Financing from international aviation and shipping: turning an emissions problem into a revenue opportunity

Similar documents
Bunker Finance: a briefing for the High Level Advisory Group on Climate Change Financing

Response to UNFCCC Secretariat request for proposals on: Information on strategies and approaches for mobilizing scaled-up climate finance (COP)

G20 STUDY GROUP ON CLIMATE FINANCE PROGRESS REPORT. (November )

Alchemy Economics the UK government s conjuring trick to justify airport expansion"

WWF Expectations for the UNFCCC Durban Conference of Parties

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. Market-Based Instruments for International Aviation and Shipping as a Source of Climate Finance

Paris Legally Binding Agreement

EU 4 EU Emission Trading Scheme (2003/87/EC)

Adaptation for developing countries in a post-2012 UN Climate Regime

Financing Climate Change Adaptation and Mitigation in Africa: Key Issues and Options for Policy-Makers and Negotiators.

A systems perspective to marketbased measures (MBM) comparison

How to Mobilise USD 100 Billion?

Analysis Summary Consultation - SOU 2016:83 "A Swedish Aviation Tax"

Maritime Transport and the Climate Change Challenge

SUBMISSION BY IRELAND AND THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION ON BEHALF OF THE EUROPEAN UNION AND ITS MEMBER STATES

CONTRIBUTION TO THE REVISION OF THE ENERGY TAX DIRECTIVE

Applying the Principle of Common but Differentiated Responsibility to the Mitigation of Greenhouse Gases from International Shipping

3. The paper draws on existing work and analysis. 4. To ensure that this analysis is beneficial to the

Summary. 1. Aviation taxation. February a briefing by

Draft Policy Proposals on a Global MBM Scheme (GMBM) (As of 17 December 2015)

IPCC 44 October

ecbi policy brief International Air Passenger Adaptation Levy (IAPAL) European Capacity Building Initiative Thirteen Questions and Answers

HIGH-LEVEL MEETING ON A GLOBAL MARKET-BASED MEASURE SCHEME

DRAFT COMPROMISE AMENDMENTS 1-17

easyjet response to the Scottish government consultation on a Scottish replacement to Air Passenger Duty

ASSEMBLY 39TH SESSION

Our challenges and emerging goal State of affairs of negotiation towards Copenhagen Possible agreement in Copenhagen Conclusion: emerging feature of

DRAFT Decision 1/CP.15 (Decision 1/CMP.5 in separate document)

SUBMISSION BY DENMARK AND THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION ON BEHALF OF THE EUROPEAN UNION AND ITS MEMBER STATES

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Brussels, C (2011) 4932 final. State aid SA (2011/NN) Ireland Air Transport - Exemptions from air passenger tax

Climate change justice: an introduction

REVIEW PRACTICE GUIDANCE

Report of the High-level Advisory Group on Climate Change Financing

Main reasons for the changes introduced into the 1996 Convention by the 2010 Protocol

This document is meant purely as a documentation tool and the institutions do not assume any liability for its contents

WORK OF THE CONTACT GROUP ON ITEM 3 Section D

The Conference of Parties. Recalling Article 4, paragraphs 3, 4 and 5 of the Convention,

Periodic Review: Background and Analysis

15889/10 PSJ/is 1 DG G

OPINION OF ADVOCATE GENERAL KOKOTT delivered on 6 October 2011 (1) Case C 366/10. Air Transport Association of America and Others

ACI EUROPE POSITION on AVIATION TAXES IN THE EU Putting the economic recovery at risk

DECISIONS ADOPTED JOINTLY BY THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL

Share of Proceeds to assist in meeting the costs of adaptation. I. Background

Outcomes of COP17 and CMP7

GEF Policy Guidelines for the financing of biennial update reports for Parties not included in Annex I to the United Nations Framework Convention on

Relationship with UNFCCC and External Bodies

An equitable financial mechanism under the UNFCCC. The United Nations Climate Fund

Stephen Barrett, Technical Advisor, Consultant, ICAO

Climate finance in developing countries

Negotiating the. Indrajit Bose

Climate Finance: Issues and Opportunities. Presented by Jon Sohn February 2010 Airlie House, Virginia

Outcomes of the Twenty-first Session of the Conference of the Parties to the UNFCCC in Paris

Taking Forward the UK Climate Change Bill: The Government Response to Pre-Legislative Scrutiny and Public Consultation

