NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON THE INTEREST RATE ELASTICITY OF THE DEMAND FOR INTERNATIONAL RESERVES: SOME EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Similar documents
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DEMAND FOR INTERNATIONAL RESERVES AND MONETARY EQUILIBRIUM: SOME EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPING COUNTRIES.

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SHORT-RUN RELATION BETWEEN INFLATION AND GROWTH IN LATIN AMERICA. Sebastian Edwards. Working Paper No.

Volume 35, Issue 1. Yu Hsing Southeastern Louisiana University

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY ON PRIVATE SAVING: THE TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

Chapter URL:

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

1) Real and Nominal exchange rates are highly positively correlated. 2) Real and nominal exchange rates are well approximated by a random walk.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

The purpose of this paper is to examine the determinants of U.S. foreign

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION

Incorporation of Fixed-Flexible Exchange Rates in Econometric Trade Models: A Grafted Polynomial Approach

1+R = (1+r)*(1+expected inflation) = r + expected inflation + r*expected inflation +1

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

On the Determinants of Exchange Rate Misalignments

Inflation, Inflation Uncertainty, Political Stability, and Economic Growth

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

International Tax Reforms with Flexible Prices

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: Oil Price Rise and Italy

The World Bank Revised Minimum Standard Model: Concepts and limitations

A SIMULTANEOUS-EQUATION MODEL OF THE DETERMINANTS OF THE THAI BAHT/U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Financial Liberalization and Money Demand in Mauritius

Paper Published in the February 2005 Journal of Business & Economic Research Why the Quantity of Money Still Matters

Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence

International Trade in Goods and Assets. 1. The economic activity of a small, open economy can affect the world prices.

THRESHOLD EFFECT OF INFLATION ON MONEY DEMAND IN MALAYSIA

Working Paper No. 2032

Determinant of Tax Buoyancy: Empirical Evidence from Developing Countries

The impact of changing diversification on stability and growth in a regional economy

What Can Macroeconometric Models Say About Asia-Type Crises?

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Are Devaluations Contractionary in LDCs?

Working Paper. An Analysis of Emerging Market Spreads NO.3. Shin Oya. November 2001 JBIC INSTITUTE JAPAN BANK FOR INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

THE BEHAVIOUR OF GOVERNMENT OF CANADA REAL RETURN BOND RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY

Market Value of the Firm, Market Value of Equity, Return Rate on Capital and the Optimal Capital Structure

DEMAND FOR MONEY. Ch. 9 (Ch.19 in the text) ECON248: Money and Banking Ch.9 Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi

DWI Exchange Rate Changes and Inflation in Developing Countries. Romeo M. Bautista and James Riedel. Public Disclosure Authorized DRAFT

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

Inflation in Latin America,

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119

Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence

Test of an Inverted J-Shape Hypothesis between the Expected Real Exchange Rate and Real Output: The Case of Ireland. Yu Hsing 1

Does an Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization Programme Help For Disinflation in Turkey?

Demand and Supply for Residential Housing in Urban China. Gregory C Chow Princeton University. Linlin Niu WISE, Xiamen University.

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS

working paper Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness By Bernardin Akitoby and Thomas Stratmann No.

Weak Policy in an Open Economy: The US with a Floating Exchange Rate, Henry Thompson

7) What is the money demand function when the utility of money for the representative household is M M

The Velocity of Money and Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Developed and Latin-American Countries

International Finance

Currency Substitution, Capital Mobility and Functional Forms of Money Demand in Pakistan

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

The Impact of Foreign Capital Transfers on Developing Country Agriculture. Donald W. Larson and Robert C. Vogel * ABSTRACT

Implications of Financial Repression on Economic Growth: Evidence from Nigeria

FOREIGN TRADE MULTIPLIER IN ROMANIA BEFORE AND AFTER ACCESSION TO THE EUROPEAN UNION

Inflation Uncertainty, Investment Spending, and Fiscal Policy

Relationship Between GDP, Inflation and Real Interest Rate with Exchange Rate Fluctuation of African Countries

Jeffrey Frankel s chapter is a useful summary and extension of results in

Policy Brief. Stabilizing Properties of Flexible Exchange Rates: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis. Number PB13-28 November 2013

Jacek Prokop a, *, Ewa Baranowska-Prokop b

A Reexamination of Balassa's Productivity Bias Hypothesis

Consumption expenditure The five most important variables that determine the level of consumption are:

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Demand for Money MV T = PT,

Test of the bank lending channel: The case of Hungary

Nonprofit organizations are becoming a large and important

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA?

