Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Similar documents
THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Modelling economic scenarios for IFRS 9 impairment calculations. Keith Church 4most (Europe) Ltd AUGUST 2017

Monetary policy, asset prices, and uncertainty

Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

1 Introduction. Term Paper: The Hall and Taylor Model in Duali 1. Yumin Li 5/8/2012

Monetary Policy Analysis. Bennett T. McCallum* Carnegie Mellon University. and. National Bureau of Economic Research.

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

Inflation Targeting and Optimal Monetary Policy. Michael Woodford Princeton University

Monetary Policy. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

The Zero Lower Bound

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment

Topic 3: Endogenous Technology & Cross-Country Evidence

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

R-Star Wars: The Phantom Menace

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

The Chinese impact on GDP growth and inflation in the industrial countries

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

Current balance %points GDP Real Effective exchange rate % points diff Price Level % diff GDP Growth % points diff. Year

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

COMMENTS ON MONETARY POLICY UNDER UNCERTAINTY IN MICRO-FOUNDED MACROECONOMETRIC MODELS, BY A. LEVIN, A. ONATSKI, J. WILLIAMS AND N.

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

A portfolio approach to the optimal funding of pensions

Output gap uncertainty: Does it matter for the Taylor rule? *

SOLUTION Fama Bliss and Risk Premiums in the Term Structure

University of Wollongong Economics Working Paper Series 2008

MONETARY POLICY, PRICE STABILITY AND OUTPUT GAP STABILISATION

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

GPD-POT and GEV block maxima

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Monetary Policy in Pakistan: Confronting Fiscal Dominance and Imperfect Credibility

Commentary. Olivier Blanchard. 1. Should We Expect Automatic Stabilizers to Work, That Is, to Stabilize?

How to Pay for the Crisis

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Income Tax Cuts and Inflation in Ireland

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Choosing the Regime in an Uncertain World, The UK and Monetary Union 1

Monetary policy regime formalization: instrumental rules

Linking Microsimulation and CGE models

Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank

Money, Sticky Wages, and the Great Depression

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

MODELLING VOLATILITY SURFACES WITH GARCH

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

Introducing OLG-CGE modelling and the National institute General Equilibrium model for studying population Ageing, NiAGE

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

The science of monetary policy

An Illustrative Calculation of r

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018

A Singular Achievement of Recent Monetary Policy

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

Debt Sustainability and Exchange Stabilisation: Towards a New Theory

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Perspectives on the Current Stance of Monetary Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Multistep prediction error decomposition in DSGE models: estimation and forecast performance

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Uncertainty about Perceived Inflation Target and Stabilisation Policy

Transcription:

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model R. Barrell S.G.Hall 3 And I. Hurst Abstract This paper argues that the dominant practise of evaluating the properties of feedback rules in stochastic models using marginal distributions of the variables of interest implies the loss of considerable information. It argues that it is both practical and important to base decisions on the full joint density function. This argument is illustrated by comparing the properties of three rules applied to a large stochastic model under rational expectations. Word count:,535. National Institute of Economic and Social Research. Dept of Economics, University of Leicester. 3. Corresponding Author, NIESR, Dean Trench St. Smith Sq. London SWP 3HE, UK We gratefully acknowledge the support of the ESRC under Grant No. L3850. Final responsibility for the contents of this paper rest solely with the authors

. Introduction There has been an enormous literature in recent years examining the properties of various policy feedback rules in a stochastic environment. Here we list only a few key references, Taylor 993, 999, Svenson 997, Woodford 003, Svenson and Woodford,00, Orphanides and Williams 00, Fuhrer 997, Giannoni 00. One almost universal feature of this literature is that where an author considers a stochastic model decisions are based on the marginal distribution of the endogenous variables and the joint distribution is ignored. That is to say we might look at the variance of output and the variance of inflation but we would not consider the joint distribution of output and inflation. In this paper we argue a conceptually very simple point. The marginal distribution conceals a great deal of interesting information which is contained in the full joint distribution. Very often in standard analysis we are forced to assign largely arbitrary weights to policy objectives so as to trade them of against each other. However when we understand the full joint distribution a policy maker is presented with a much richer information set about the possible outcomes and often this may make the choice of an appropriate policy rule much easier. The next section then sets out a framework which contrasts the information in the marginal and joint distribution. Section 3 then shows how this information can be used in a practical investigation of the National Institute s NIGEM model under three alternative policy rules. Finally section 4 concludes.. A Formal Framework When we consider the above referenced literature on monetary rules and stabilisation policy the essence of the problem is that we are attempting to evaluate a density subject to certain assumptions about either the structure or the parameterisation of a particular rule. Formally this amounts to analysing how probability forecasts for a set of variables might change as the rule changes. So assume that we are concerned with the m-variable vector, z t =(z t,z t,,z mt ) and that the density is evaluated subject to a parametric model M (φ ) where φ is the parameterisation of the model. We assume that this parameterisation is general enough so that any rules being considered can be viewed as specific parameterisations of the general model M. The possible different density functions produced by different values of φ can then be characterised by assuming that φ lies in a compact parameter space Φ. Then, M φ) = { f ( z, z... z ; Φ), φ }. (, T Φ This may be factorised to consider various density function of interest (see Garrat, Lee, Pesaran and Shin(003)), we might factorise it sequentially to give the conditional distribution of z s conditional on all earlier z values, this would correspond to the density of a standard VAR analysis. We could decompose z into exogenous and endogenous variables (x and y) and derive the density function of the y variables jointly conditional on the x s. What is conventionally done in the monetary policy literature however is to calculate the marginal distribution of individual z s, that is if we define the marginal distribution of z it to be F(z it ) then

