s profits when things are going well, but they shoulder minimal losses if the bank fails (Bhagat and Bolton 2014). This limited liability may encourage them to take undue risks with depositors money. There is a growing chorus of commentators arguing that the financial system will only be safe if bank managers have more personal liability (e.g. Kay 2015, Cohan 2017). Whether the liability of bank managers has a significant effect on risk-taking is an open question. Bank managers care about their reputations and future careers; so, they might try to avoid the failure of their bank at any cost. Other stakeholders, such as uninsured creditors, may be able to force banks to reduce risk-taking (Calomiris and Kahn 1991, Diamond and Rajan 2000). To make their case, proponents of increased personal liability often point to what happened to investment banks over the last few decades. Before the 1980s, investment banks operated as partnerships with unlimited liability. During the 1980s, they went public. Anecdotally, this seems to have gone hand in hand with increased risk taking. However, this coincided with a period of general financial deregulation. So, how do we know what caused investment banks to take more risk? In recent work (Koudijs et al. 2018), we study a unique historical episode in which similar bankers, operating in similar institutional and economic environments, faced different degrees of personal liability, depending on the timing of their marriages. Our findings suggest that limited liability really matters for bank risk-taking.

Banker liability in the past While bankers today shoulder relatively little risk, this was not always the case. During the US National Banking era (1864-1912), shares in national banks carried double liability. If a bank failed, each shareholder needed to pay back depositors out of personal assets, up to the amount of his original investment in the bank. For example, if he initially invested $1,000, he could lose that investment plus an additional $1,000. Bank presidents who were responsible for the dayto-day operations of the bank were major shareholders, typically owning 10-20% of their bank s stock. The early part of the National Banking era coincides with a change in the marital property laws of certain US states. Under traditional American common law, when a woman married, her property became her husband s. Starting in the 1840s, states started to pass Married Women s Property Acts (MWPAs), which allowed married women to own property in their own right. However, these laws only applied to couples married after the passage of the MWPA. Crucially, the MWPAs protected a married woman s property from claims against her husband. If her husband was a national bank president, this included double liability claims on his bank s shares. The typical national bank president during the 1860s and 1870s was a middle-aged, married man. Depending on his birth year, age at marriage, and state of marriage, he may have been married before or after the passage of a MWPA in his state. In the latter case, his wife s property would have been protected from any double liability claims if his bank failed. As such, his household liability would have been less than that of an otherwise identical banker who was married before a MWPA. Here s a simple example. A banker with $100 in assets marries a woman with $100. The banker invests $75 in his bank. If this marriage occurred before a MWPA, depositors (represented by the regulator) could lay claim to $75 of the household s remaining personal assets if the bank failed. However, if the marriage occurred after a MWPA, depositors would only have a right to the $25 the banker individuallyhad left. This reduction in personal liability may have led the banker to put his depositors money into riskier but higher-yield investments. Limited liability and bank risk-taking We collect data on the activities of New England national banks during the 1860s and 1870s, as well as information about bank presidents marriage histories. This allows us to classify bankers as protected (i.e. married after a MWPA was passed in his state) or unprotected. We then compare the risk-taking behaviour of protected and unprotected bankers. A key measure of bank risk-taking is leverage. We define this as loans and securities - inherently risky investments made by the bank relative to capital invested in the bank by shareholders. A bank that extends more loans relative to capital is more likely to suffer losses that render it unable to pay back depositors. As it turns out, bankers with less personal liability managed more highly levered banks. More precisely, a bank s ratio of loans and securities to capital was 7 to 10 percentage points higher if

its president was married after a MWPA. This does not reflect underlying differences between protected and unprotected bankers (such as age), or the characteristics of counties or towns that they live in. It also does not reflect characteristics of the banks themselves when an individual bank switches from having an unprotected president to a protected president (through turnover, or a change in the president s marital status), leverage increases in that bank. Not surprisingly, the impact of a president s protection status is contingent on the relative wealth of his wife. Figure 1 plots the difference in leverage between banks with protected and unprotected presidents with different intra-household allocations of property (inferred from the ratio of the wife s family wealth to the husband s family wealth). Being married after a MWPA only increases leverage for bankers whose wives own a sufficiently large share of the household s property. Figure 1 The effect of limited liability on bank leverage Source: Figure 1 in Koudijs et al. (2018). Note: Figure uses non-parametric local mean smoothing, where both the x-axis and y-axis variables are residualised with fixed effects and control variables. The vertical lines denote the 5thand 95thconfidence intervals. Bankers with less personal liability were more likely to engage in other risky lending practices as well. In particular, they were more likely to hide bad loans on their balance sheets, and to extend loans that were too risky according to regulators.