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

3. TFU: A zero rate of increase in the Consumer Price Index is an appropriate target for monetary policy.

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

AN INVESTIGATION ON THE TRANSACTION MOTIVATION AND THE SPECULATIVE MOTIVATION OF THE DEMAND FOR MONEY IN SRI LANKA

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

1 Introduction. Domonkos F Vamossy. Whitworth University, United States

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

TECHNICAL TRADING AT THE CURRENCY MARKET INCREASES THE OVERSHOOTING EFFECT* MIKAEL BASK

Assessing Potential Inflation Consequences of QE after Financial Crises

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

Did the Swiss Demand for Money Function Shift? Journal of Economics and Business, 35(2) April 1983,

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE OF THE TRANSITION COUNTRY THE CASE OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC

Comments on Jeffrey Frankel, Commodity Prices and Monetary Policy by Lars Svensson

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF FEDERAL TAX DEDUCTIBILITY ON STATE AND LOCAL TAXES AND SPENDING. Gilbert Metcalf. Working Paper No.

Ever Closer to Heaven? An Optimum-Currency-Area Index for European Countries. Tamim Bayoumi and Barry Eichengreen 1 August 1996

Transcription:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON THE INTEREST RATE ELASTICITY OF THE DEMAND FOR INTERNATIONAL RESERVES: SOME EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Sebastian Edwards Working Paper No. 1532 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 January 1985 I am indebted to Michael Darby and two anonymous referees for help-. ful comments. The research reported here is part of the NBERts research program in International Studies and project in Productivity (World Economy). Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

NBER Working Paper #1532 January 1985 On the Interest Rate Elasticity of the Demand for International Reserves: Some Evidence from Developing Countries ABSTRACT Contrary to what is suggested by the theory, most empirical studies on the demand for international reserves have failed to find a significant (negative) coefficient for the opportunity cost of holding reserves. In this paper it is argued that the reason for this is that the opportunity cost of holding international reserves has been measured incorrectly. In the empirical analysis presented in this paper the spread between the interest rate at which countries can borrow from abroad and LIBOR is used as a proxy for the net opportunity cost for holding reserves. The results obtained using data for a group of developing countries for 1976198O show that when this net opportunity cost is used, the regression coefficient is significantly negative. Sebastian Edwards Department of Economics U.C.L.A. Los Angeles, CA 90024 (213) 825 1011

1 Theoretical studies on the demand for international reserves have generally postulated that the quantity of reserves demanded by a particular country will depend, in a negative way, on the opportunity cost of holding them.' Most empirical studies on the subject, however, have repeatedly failed to find a significant relation between international reserves and their opportunity cost. These results have puzzled for a long time economists that have analyzed international reserves behavior, and a number of possible explanations have been offered. For example, in his well known survey John Williamson writes: "Various proxies for [the opportunity cost of reserves holdings]... have been tried, with uniform lack of success. Possible explanations are that the proxies chosen are not good ones, that there is not in fact sufficient variation in the opportunity cost of reserve holding to permit statistical estimation, and that the interest elasticity of demand for reserves is low." (1973, page 696). Other authors Bird (1978, pp. 88 89), Frenkel (1984, P. 58) and Edwards (1983, p. 279), for example have discussed this apparent insensitivity of the demand for international reserves with respect to their opportunity cost. As a result of these findings in most recent empirical studies the opportunity cost variable has been dropped from the regression analysis of the demand for international reserves.2 In this paper the empirical relationship between the demand for international reserves and the opportunity cost of holding them is reexamined. It is argued that since international reserves are usually held in the form of short term interest bearing assets, the appropriate opportunity cost of holding them is a net cost, which should be computed as the gross income forgone by holding reserves minus the return obtained from holding them.3 The analysis is performed using data from 17 developing countries for 1976 1980, and the results obtained indicate that when a net cost is used as