F ( znt )... f ( z, z,... zt ; ) dzij i =... m, j =... T, i, j n, = φ t. If the z s are independent then f ( z, z... z ; φ ) = F( z ) 3., T ij i = j = m T And the set of marginal distributions carries all the information which is of interest in the joint distribution. However if this independence does not hold then there is no simple relationship between the joint probability distribution and the set of marginal distributions. Indeed in the typical applications in the monetary rules literature it seems unlikely that outcomes for inflation and the output gap will be independent. Hence the concentration on marginal distributions may be significantly distorting the results. It is however possible to define the probability of a particular joint set of events occurring. So suppose a joint event was defined as ϑ z, z,... zt ; ) < a 4. ( φ Then we can define the probability of this joint event occurring by π a, ϑ) = Pr[ ϑ( z, z,... z ) < a M ( )] 5. ( T Φ While the marginal distributions are normally what is calculated in the Monte Carlo analysis it is actually very straightforward to also calculate this joint probability from a Monte Carlo experiment. Justifying the use of the full distribution should hardly need further elaboration from one viewpoint. For example Woodford(003, pg. 386, equation.3)) states a taylor series approximation to a general welfare criterion as; 3 U + U x E( x) + tr( U xx var( x)) + tr( U xξ cov( ξ, x)) + tr( U ξξ var( ξ ) + Ο( ϕ, ξ ) 6. Using his notation, where the crucial thing from our point of view is that var is the complete variance-covariance matrix. However a lot of the literature relies on a utility based welfare criterion which explicitly derives a welfare function involving only the variance of the output gap and the variance of inflation. The derivation of this criterion is surveyed in Woodford(003, pages 39-463). In brief it proceeds from stating that the natural welfare function should be derived from a representative agent s utility function which is a function of consumption and the disutility of labour. A series of simplifying assumption are then made which eventually allow this to be represented approximately only by the two variances. Justifying the relevance of the joint density function can then be done by either questioning the initial assumption that welfare is only a function of the representative utility or questioning the specific assumptions made in the formal derivation. The first of these avenues would include arguing that governments often care about the degree of dispersion of individual income outcomes around the average as well as the average level of income. The second would lead us to question such assumptions as the idea that the natural level of output 3

