Do Tax Incentives Increase 401(k) Retirement Saving? Evidence from the Adoption of Catch-Up Contributions

Similar documents
DO TAX INCENTIVES INCREASE 401(K) RETIREMENT SAVING? EVIDENCE FROM THE ADOPTION OF CATCH-UP CONTRIBUTIONS

DO TAX INCENTIVES INCREASE 401(K) RETIREMENT SAVING? EVIDENCE FROM THE ADOPTION OF CATCH-UP CONTRIBUTIONS

DO TAX INCENTIVES INCREASE 401(K) RETIREMENT SAVING? EVIDENCE FROM THE ADOPTION OF CATCH-UP CONTRIBUTIONS

Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home?

Does Age-Related Decline in Ability Correspond with Retirement Age?

HOW LONG DO UNEMPLOYED OLDER WORKERS SEARCH FOR A JOB?

How Much Work Would a 50% Disability Insurance Benefit Offset Encourage?: An Analysis Using SSI and SSDI Incentives

TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS

Stretching the match: Unintended effects on plan contributions

Demographic Change, Retirement Saving, and Financial Market Returns

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

The Effect of Pension Subsidies on Retirement Timing of Older Women: Evidence from a Regression Kink Design

DO YOUNG ADULTS WITH STUDENT DEBT SAVE LESS FOR RETIREMENT?

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009

Impacts of Parental Health Insurance Coverage Availability on Disability Benefit Applications of Young Adults

Does Raising Contribution Limits Lead to More Saving? Evidence from the Catch-up Limit Reform

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

TECHNICAL APPENDIX FOR THE STATE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS: CURRENT 5500 DATA

The Effect of Health Reform on Retirement

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Do Defaults Have Spillover Effects? The Effect of the Default Asset on Retirement Plan Contributions

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

The Future of Social Security

MAKING MAXIMUM USE OF TAX-DEFERRED RETIREMENT ACCOUNTS. Janette Kawachi, Karen E. Smith, and Eric J. Toder

The Rise of 401(k) Plans, Lifetime Earnings, and Wealth at Retirement

Understanding Participation in SSI. Kathleen McGarry University of California, Los Angeles and NBER and Robert F. Schoeni University of Michigan

The Affordable Care Act as Retiree Health Insurance: Implications for Retirement and Social Security Claiming

Is Debt Good or Bad for a Comfortable Retirement? Exploring the Relationship between Consumer Debt and Retirement Preparedness

HOW IMPORTANT IS MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY IN THE TIMING OF RETIREMENT?

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

Social Security Household Benefits: Measuring Program Knowledge

THE IMPACT OF RAISING CHILDREN ON RETIREMENT SECURITY

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

POLICY BRIEF: THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement?

DRAFT. A microsimulation analysis of public and private policies aimed at increasing the age of retirement 1. April Jeff Carr and André Léonard

The Decision to Delay Social Security Benefits: Theory and Evidence

Every year, the Statistics of Income (SOI) Division

GAO GENDER PAY DIFFERENCES. Progress Made, but Women Remain Overrepresented among Low-Wage Workers. Report to Congressional Requesters

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

The Implications of Declining Retiree Health Insurance

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

401(k) PLANS AND RACE

GUARDIANSHIP AND THE REPRESENTATIVE PAYEE PROGRAM. Anek Belbase and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher. CRR WP August 2017

The Potential Effects of Cash Balance Plans on the Distribution of Pension Wealth At Midlife. Richard W. Johnson and Cori E. Uccello.

THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS

DOG BITES MAN: AMERICANS ARE SHORTSIGHTED ABOUT THEIR FINANCES

EFFECTIVENESS OF TAX INCENTIVES TO BOOST (RETIREMENT) SAVING: THEORETICAL

Do Older SSDI Applicants Denied Benefits on the Basis of their Work Capacity Return to Work After Denial?

center for retirement research

Gender Pay Differences: Progress Made, but Women Remain Overrepresented Among Low- Wage Workers

Disability Risk and Alternative Work Arrangements

PERSISTENCE IN LABOR SUPPLY AND THE RESPONSE TO THE SOCIAL SECURITY EARNINGS TEST. Leora Friedberg and Anthony Webb*

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Can Social Security Explain Trends in Labor Force Participation of Older Men in the United States?