Limited liability and financial crises: The Panic of 1873 What were the consequences of protected bankers risky behaviour? We look at what happened to banks managed by presidents who faced different degrees of personal liability after the Panic of 1873. The Panic of 1873 was a nationwide financial crisis, triggered by the failure of an East- Coast investment bank, and followed by a string of bank failures and a lengthy recession (sound familiar?). In fact, banks managed by bankers with less personal liability fared worse after the Panic. Banks managed by bankers married after a MWPA experienced a larger decline in earnings relative to capital over the course of the depression (Figure 2). Moreover, this effect is most pronounced for bankers with relatively wealthy wives, whose personal liability would have been most limited by a MWPA (Figure 3). Figure 2 The effect of limited liability on bank earnings after the Panic of 1873 Source: Figure 2, Panel A in Koudijs et al. (2018). Note: Figure plots coefficients from regressions of aggregate earnings over capital on the protection status of the banker in 1873, including fixed effects and other controls. The vertical lines denote the 5thand 95thconfidence intervals. Figure 3 The effect of limited liability on bank earnings, 1873-1878

Source: Figure 3, Panel A in Koudijs et al. (2018). Note: Figure uses non-parametric local mean smoothing, where both the x-axis and y-axis variables are residualised with fixed effects and control variables. The vertical lines denote the 5thand 95thconfidence intervals. In short, limited liability induced bankers to take more risks, and this had real consequences for performance during a financial crisis. Implications for policy Our findings strongly suggest that increasing bank managers liability would discourage bank risk-taking, subject to the usual caveats about extrapolating from a historical period to the present. What does this imply about optimal bank regulation? One thing to consider is whether limiting bank risk-taking is a good thing. While less-risky banks may reduce the likelihood of a major financial crisis, they may also limit beneficial lending to innovative new businesses. We find no evidence, however, that this was the case in the 19th century the protection status of local bankers did not affect innovation in manufacturing firms, measured through the adoption of steam power. Still, this evidence is only suggestive. More work remains to be done to establish the right amount of banker liability. One important lesson is that, in terms of policy, one size does not fit all. The effectiveness of a policy that increases banker liability will depend on bankers individual circumstances. Bankers

with a comfortable cushion (through marriage or an independent source of wealth) may respond differently than those who do not. So long as our laws allow bankers to shield the profits from risky investments from the claims of creditors, bankers will find clever ways to do so. Which brings us back to Dick Fuld. In 2009, when calls for personal lawsuits against bankers were loudest, Fuld sold his $13.5 million Florida beachside getaway to his wife for a mere $100 a modern twist on the concept of limited spousal liability that began with the MWPAs. Regulators should ask themselves whether the benefits of limited liability outweigh the costs. Our research suggests that they may not. References Bebchuk, L A, A Cohen and H Spamann (2010), Wages of failure: Executive compensation at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000-2008, Yale Journal on Regulation 27: 257. Bhagat, S, and B Bolton (2014), Financial crisis and bank executive incentive compensation, Journal of Corporate Finance 25: 313-341. Calomiris, C W, and C M Kahn (1991), The role of demandable debt in structuring optimal banking arrangements, American Economic Review 497-513. Cohan, W D (2017), Why Wall Street Matters, New York: Random House. Diamond, D W, and R G Rajan (2000), A theory of bank capital, Journal of Finance 55(6): 2431-2465. Kay, J (2015), Other People's Money: The Real Business of Finance, New York: PublicAffairs. Koudijs, P, L Salisbury and G Sran (2018), For richer, for poorer: Bankers liability and risktaking in New England, 1867-1880, NBER Working Paper No. 24998.