2 the appropriate opportunity cost, the corresponding demand elasticity is in most cases significantly negative as predicted by the theory. I. The Opportunity Cost of Holding International Reserves One of the most difficult problems in the empirical analysis of international reserves behavior has been to find an adequate measure for the opportunity cost of holding them. Some authors lkenen and Yudin (1965), Kelly (1970)1 have used income per capita as a proxy, and have found that its regression coefficient has the "wrong" sign. Hipple (1974), on the other hand, used the inverse of the gross marginal capital output ratio as a proxy for the opportunity cost of holding reserves, and found that the regression coefficients either had the "wrong" sign or were insignificant. Courchene and Youssef (1967) and Frenkel and Jovanovic (1981) have used the domestic rate of interest as a proxy. While Courchene and Youssef (1967) found that in most cases the regression coefficients were insignificant, Frenkel and Jovanovic found a marginally significant negative elasticity of the demand for reserves with respect to its opportunity cost. Other authors [i.e, Clark (1970b); Frenkel (1978, 1980); Bilson and Frenkel (1979); Heller and Kabn.(197); Edwards (1980, 1983)] have simply decided to drop the opportunity cost variable from their empirical analyses. An important aspect of the opportunity cost of holding reserves, that has been generally ignored in empirical studies, is that international reserves are usually held in the form of short term interest bearing assets.4 This means that the actual opportunity cost of holding reserves is not, as most authors have assumed, the (social) marginal product of capital in the country under consideration. The correct measure of this opportunity cost will be a net cost, given by the difference between the domestic marginal product of

3 capital which will capture the gross forgone income from holding resources in the form of international reserves, and the return obtained from holding the reserves. From the perspective of empirical analysis, however, there are nontrivial difficulties in computing adequate series for the net opportunity cost of holding reserves. These difficulties are particularly serious for the case of develop4ng countries. First, in most LDC's there are no reliable data on the marginal product of capital, or on other alternative uasures for the gross forgone income of holding reserves.5 Second, there are no data available on the composition of reserves, or on the return obtained from these holdings. For this reason, any attempt to empirically analyze the relation between the demand for reserves and its net opportunity cost requires finding a proxy for this net opportunity cost. In this paper this problem is handled in the following form: First it is assumed that, in equilibrium, the gross forgone income from holding one unit of international reserves can be approximated by the cost at which that country borrows from the international financial market. This assumption follows from the well known principle that countries will borrow from abroad as long as the cost of borrowing is lower or equal to the (social) marginal productivity of those funds.6 This is a convenient assumption, since it is possible to obtain historical data on the cost of borrowing from Euromarkets for a number of developing countries [see for example, World Bank). Second, with respect to the return obtained on reserves holdings, it is assumed that non gold reserves earn a rate equal to LIBOR. This seems to be an appropriate assumption since reserves are usually held in the form of highly liquid assets, which earn a fairly low return. Cline (1983), for example, has recently assumed that non gold reserves holdings by developing countries earn

4 1.5 percentage points below LIBOR. In the present study, then, it is assumed that the net cost of holding reserves can be proxied by the differential between the cost of foreign borrowing and the LIBOR rate.7 In section II the results obtained from estimating demand for reserves functions for a group of 17 LDC's during 1976 1980 using this measure of the net opportunity cost are presented. II. Empirical Results Most studies on the subject have assumed that the demand for reserves is a stable function of a small number of variables. In particular, it has generally been assumed that the demand for reserves will depend positively on the scale of the country (usually measured by GNP, y); positively on the degree of opennes (usually proxied by the average propensity to import, m); positively on the degree of variability of international payments (usually measured as the coefficient of variation of export earnings, a); and negatively on the opportunity cost of holding reserves.8 It should be noted that some authors (Heller 1966, Reller and I1In 1978) have postulated that the coefficient of the propensity to import in should be negative. Initially this view was the dominant one. More recently however, this view has been superseded on the basis of empirical evidence and the realization that the sign of the openness variable will depend on whether expenditure switching or expenditure reducing policies are being pursued. Generally speaking, the results obtained from the estimation of demand for reserves functions have been quite satisfactory, with most of the regression coefficients with the exception of the opportunity cost variable being significant and of the expected sign. These empirical studies, however, have generally been more successful for the case of industrialized