AN OVERVIEW OF THE HNS CONVENTION

CARBON PRICING PRINCIPLES. Prepared by the ICC Commission on Environment and Energy

Chair s Summary Meeting of the Major Economies Forum September 22-23, 2016

Modalities and procedures for the new market-based mechanism

Q&A about the International Tourist Tax

AD HOC WORKING GROUP ON LONG-TERM COOPERATIVE ACTION UNDER THE CONVENTION Resumed seventh session Barcelona, 2 6 November 2009

Scaling voluntary action within the framework of the paris agreement

International Climate Policy & Carbon Markets

UNFCCC EXPERT MEETING TO ASSESS EXPERIENCES IN THE USE OF THE REPORTING AND REVIEW GUIDELINES. Bonn, Germany, 4 6 December 2001

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

Elements of a Trade and Climate Code

Some Aspects on Ongoing Climate Change Negotiations Africa s Perspective

Decision 3/CP.17. Launching the Green Climate Fund

COMMENTS ON BILL C-64 (AN ACT RESPECTING WRECKS, ABANDONED, DILAPIDATED OR HAZARDOUS VESSELS AND SALVAGE OPERATIONS

Organisation strategy for Sweden s cooperation with the Green Climate Fund for

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 11 May /10 ECOFIN 249 ENV 265 POLGEN 69

EU-Japan EPA SECTION A GENERAL PROVISIONS. Article 1 Objectives, coverage and definitions

Challenges in implementing SDGs, Paris Climate Agreement. Ms. Tuhina Sinha, Asst. Professor, SPA, JNAFAU, Hyderabad

2018 Interim Results Presentation Transcript

THE HNS PROTOCOL. by Dr. Rosalie P. Balkin Director Legal Affairs and External Relations Division International Maritime Organization

Mobilizing Resources for Climate Finance

Emissions Trading: What is it for? Where has it got to? What role for aviation?

Technical Information

7607/17 SH/iw 1 DGA 1B

Agenda item 3: Review of Progress made by the Task Force Teams

With this in mind, Carbon Market Watch makes the following recommendations to the development of guidance for Article 6, paragraph 2.

Submission to. Australia's Future Tax System

THE QUEEN on the application of PLAN B EARTH & OTHERS. - and - THE SECRETARY OF STATE FOR BUSINESS, ENERGY AND INDUSTRIAL STRATEGY.

Strategies and approaches for long-term climate finance

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

Options for Europe when acting alone on CO2 emissions from shipping

Grasping the nettle: Swedish tax to tackle aviation?s impact on climate

Fact sheet: Financing climate change action Investment and financial flows for a strengthened response to climate change

PROTECTION AND PRESERVATION OF THE MARINE ENVIRONMENT

Climate Change Litigation a global phenomenon. Presentation by Gillian Lobo Law & Environment Conference Lawyer, ClientEarth 26 April 2018

Official Journal of the European Communities

The Question of Transparency Article 13 of the Paris Agreement requires provision of information necessary to track progress in implementing NDCs.

PRACTICAL APPROACHES TO FINANCING AND EXECUTING CLIMATE CHANGE ADAPTATION

Value Added Tax. Your frequently asked questions answered

Outline. Setting the context. Setting the context 30/04/2016. Climate Justice

Questions and Answers: the consequences of the United Kingdom leaving the European Union without a ratified Withdrawal Agreement (no deal Brexit)

Note by the secretariat. Summary

International Policies and Cooperation to Advance an Inclusive Green Economy

A report prepared by COPE Solutions Inc.

Ordinance on the Reduction of CO2 Emissions. (CO 2 Ordinance)

Working Paper S e r i e s

regulation approach incentive approach

Transcription:

RECOMMENDATION PAPER 2010 Financing from international aviation and shipping: turning an emissions problem into a revenue opportunity December 2010 One of the most promising innovative sources of public financing for adaptation and mitigation actions in developing countries is from measures to address emissions from international aviation and shipping. This paper discusses the findings of the AGF on financing from aviation and maritime transport, and proposes options to ensure any such measures are compatible with the UNFCCC, including the responsibility of developed countries to provide financing for climate actions in developing countries, and the principal of common but differentiated responsibilities. Summary Emissions from international aviation and shipping must be controlled to give a good chance of limiting warming to 1.5 o C or 2 o C. Policies to control them could raise $24billion annually, according to the AGF. In WWF's view the large majority of this should be used for climate finance. Co-operative policies are in line with the UN Climate Convention, provided that developing countries incur no incremental costs (have 'no net incidence'). The best way to ensure this in the shipping sector is a universal mechanism with a rebate for developing countries to compensate for the impact on their trade. The best way to ensure this in the aviation sector is a policy limited to flights into and/or out of developed countries. The overall impacts of these policies would be very small: a reduction in trade of only 0.25% from a shipping mechanism. The COP should take a decision in Cancun that encourages swift action from ICAO and IMO to implement policies, and that generates revenue and channels it to climate finance. 1

Need to reduce emissions International aviation and shipping are major and fast-growing sources of greenhouse gas emissions. The sectors' combined emissions were over 1 GtCO 2 in 2007 and are expected to rise to around 1.7 GtCO 2 in 2020, not counting the additional non-co 2 warming impacts of aviation. Business-as-usual projections by the International Civil Aviation Organisation (ICAO) and International Maritime Organisation (IMO) suggest that in the absence of policies to control them, emissions could triple by 2050. Such unchecked emissions would take up a substantial proportion of any global carbon budget, and undermine the chances of avoiding temperature rises of 2 o C, let alone 1.5 o C. Bunker 1 Finance from mitigation policies for aviation and shipping sectors Measures that target these emissions, by putting a price on aviation and shipping carbon emissions, either through an Emissions Trading Scheme (both sectors) or a fuel levy (for shipping), could raise substantial revenues. These measures are under active discussion at IMO and ICAO. An air passenger levy (ticket tax) would target emissions less directly, but would still raise significant revenue. Money raised by any such measure could then be used to support climate change adaptation and mitigation in developing countries. The UN High-Level Advisory Group on Climate Finance (AGF) examined the possible revenues from the sectors. The AGF found that up to $18 billion could be raised overall from shipping and up to $6 billion from aviation, at a carbon price of $25/tCO2, but went on to state that only a quarter to a half of this revenue is likely to be used for climate finance yielding a range of $4-9 billion for climate from shipping and $2-3 billion from aviation. The AGF recommendations are examined in more detail below. Should measures be global or apply to developed countries only? Aviation and shipping are quintessentially global sectors and the bulk of their emissions take place in international waters or airspace. SBSTA first discussed the question of how to allocate these emissions to Parties in 1996, but there has been no substantive debate on the issue for several years. In effect, Parties are agreed that the emissions cannot be attributed to individual countries. With no agreed definition of which emissions belong to which Parties, it has proved difficult to design any policy that applies to 'Annex I emissions' only, since there is no way to decide what constitutes 'Annex I emissions'. The most appropriate place to tackle these emissions is by negotiating an outcome based on the mandate provided by paragraph 1 b (iv) of the Bali Action Plan, which seeks to implement Article 4 of the Convention on co-operative sectoral approaches. Article 4.1 of the Convention provides that 'all Parties shall promote and cooperate in the development, application and diffusion, including transfer, of technologies, practices and processes that control, reduce or prevent anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases [...] in all relevant sectors, including [...] transport'. Article 4.3 stipulates that developed country Parties 'shall also provide such financial resources, including for the transfer of technology, needed by the developing country Parties to meet the agreed full incremental costs of implementing measures' referred to in Article 4.1. Co-operative policies on bunker fuels, then, can: reduce greenhouse gas emissions; raise finance for climate action in developing countries; and be compatible with the Convention, provided that these policies conform to UNFCCC principles, including that of common but differentiated responsibilities and respective capabilities (CBDRRC), and that developing countries do not incur net costs as a result of measures to generate climate finance. The same concept is discussed in the AGF report in terms of ensuring 'no net incidence' on developing countries and this paper will adopt that terminology. 1 Bunkers is the term for the fuels used in international aviation and maritime transport. 2