Bonus Impacts on Receipt of Unemployment Insurance

Active vs. Passive Decisions and Crowd-out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark

VERY PRELIMINARY - DO NOT QUOTE OR DISTRIBUTE

Chapter 7: Investment Decision Rules

The Growing Longevity Gap between Rich and Poor and Its Impact on Redistribution through Social Security

Alan L. Gustman Dartmouth College and NBER Thomas L. Steinmeier Texas Tech University Nahid Tabatabai Dartmouth College

A Data and Chart Book. August by Retirement Plan Coverage of Boomers: Analysis of 2003 SIPP Data. Satyendra K. Verma. Satyendra K.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRANSITION TO PERSONAL ACCOUNTS AND INCREASING RETIREMENT WEALTH: MACRO AND MICRO EVIDENCE

Effective May 14, 2014, an after-tax Roth

Discussion: Extending Working Life

CRS Report for Congress

Consumption. Basic Determinants. the stream of income

RETIREMENT PLAN COVERAGE AND SAVING TRENDS OF BABY BOOMER COHORTS BY SEX: ANALYSIS OF THE 1989 AND 1998 SCF

Apriority area for the public health workforce research

Working paper series. The Decline in Lifetime Earnings Mobility in the U.S.: Evidence from Survey-Linked Administrative Data

WHY ARE OLDER WORKERS AT GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

Long Run Changes in Tax Expenditures on 401(k) Type Retirement Plans

The Impact of the Default Investment Decision on Participant Deferral Rates: Managed Accounts vs Target-Date Funds

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

TAX-PREFERRED ASSETS AND DEBT, AND THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 1986: SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM ERIC M. ENGEN * & WILLIAM G.

Using Consequence Messaging to Improve Understanding of Social Security

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making

Retirement Security: What s Working and What s Not? James Poterba MIT, NBER, & TIAA-CREF. Bipartisan Policy Center 30 July 2014

Progress Report. Prepaid College Program Fiscally Sound, Additional Changes May Be Appropriate

IS WORKING LONGER A GOOD PRESCRIPTION FOR ALL?

Characteristics of Low-Wage Workers and Their Labor Market Experiences: Evidence from the Mid- to Late 1990s

Social Security Literacy and Retirement Well-Being

Getting Real with Capital Gains Taxes by Adjusting for Inflation

Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different?

Broad and Deep: The Extensive Learning Agenda in YouthSave

Health Insurance Coverage in the District of Columbia

Medicaid Insurance and Redistribution in Old Age

Additional Slack in the Economy: The Poor Recovery in Labor Force Participation During This Business Cycle

We follow Agarwal, Driscoll, and Laibson (2012; henceforth, ADL) to estimate the optimal, (X2)

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder

ESTIMATING PENSION COVERAGE USING DIFFERENT DATA SETS

New ICI Research on Mutual Fund Ownership and on the U.S. Retirement Market

ASSET ALLOCATION AND ASSET LOCATION DECISIONS: EVIDENCE FROM THE SURVEY OF CONSUMER FINANCES

Discussion of Trends in Individual Earnings Variability and Household Incom. the Past 20 Years

by Sankar De and Manpreet Singh

What Explains Changes in Retirement Plans during the Great Recession?

Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April Lower Personal Income Tax Rates. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne

Transcription:

Do Tax Incentives Increase 401(k) Retirement Saving? Evidence from the Adoption of Catch-Up Contributions Matthew S. Rutledge Center for Retirement Research at Boston College April Yanyuan Wu Mathematica Policy Research Francis Vitagliano Center for Retirement Research at Boston College 17 th Annual Joint Meeting of the Retirement Research Consortium August 6-7, 2015 Washington, DC The NBER Retirement Research Center, the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College (CRR), and the University of Michigan Retirement Research Center (MRRC) gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Social Security Administration (SSA) for this conference. The findings and conclusions are solely those of the authors and do not represent the views of SSA, any agency of the federal government, the NBER Retirement Research Center, CRR, or MRRC. The authors are indebted to the indispensable data analysis of Qi Guan, and would also like to thank Robin Jensen for excellent research assistance. The authors are grateful to Kelly Trageser, Gary Benedetto, Holly Monti, and Martha Stinson for helping us access the SIPP synthetic data and re-running our code on the actual data.

Introduction The Joint Committee on Taxation estimates that the tax-deferred treatment of defined contribution (DC) plans like 401(k)s cost the U.S. federal government $61.4 billion in lost revenue in 2014. But researchers have not come to a consensus on whether the tax incentives to save in 401(k)s induces additional retirement saving overall, or even additional 401(k) saving. The increase in the maximum tax-deferred 401(k) contribution for participants age 50 and older provides a natural experiment in whether savers respond to a change in the tax incentives. Starting in 2002, individuals age 50 and over were allowed to make catch-up contributions over and above the tax-deferred maximum. In 2015, the contribution limit is $18,000, but older workers can contribute an extra $6,000 per year. The higher limit provides an incentive for workers previously constrained by the maximum to increase their tax-deferred savings, but does not change the incentives to save for workers unconstrained by the limit. The impact of the catch-up provision on 401(k) saving has received little attention; the few existing studies are limited to descriptive analyses conducted shortly after its adoption. This study evaluates the response in 401(k) saving to the change in tax incentives using demographic characteristics from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) linked to administrative data on tax-deferred earnings from the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA). Evaluating the effect of the catch-up provision on 401(k) saving requires accounting for three factors: the fundamental differences between maximum contributors (who faced a change in incentives) and participants contributing a lower amount (who faced no change), the growth in 401(k) contributions over time, and the potential increase in saving with age. This study adopts a triple-differences framework, comparing the change in 401(k) contributions for maximum contributors just after age 50 to similar participants just under age 50, within a tight window around the policy change. The identification assumption is that maximum contributors at ages 50-53 are (conditionally) identical to maximum contributors at ages 46-49, except that the older group faces a higher deferral limit. In that event, the differential increase in contributions for this older group from just before 2002 to just after is due to the adoption of the catch-up provision.

401(k) Deferral Limits Under defined contribution plans such as traditional 401(k)s, contributions are pre-tax, up to a deferral limit, and are only taxed at withdrawal. The contribution limits have long been adjusted for inflation but, in 2001, the federal government increased the limits at a faster rate through 2005. They also introduced a catch-up provision, establishing a higher contribution limit for workers age 50 and over. The idea behind the provision is that individuals, who may postpone saving for retirement when they are younger, need to step up their saving as their retirement age starts to loom larger. The basic contribution limit rose from $10,500 in 2001, just before the new law took effect, to $14,000 in 2005 while the allowable catch-up contribution increased from $0 to $4,000 during this period. For most people, contributing the maximum amount to a 401(k) in any year is not an easy task. Only about 9 percent of individuals in this paper s sample have 401(k) contributions within 10 percent of the deferral limit. The difference in mean earnings and wealth between max and non-max contributors is dramatic: max contributors earn about $163,000 and have a net worth of $439,000, compared to $57,000 and $200,000, respectively, for the full sample. Data and Methodology This study uses the SIPP Synthetic Beta (SSB), a data product that allows users to link the SIPP household survey to administrative earnings records without requiring access to the restricted data. The SIPP includes demographic and economic characteristics usually not available in an administrative dataset alone. The SSA administrative data to which the SIPP is linked provides information about total earnings and 401(k) contributions that are likely to be more accurate than self-reported information alone. The sample includes any individual matched to the SSA earnings records who was age 46-53 at some point between 1999 and 2005, excluding individuals with inconsistent work history over this period or who have a work-limiting health condition. Restricting the sample to this age range assures that differences in saving over the life-cycle are minimized. Analyzing a short window before the adoption of the catch-up provision (1999-2001), the year of its adoption (2002), and three years after its implementation (2003-2005) similarly minimizes differences over time due to the secular growth of 401(k) saving.