5 countries. In the case of developing countries it has been found that for the more recent period the coefficients of the openness variables and of a have not been significant [Frenkel 1980, Edwards 1984b]. In this section results from the estimation of a demand function for international reserves for a group of 17 developing countries for 1976 1980 are presented. Following the literature on the subject it is assumed that the demand for reserves (R) can be written in the following form: log R = + log )T + 2 log in + $3 log a + $4 log r + w (1) where, as before, y is GNP expressed in U.S. dollars; in is the average propensity to import; a is the standard error of the log of detrended export earnings; r is the net opportunity cost of holding reserves, and for each country it is measured as the difference between the cost of foreign borrowing and LIBOR; and w is an error term with the usual properties. It is expected that $1>0, $2>0, $3>0 and $4<0. The following countries were included in the estimation: Greece, Portugal, Spain, Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Panama, Uruguay, Venezuela, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand.arid Morocco. The countries' selection was based on data availability; these are the only developing countries for which data on the spread over LIBOR and GNP were available for all the years considered in this study. See the Appendix for the data sources. Equations of the type of (1) have usually been estimated using OLS on cross sections for each year (Frenkel 1974). In the present case, however, the use of OLS is inappropriate since there is evidence that suggests that the spread between the cost of borrowing and LIBOR (r) will be affected by the international reserves to GNP ratio (Edwards 1984a). For this reason a

6 - simultaneous procedure should be used in the estimation of (1). Table 1 presents the results obtained from the estimation of equation (1) using two stages least squares, for each year. Since the errors for each cross section equation are likely to be correlated across years (Frenkel, 1978), a joint generalized least squares procedure, that takes into account the error covariance across equations, was also used.' The results obtained in this case are reported in Table 2. As may be seen the results obtained are quite interesting. First, contrary to previous results it is shown that for most of the years considered the coefficient of the net cost of holding reserves is significantly negative at the conventional levels. Furthermore, the estimated elasticities of the demand for reserves with respect to the net opportunity cost are quite large in absolute terms, indicating that monetary authorities will generally undertake substantial adjustments in their reserves holdings when the (net) opportunity cost changes. Also these results indicate that the elasticity of the demand for reserves with respect to income is not significantly different from one. This contrasts with previous results that suggested that during the Bretton Woods system there were diseccsnomies of scales in the holding of international reserves by developing countries (Edwards 1983, 1984c). The coefficient of the variability term c is never significantly different from zero. This coincides with previous findings reported by Frenkel (1978) for an earlier period, and indicates that during the recent period these LDC's have not taken into account the variability of their export earnings when determining the amount of reserves they want to hold. Regarding the openness variable in, its estimated coefficient is not significant at the conventional levels.11

/ Table 1 The Demand for International Reserves by Developing Countries 1976 1980: (Two Stages Least Squares) 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 constant 0.641 (0.316). 0.079 (0.046) 1.503 ( 0.957) 0-089 ( 0.042) 0.788 ( 0.367) log y 0.871 (3.771) 0.789 (3.791) 0.897 (4.417) 0.601 (2.052) 0.666 (2.550) log tn 0.218 (0.436) 0.477 ( 0.905) 0.168 (0.329) 0,541 ( 0,823) 0.281 ( 0.478) log a fl 0.187 (0.326) 0.158 (0.292) 0.067 (-0.140) 0.111 (0.231) 0.220 (-0.530) log r 3.066 ( 2.086) 3.105 ( 2.443) 1.201 ( 1.618) 2.471 ( 1.865) 1.726 ( 1.853) F 8.94 14.00 14.09 12.25 9.67 R2 0.765 0.836 0.837 0.817. 0.779 SEE 0.745 0.600 0.566 0.632 0.686 Notes: t statistics in parentheses.