Ensuring no net incidence on developing countries Net incidence on developing countries can be eliminated in one of two ways: restricting the scope of the policy, or compensating developing countries (separately to any climate finance element). The two sectors should be considered separately in order to find the most appropriate solution for each. In the case of shipping The IMO operates on the principle of 'no more favourable treatment of ships'. In other words, ships of all flags should be treated equally under any given policy. This is a strongly advisable approach, as it is very straightforward to change the flag of a ship. Already three-quarters of the global fleet is flagged in developing countries and the remaining quarter would readily re-flag if faced with a carbon cost applied only to Annex I ships. Although a majority of shipping is currently controlled by companies registered in Annex I countries, they could also quickly relocate if it became advantageous to do so. So nationality of ownership is of little benefit as a basis for differentiation. It has been suggested that policies could be applied only to ships sailing to Annex I ports. This might be feasible, but it could also invite evasion. For instance, a ship headed from Asia to Europe could dock briefly in North Africa, so that only emissions on its final leg fell within the policy. Applying the policy to emissions from any cargo destined for Annex I countries could get around this problem, but would be extremely complex, especially as in practice ships will often discharge part of their cargo and/or take on extra goods in one port, and then another, before continuing to their final destination. So for practical reasons it is preferable for any maritime policy to apply universally, and hence all options under discussion at IMO are global policies. One possible exception is to set a minimum ( de minimis ) threshold to exclude routes to the most remote island states. Such a measure would be very unlikely to lead to serious carbon leakage, but could serve to protect vulnerable countries most reliant on seaborne imports from any rise in the price of goods. (See 'Impacts' section below.) In the case of a universal maritime policy, net incidence on developing countries could be eliminated through a rebate mechanism. Funds from a fuel levy or auction revenues from an ETS would be collected centrally, and a proportion would be redistributed directly to developing country governments to offset the economic impact of the policy. In the proposal under discussion at IMO, the basis for this rebate is a country's share of global imports by value. (Other redistribution keys are possible, eg share of exports, or a weighted average of imports and exports.) So for example, assume a maritime policy raises $25 billion, and South Africa's share of global imports is 0.6%. South Africa would receive a rebate of $150 million from the central fund. The total rebate to all developing countries would be approximately 30% or $7.5 billion. The remaining revenue of $17.5 billion would be available for three purposes: climate finance; technology support for the maritime sector, and central government revenue. WWF believes that only a small slice (say 10%) should go to the shipping sector, and none to central governments (who accept no responsibility for the emissions). The AGF, however, assumes that only between 25% and 50% of revenues could be earmarked for climate finance. Thus their estimate is that shipping could generate $4-9 billion per year, when in fact it could generate $16 billion (with a further $2 billion supporting clean development of the maritime sector in developing countries). In the case of aviation ICAO operates a policy of 'non-discrimination' between airlines. This means it is not possible to apply a policy to airlines of one country but not another and in any case this would lead to a distortion where airlines compete on the same route. However, it is much more feasible in aviation than in shipping to apply a policy only on certain routes. The EU has studied the impacts of a regional ETS (all flights within, into and out of the EU) and concluded that any leakage or distortion is likely to be small. Aircraft cannot readily alter their routes in the way ships can, and it is uneconomical for them to carry more fuel than is needed for the current leg. 3