The dependent variables in the regressions are, separately, annual total tax-deferred earnings in 2005 dollars, or the contribution rate, i.e., the ratio of total deferred earnings to total earnings in that year. The regression is a linear triple-differences model, including the full combination of interactions of three indicator variables: whether the catch-up provision is in effect; whether an individual is age 50 or older; and whether an individual has made nearmaximum contributions in any prior year. A positive and statistically significant coefficient on the triple interaction between these variables indicates that previously constrained participants increase their contributions at age 50 by more than maximum-contributors under 50 after the adoption of the catch-up provision. The model also includes year dummies; demographics; educational attainment; earnings; net worth; presence of minor and college-aged children; and pension coverage during the SIPP sampling window. Some specifications include individual fixed effects, or separate indicators for each age from 47 to 53. Results The main estimates are summarized in Figure 1. The two bottom bars cover the workers not constrained by the deferral limit; both of these groups increase contributions by only a small, but statistically significant amount ($237-248) after the adoption of the catch-up provision. As expected, the story is much different for those workers near the maximum (the top two bars). Max workers under age 50 contribute a statistically significant $917 more after 2001 than non-max contributors in the same age group, for a total additional contribution of $1,166. This increase reflects that the contribution limit was increasing faster than inflation for all ages. The largest effect was for those max contributors who were 50 and over. Their total contribution increased by $1,697, or a statistically significant $543 more than similar workers just under age 50. This increase is 4.6 percent of the average maximum deferral level before the catch-up provision was adopted about $11,700. Adjusting for inflation, the deferral limit increased by 33 percent per year for participants age 50 and over, or 22 percentage points faster than the simultaneous increase in the limit for participants under age 50 (11 percent). The 4.6 percent increase in contributions represents 21 percent of the 22-percentage-point rise in the limit for the 50+ group; that is, the implied elasticity of retirement savings to the tax incentive is 0.21. Models with separate indicators for each age, or with individual fixed effects, estimate larger

differences between max contributors 50 and over relative to similar individuals under 50. While this group does not increase their contributions all the way up to the new limit, they appear to be somewhat sensitive to tax incentives to increase their 401(k) saving. Conclusion These results suggest that contributors near the maximum have excess capacity for further tax-deferred saving and appear to respond to changes in the statutory limit. But further work is needed to fully understand the implications of this increase in 401(k) contributions induced by the catch-up provision among previously constrained older workers. Researchers have reported conflicting evidence on the extent to which saving through private-sector DB and DC plans crowds out private saving. While this study finds that contributors near the maximum are somewhat sensitive to the maximum deferral, whether the increase in 401(k) contributions is a substitution from other accounts or an increase in total saving remains unclear. Furthermore, the increases in the tax-deferred maximum affect mostly high-income households; though this group is sensitive to these incentives, lower-income households are more constrained, so changing 401(k) limits would not likely provide a broad-based solution for low saving rates.

Figure 1. Predicted Increase in 401(k) Contributions from 1999-2001 to 2002-2005, 2005 $ Max contributors over 50 $248 $917 $543 $1,697 a Max contributors under 50 $248 $917 $1,166 Non-max contributors over 50 $248 $237 a Non-max contributors under 50 $248 $248 Year Year max Year age max $0 $1,000 $2,000 a For simplicity, the figure does not depict the impact of the (Year)(Age) interaction. This interaction reduces the predicted total increase in contributions by $11 for each of the two groups that include individuals age 50 and over. Source: Authors estimates from the SIPP Completed Data Files (1999-2005).