8 Table 2 The Demand for International Reserves by Developing Countries 1976 1980: (Jointly Generalized Least Squares) 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 constant 0.299 (0.172) 0.323 (0.221) 1.442 ( 1.041) 0.879 ( 0.529) 0.412 ( 0.216) log y1 0.875 (4.397) 0.842 (5.139) 0.925 (6.028) 0.813 (4.203) 0.733 (3.442) log tn 0.225 (0.555) 0.l74 ( 0.487) 0.310 (0.918) 0.050 ( 0.210) 0.139 ( 0.308) log a ' 0.279 (0.653) 0.292 (0.741) 0.009 (0.242) 0.200 (1.304) 0.122 (0.354) log r 2.121 ( 2.951) 1.564 ( 3.020) 0.122 ( 0.272) 0.934 ( 2,479) 0.946 ( 1.966) Weighted SEE for system = 1.006 Weighted R2 for system = 0.669

9 It should be noted that the period considered in this study (1976 1980) was characterized by rapid changes in the world economy the dollar sharply depreciated in real terms, the second oil shock took place, and there were dramatic changes in the terms of trade between developing and industrial countries. Possibly, those rapidly changing conditions in the world economy explain why the hypothesis of a stable demand for reserves across time was rejected (i.e., these equations cannot be pooled). This contrast with my previous findings (Edwards 1983) using data for 1964 1972, where I showed that the demand for reserves had been stable across time for a larger group of developing countries. There is, however, an alternative explanation to the results reported in Tables 1 and 2. If when a country runs short of reserves it decides to rebuild them using foreign borrowing instead of reducing absorption or devaluing its currency, one would observe, as in these tables, a negative relation between the cost of foreign borrowing (i.e., the spread over LIBOR) and reserve holdings. This interpretation, however, assumes that reserves and debt are "complements' in the adjustment process. There is, however, some evidence suggesting that, in the case of developing countries, international reserves and foreign borrowing have been used as "substitutes" during the adjustment process. [See Eaton and Gersovjtz (1980) and Edwards (l984b)]. III. Concluding Remarks Contrary to what is suggested by the theory, most empirical studies on the demand for international reserves have failed to find a significant (negative) coefficient for the opportunity cost of holding reserves. In this paper I have argued that the most likely reason for this is that the opportunity cost of holding international reserves has been measured incorrectly as

10 the gross forgone income from holding international liquidity. I have argued that since reserves are usually held in the form of short term interest bearing assets, the appropriate cost of holding reserves is a net cost given by gross forgone income minus the return obtained from the holding of reserves. In the empirical analysis presented in this paper I have suggested that the gross forgone income can be approximated by the interest rate at which a particular country can borrow in the international capital market. The reason for this is that in equilibrium a country will borrow abroad until the domestic (social) marginal productivity of capital is equal to the rate at which it can borrow. On the other hand I have assumed that the return obtained on reserve holdings can be approximated by LIBOR. Consequently, in the estimations of the demand function for reserves the spread charged over LIBOR has been used as a proxy for the net opportunity cost of holding reserves. The empirical results obtained using data for 17 developing countries for 1976 1980 indicate that when this net opportunity cost is used in the analysis, a significantly negative coefficient, as suggested by the theory, is found. Regarding the other determinants of the demand for international reserves the results obtained tend to confirm, previous findings.

11 Appendix Data Sources tape. All raw data, except spreads over LIBOR, have been taken from the IFS International Reserves: Total reserves minus gold as given by line 1l.d of TD Income: Measured as GNP in domestic currency units, converted into U.S. dollars using the average exchange rate. The raw data was taken from the IFS tape. Average Propensity to Import: Defined as the ratio of imports (line 7l.d of the IFS) to GNP. Variability Measure (c) : is measured as the mean square error of the regression of the log of exports on time over the previous ten years. Spread (r): Measured as a weighted average of spreads paid on publicized public and publicly. guaranteed Eurodollar loans. The raw data was obtained from various issues of the World Bank's Borrowing in International Capital Markets. See Edwards (l984a) for details.