is independent of the variance of output and inflation or that there is no hysterises in the system. For instance, Byrne and Davis(004), show that the equilibrium level of investment and capital stock and hence output in the US depends upon the volatility of inflation. Hence the level of welfare using a utility function based only on consumption will depend upon the variance of inflation. Even if we accept the formal derivation of the simple welfare fuction policymakers may still be interested in knowing what to expect in terms of different combinations of output and inflation. The full density function may also be of use in model evaluation and matching stylised facts of the real world of course. 3. Results In order to illustrate the relevance of the general points made above we now use the National Institutes world model NIGEM in some stochastic simulations where we test 3 different rules for stabilising inflation and output in the European Monetary Union area. The first rule reflects the framework adopted by the European Central Bank where there is a nominal target (in their case M3, in ours nominal GDP, P t Y t ) and an inflation target which may be described as a Wicksellian rule. * * * r t t t t t = 0.5(log( P Y ) log( P Y )) + 0.75 ( log P log P ) 7: This rule is contrasted with two different Taylor rules that feedback on the output gap and inflation. The nominal target rule (7) differs from (8) in an important way as when output returns to its natural rate after a shock (7) ensures that the actual price level also returns to its previous level, ensuring that the target nominal aggregate for GDP is maintained. Rule 8 leaves the price level to be determined by the scale of the shock, the parameters of the feedback rule and the speed of response of the economy to the shock (see woodford(003), pg. 9). * * r t t t = γ (log( Y ) log( Y )) + γ ( log P log P ) 8 The Taylor Rule coefficients start with the industry standard 0.5 on output and.5 on inflation (Rule ). Our alternative has an increased weight on GDP at γ =. 5 (rule 3) with that on inflation at.5. These rules are then compared using stochastic simulations on NiGEM, which is a large, estimated and calibrated New Keynesian global model. The stochastic simulations use bootstrapping to apply equation residuals recovered from 99q to 999q4 to the forecast baseline. There are of course many ways to illustrate the joint density function, in a welfare context we could consider the normal variances and also the covariance of the joint distribution. However for illustrative purposes we feel that it emphasises the information coming from the joint distribution if we consider a set of target ranges. We therefore set up two targets which we wish to achieve, Inflation should be stabilised to within 0.3% of its target value and GDP We are grateful to an anonymous referee for this point. For more details of the model and a more extensive investigation of policy rules using this model see Barrell and Pina(004)) 4

should also be within 0.5% of its target value. Table summarises information from the marginal and joint distributions. Table. Summary Density Indicators Both fail GDP pass INF pass Both Pass INF only GDP only Combined Rule (rule ) year 0.393 0.33 0.480 0.05 0.76 0.6 mean 0.496 0.47 0.356 0.00 0.56 0.47 Standard Taylor Rule (rule ) year 0.393 0.333 0.450 0.76 0.74 0.57 mean 0.489 0.48 0.36 0.098 0.6 0.50 Output focused Taylor Rule (rule 3) year 0.404 0.393 0.403 0.0 0.0 0.93 mean 0.45 0.3 0.35 0.5 0.37 0.96 The mean is calculated over 5 years cols++3-4 =, cols +4+5+6= We are now able to analyse the decision problem faced by the policy maker much more fully. If we are interested in maximising the pass rate for inflation on average over the simulation we would pick rule while if we are interested in GDP we would pick rule 3. The choice between the two rules is then far from obvious. However the joint probability of meeting both targets is maximised by rule 3 suggesting that this rule might be preferable. Similarly rule 3 minimises the probability of missing both targets. There is still a normative element in the choice but the extra information provided by the joint density is useful we would argue. 4.Conclusion In this paper we have argued that the joint probability distribution of a number of policy objectives contains considerable information which is unavailable if we only consider the marginal distributions as is the case with almost all current work. We have shown that it is actually quite easy to calculate the joint distribution and that in a practical example this offers some important insights. In particular a rule chosen on the basis of the marginal distribution may not be chosen when the full density is investigated. 5

References Barrell, R. and Pina, A. (004), How Important are Automatic Stabilisers in Europe? Economic Modelling vol., no. pp-35 Byrne J.P. and Davie E.P.(004), Permanent and temporary inflation uncertainty and investment in the United States Economic Letters vol 85 no. pp7-77 Fuhrer J.C.(997) Inflation Output variance trade-offs and optimal monetary policy Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 9(). Garratt A., Lee K., Pesaran M.H. and Shin Y (003) Forecast Uncertainty in Macroeconometric Modelling: An application to the UK Economy Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol 98 No. 464, pp. 89-838 Giannoni M.P.(00) Does Model Uncertainty Justify Caution? Robust Optimal Monetary Policy in a forward Looking Model Macroeconomic Dynamics, 6, -44 Orphanides A. and Williams J.C.(00) Robust Monetary Policy Rules with Unknown Natural rates Brooking Papers on Economic Activity,, 63-45 Svenson L.E.O.(997) Inflation Forecast targeting: Implementing and Monitoring Inflation Targets European Economic Review Svenson L.E.O.and Woodford M. (003) Implementing Optimal Policy through Inflation- Forecast Targeting in M. Woodford (ed) Inflation Targeting, Chicago University Press, Chicago Taylor J.B. (993) Discretion versus policy rules in practise Carnegie Rochester conference series on public policy, 39, 95-4 Taylor J.B.(999) Introduction in J.B.Taylor (ed) Monetary Policy rules, Chicago University Press, Chicago. Woodford M.(003) Interest and Prices; Foundations of a theory of Monetary Policy Princeton University Press. Princeton. 6