Therefore, to eliminate incidence on developing countries, the AGF suggests excluding all flights between developing countries, and half of flights between developed and developing countries (in practice, as almost all flights are return trips, it make little difference whether flights from developed into developing countries are excluded, or the other way around). This would be effective in eliminating incidence on developing countries, but it does reduce by around 50% the pool of emissions to which the policy applies reducing its environmental effectiveness. Another option is under discussion at ICAO. Resolution A37/17-2 [ref], passed by the recent ICAO Assembly (but subject to an unprecedented number of reservations by States) suggests an approach based on a de minimis threshold: states with less than 1% of global aviation activity would be exempt from market-based measures 2. This would mean that measures apply to only around 25% of States, but capture around 80% of emissions. Another benefit of this approach is that it is flexible over time. As a country develops in relative economic terms, its aviation sector may exceed the 1% threshold, triggering inclusion in the scheme. Whatever scope of emissions policies are applied to, the revenue generated will be subject to the same claims as for shipping: between climate finance, the aviation sector and governments. The AGF assumes again that only 25% to 50% could be made available to climate finance. Combined with the reduced scope of application, this reduces their estimates of revenues from aviation to $2-3 billion. If 90% of revenue is used for climate finance, with 80% of international aviation covered, around $6 billion could be generated for climate action. Impacts of mitigation schemes The overall impact of an aviation policy would be small, as a carbon price applied to tickets would only push up the price by a small fraction of their existing cost (examples given by the AGF are increases of 2% and 3%); it would be progressive, as it is overwhelmingly the globally wealthy who are able to afford air travel; and in any case it is feasible to restrict the scope of the policy to exclude any incidence on developing countries. A universal shipping policy would have some impact on trade, but studies to date suggest that the overall impact would be small. A recent study by a specially-convened IMO Expert Group stated that the overall reduction in trade would be below 0.2%; AGF put it at 0.25%. (This is partly because shipping is an extremely carbon efficient mode of transport per tonne-km, so imposing a carbon price leads to only a very small increase in the cost of a tonne of goods.) The distributional effects may be more noticeable. These occur when an exporter competes with a producer located in (or closer to) the target market. The increased cost of goods gives a marginal advantage to the local over the distant producer, and the effect varies with the elasticity of the good. In two examples quoted by the AGF: one would reasonably expect US consumers to pay the full cost of a carbon price on bunker fuels for both the laden voyages from the Middle East to the US and for the return journey of an oil tanker (reflecting the elasticity of demand and supply of oil). By contrast, Japanese auto exporters would be likely to bear at least some of the additional carbon cost of transport to the US reflecting the strong competition in the auto market from domestic US manufacturers and from other (closer) competing nations including in Europe. 3 Even where these effects occur, however, they are not likely to alter trade flows by more than a few percentage points, given the carbon efficiency of shipping and the low impact of a carbon price per tonne of goods moved. Gi (MARK What does gi MEAN HERE OR IS IT NOT MEANT TO BE THERE) 2 Unfortunately, the resolution applies the exemption to the aircraft carriers registered in those countries, which seems to fly in the face of ICAO's non-discrimination policy. An exemption for any flight to such a country would be a better measure, possibly combined with rules to exclude very small aircraft operators (as happens with the EU ETS). 3 AGF Workstream paper 2 on International Transport, page 12. http://www.un.org/wcm/webdav/site/climatechange/shared/documents/agf_reports/work_stream_2_intern ational_transport.pdf 4

A decision in Cancun ICAO and IMO are the bodies with the technical expertise to design and implement bunker policies, and discussions are already well advanced especially at IMO, where a number of substantive proposals have been thoroughly evaluated. ICAO's approach has been to focus on the political rather than the substantive elements of market-measures, and consensus has proved difficult to achieve, although the acknowledgement of regional measures in the recent Assembly resolution may open the way to action by a coalition of the willing. However, progress in IMO and ICAO remains much too slow, and they have been unable to resolve issues related to CBDR, on which they would benefit enormously from guidance from the COP. Therefore a COP 16 decision should express the following: Parties should co-operate to reduce international bunker emissions, working through ICAO and IMO. IMO and ICAO should be encouraged to develop as speedily as possible measures to reduce emissions. Ideally, as the body with overall responsibility for climate protection, the COP should set a target, or reserve the right to set a target in future. In developing policies, ICAO and IMO should be guided by their respective conventions and customary practices, while taking into account the interests of developing countries. This will give them the flexibility to develop appropriate solutions for their sectors, while ensuring there is no net incidence on developing countries. The vast majority of the revenues from such policies should be used for climate finance in developing countries. This will ensure that bunkers policies are not only neutral for developing countries, but generate a much-needed stream of revenue to finance adaptation and mitigation projects. Conclusion International aviation and shipping are mitigation problems of major concern they are large and fast-growing sources of emissions with no overall regulatory framework to control them. Policies to control them could pay a double dividend reducing emissions but also unlocking major flows of climate finance. Delivering such policies will require substantial political will, as the sectors are not amenable to rigid distinctions between Annex I and non-annex I. But since their emissions do not belong to any Party, co-operative action to tackle them need not set a precedent for the treatment of emissions that do belong to individual Parties. Furthermore, Article 4 of the Convention provides a clear mandate for such co-operative sectoral approaches, provided there is no net incidence on developing countries and this is feasible. Emissions problem or revenue opportunity? The choice is yours... Why we are here To stop the degradation of the planet s natural environment and to build a future in which humans live in harmony with nature. www.panda.org/climate Contact: Mark Lutes Finance Policy Coordinator WWF Global Climate Initiative E : mark.lutes@wwf.panda.org Mobile: +1 416 473 5919 WWF Registered Trademark Owner 1986, WWF World Wide Fund For Nature 2010, WWF All rights reserved (formerly World Wildlife Fund), Gland, Switzerland 5