12 Footnotes 'Most studies on the demand for international reserves have assumed that reserves are held both to finance international transactions and as a buffer stock to face unexpected payments difficulties. These studies have assumed that the demand for international reserves is a stable function of a small number of variables. For reviews of the literature on the demand for reserves see, for example, Clower and Lipsey (1968), Gruebel (1971), Williamson (1973), Ripple (1974), Edwards (1984b) and Frenkel (1984). 2See, for example, Frenkel (1974, 1978, 1980, 1984), Bilson and Frenkel (1979), Edwards (1983), and Reller and Kahn (1978). It should be noted, however, that in a recent study Frenkel and Jovanovic (1981) found that the opportunity cost of holding reserves was marginally significant in their regression analysis. lyoha (1976) also claimed to have found a significant coefficient for the opportunity cost variable. His results, however, have been critized by Hipple (1979) and Shinkai (1979). 3on this point see, for example, the discussions in Darby (1983), Edwards (1983, 1984b), and Frenkel (1984). - 41t is important to point out that while empirical studies have tended to ignore the net cost of holding reserves, analytical discussions on the subject have sometimes recognized this fact. See, for example, Reller (1966), Ripple (1974), Darby (1983), Frenkel (1984) and Edwards (1983). See also Cline (1983). 5The problem, of course, is that in most developing countries the domestic capital market is usually "repressed" and there are no reliable data on domestic interest rates.

13 6 the relation between the cost of foreign borrowing and the domestic marginal product of capital see, for example, Thirwall, (1978, p. 298 300) and Williamson (1983, pp. 108 119). 7Since the countries considered in this study are small open economies, the opportunity cost measure the difference between the borrowing rate and LIBOR can be interpreted as a risk factor. In this case, the spread over LIBOR will be an adquate measure of the opportunity cost only if, as has been suggested by Harberger (1976, 1980) among others, lenders and borrowers have different perceptions regarding the probability of default. In particular, if as Harberger (1980, p. 336) suggests borrowers perceive a lower probability of default than lenders, these small countries will face an upward sloping supply curve for foreign funds, and the spread over LIBOR will be an appropriate proxy for the net opportunity cost of holding reserves. 8See, for example, the discussions in Gruebel (1971), Williamson (1973), Hipple (1974), Frenkel (1984) and Edwards (l984b). As mentioned, however, most of the recent empirical studies have dropped the opportunity cost variables. Also, empirical studies have shown that there was a structural shift in the demand for reserve functions around 1973, when the international monetary system abandoned fixed parities and moved towards greater exchange rate flexibility. 91n the estimations reported in Table 1 the following instruments were used: debt output ratio; average duration of foreign loans obtained by each country; average value of foreign loans; investment GDP ratio; current account to GNP ratio, y, m and a. The estimation reported in Table 2 amounts to re estimating simultaneously the equations reported in Table 1 for all years, taking into account the errors' covariance across years. These results include the most recent data available. The reason for this is that in 1981

14 the World Bank suspended the publication of Borrowing in International Capital Markets. For some of the years data were available for a larger number of countries. The results obtained in this case not reported here due to space considerations, but available from the author on request basically confirmed the conclusions discussed in this paper. 1 It should be noted that the results obtained were somewhat sensitive to the instruments used. In particular, when some of the instruments listed in footnote 9 were dropped, the signs and t statistics of some of the variables changed. Surprisingly, (sadly?), the problem of choosing instruments, performing and reporting sensitivity analyses under different sets of instruments has been largely neglected by econometricians. 11See von Furstenberg's (1982) recent study on the demand for reserves during the recent period, for time series regressions that include the terms of trade and other cyclical variables.

15 REFERENCE S Bilson, John F.0. and Jacob A. Frenkel, "Dynamic Adjustment and the Demand for International Reserves," NBER Working Paper 403 (September 1979). Bird, Graham, The International Monetary System and the Less Developed Countries, London: MacMillan, 1978. Clark, Peter E., "Demand for International Reserves: A Cross Country Analysis," Canadian Journal of Economics, 3 (November 1970), 577 594. Cline, William, International Debt and the Stability of the World Economy, Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1983. Clower, Robert and Richard Lipsey, "The Present State of International Liquidity Theory," American Economic Review, 58 (May 1968), 586 595. Darby, Michael R., "The United States as an Exogenous Source of World Inflation Under the Bretton Woods System," in M.R. Darby et. al. The International Transmission of Inflation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983. Eaton, Jonathan and Mark Gersovitz, "LDC Participation in International Finania1 Markets: Debt and Reserves" Journal of Development Economics, (March 1980), pp. 3 21. Edwards, Sebastian, "A Note on the Dynamic Adjustment of the Demand for International Reserves by LDC's," Economic Letters, 5 (1980), 71 74. "The Demand for Reserves and Exchange Rate Adjustments: The Case of LDC's, 1964 1972," Economica, 50 (August 1983), 269 280. "LDC's Foreign Borrowing and Default Risk: An Empirical Investigation 1970 1980," American Economic Review, forthcoming, (1984a).

16, "The Role of International Reserves and Foreign Debt in the Adjustment Process," in Adjustment, Conditionality and International Financing, Edited by the IMP, (Washington, D.C. IMF, 1984b). "The Demand for International Reserves and Monetary Equilibrium: Some Evidence from LDC's," Review of Economics and Statistics, (fortcoming 1984c). Frenkel, Jacob A., "The Demand for International Reserves by Developed and Less Developed Countries," Economica, 41 (February 1974), 14 24. "International Reserves: Pegged Excthange Rates and Managed Float," in Brunner, K., and Meltzer, A.H., (eds.), Economic Policies in Open Economies in supplementary series to Journal of Monetary Economics, North Holland, 1978, 111 140. "The Demand for International Reserves Under Pegged and Flexible Exchange Rates and Aspects of the Economics of Managed Float," in D. Bigman and T. Taya (eds.), The Function of Floating Exchange Rates, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, 1980. "International Liquidity and Monetary Control," in George von Furstenberg (ed.), International Money and Credit: The Policy Roles, (Washington, D.C. IMF: 1984). and Boyan Jovanovic, "Optimal International Reserves: A Stochastic Framework," Economic Journal, 91 (June 1981), 507 14. Gruebel, Herbert C., "The Demand for International Reserves: A Critical Review of the Literature," Journal of Economic Literature, 9 (December, 1971), 1148 1166. Harberger, Arnold C., "On Country Risk and the Social Cost of Foreign Borrowing by Developing Countries," unpublished ms., University of Chicago, 1976.

17 "Vignettes on the World Capital Market," American Economic Review, 70 (May 1980), 331 337. Heller, H. Robert, "Optimal International Reserves," Economic Journal, 76, (June 1966), 296 311. and Mohsin S. Kahn, "The Demand for International Reserves Under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rates," IMF Staff Papers, 25 (December 1978), 623 49. Hippel, F. Steb, The Disturbance Approach to the Demand for International Reserves, Studies in International Finance No. 35, N.J., 1974. "A Note on the Measurement of the Holding Cost of International Reserves," Review of Economics and Statistics, (November 1979): 612 14. lyoha, Milton A., "Demand for International Reserves by Less Developed Countries: A Distributed Lag Specification," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 58 (August 1976), 351 55. Kenen, Peter B. and Elionor B. Yudin, "The Demand for International Reserves," Review of Economics and Statistics, 47 (August 1965), 242 250. Shinkai, Y., "Demand for International Reserves in Less Developed Countries: Comment," Review of Economics and Statistics (November l979) 614 15. Thiriwall, A.P., Growth and Development, 2nd ed. (MacMillan, London 1978). von Furstenberg, George M., "New Estimates of the Demand for Non gold Reserves Under Floating Exchange Rates," Journal of International Money and Finance, (April 1982), 81 96. Williamson, John, "International Liquidity: A Survey," Economic Journal, 83 (1973), 685 746. The Open Economy and the World Economy, (New York: Basic Books 1983). World Bank: Borrowing in International Capital Markets (various issues).