Privatization and government preference. Abstract

Similar documents
Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Mark. De Ngo, Duc; Okura, Mahito. Economics Bulletin, 12(20), pp.1-9; Issue Date

Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly Revisited: An Extension of Stackelberg Competition

Market Structure and Privatization Policy under International Competition

Mixed Duopoly with Price Competition

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Market

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Relocation and Public Ownership of Firms

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly under Uncertainty

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

Export performance requirements under international duopoly*

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

Strategic Managerial Delegation in a Mixed. Duopoly with Capacity Choice: Partial. Delegation or Full Delegation

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Solution Problem Set 2

Long-Run Effects of Tax Policies in a Mixed Market

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs

Arindam Das Gupta Independent. Abstract

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Cournot-Bertrand competition in a unionized mixed duopoly

Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment in. Mixed Oligopolies

Quantity Competition vs. Price Competition under Optimal Subsidy in a Mixed Duopoly. Marcella Scrimitore. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2012

Export Subsidies versus Export Quotas with Incompletely Informed Policy Makers

Does Timing of Decisions in a Mixed Duopoly Matter?

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Bankruptcy risk and the performance of tradable permit markets. Abstract

Price Leadership in a Homogeneous Product Market

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Public Enterprise Strategies in a Market Open to Domestic and International Competition

Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

On Effects of Asymmetric Information on Non-Life Insurance Prices under Competition

Technology Licensing in a Differentiated Oligopoly

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Citation Economic Modelling, 2014, v. 36, p

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Competitive Markets. Market supply Competitive equilibrium Total surplus and efficiency Taxes and subsidies Price maintenance Application: Imports

Organizational Structure and the Choice of Price vs. Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly

1 Solutions to Homework 3

The Nightmare of the Leader: The Impact of Deregulation on an Oligopoly Insurance Market

Cournot-Bertrand Comparison in a Mixed Oligopoly

ENDOGENOUS TIMING IN A MIXED DUOPOLY: WEIGHTED WELFARE AND PRICE COMPETITION

Transcription:

Privatization and government preference Hideya Kato Faculty of Economics, Nagoya Keizai University, 6-, Uchikubo, Inuyama, Aichi, 484-8504, Japan Abstract This paper uses a mixed oligopoly model to examine the relationship between the privatization of a public firm and government preferences for tax revenue. From a public choice viewpoint, we assume the government prefers tax revenue to the sum of consumer and producer surplus, whereas the public firm only cares about the sum of consumer and producer surplus. The results indicate that if the government sufficiently prefers tax revenue, it will not privatize the public firm. I am truly grateful to an associate editor, an anonymous referee, Nobuhito Takeuchi, Mitsuyoshi Yanagihara, Tsuyoshi Shinozaki, and seminar participants at Nagoya Keizai University for their helpful comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are my own. Citation: Kato, Hideya, (2008) "Privatization and government preference." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 2, No. 40 pp. -7 Submitted: September 3, 2008. Accepted: December 7, 2008. URL: http://economicsbulletin.vanderbilt.edu/2008/volume2/eb-08l30004a.pdf

Introduction During the past two decades, a number of theoretical studies have concerned privatization. Most of these studies use a mixed oligopoly model, where a public firm maximizing social welfare, or the sum of consumer and producer surplus, competes with private firms maximizing their own profits in Cournot or Stacklberg competition. Their main concern has been how the number of private firms affects the privatization of the public firm. White (996) and Fjell and Heywood (2004) introduced a production subsidy into the mixed oligopoly model. These works typically assume that both the government and the public firm are benevolent in that they maximize social welfare (the sum of consumer and producer surplus less the subsidy). As a result, they conclude that the government should subsidize production in the mixed oligopoly. However, from a public choice viewpoint, it does not seem adequate to assume that the government and the public firm are benevolent. Instead, it is reasonable to consider that the government and the public firm have the following two features. First, the government may prefer tax revenue to the sum of consumer and producer surplus; that is, the government may not be benevolent. 2 The extreme case is a Leviathan government that seeks to maximize only tax revenue. 3 In this case, the government s optimal policy is to tax production rather than to subsidize it. 4 Second, the objective of the public firm may differ from that of the government. One characteristic of bureaucracies is a division of functions between different agencies. In general, because the public firm is not a tax collection agency, the public firm does not care about tax revenue but instead cares about the sum of consumer and producer surplus. In this analysis we assume that the government puts a larger weight on tax revenue than on the sum of consumer and producer surplus, whereas the public firm only cares about the sum of consumer and producer surplus. In this context, we examine the relationship between the privatization of the public firm and the government preferences for tax revenue. The main results of this paper are as follows. First, the government For a detailed survey, see De Fraja and Delbono (990). 2 Matsumura (998) also assumes that the objective function of the government is not social welfare. Unlike our model, however, he assumes that the government puts a larger weight on consumer surplus than on producer surplus. 3 For a detailed explanation of the Leviathan government, see Brennan and Buchannan (980). 4 Mujumdar and Pal (998) and De Fraja (99) are exceptions. Although they incorporate tax into a mixed oligopoly model, they do not investigate the optimal tax scheme.

sets a higher tax rate in a mixed oligopoly than in a privatized oligopoly. Second, whether the government privatizes the public firm depends on the government preference for tax revenue. 2 The model 2. The mixed oligopoly We consider a mixed oligopoly model where a public firm (firm 0) and a private firm (firm ) compete in a market. Both firms produce a homogeneous good and sell it in the market. An inverse demand function is given by p = Q, where p is the market price and Q is the total output. This total output is Q = q 0 + q, where q 0 and q are the outputs of the public firm and the private firm, respectively. Both firms have the same cost function, C(q i )=kqi 2 /2, i =0,.5 In what follows, we set k = for simplicity. A specific tax rate is imposed on both firms. It is assumed that both firms play a Cournot Nash game; that is, they simultaneously choose output. The private firm chooses output so as to maximize the following profit function: π =( Q)q q2 2 tq, () where t is the specific tax rate. On the other hand, the public firm chooses output so as to maximize the sum of consumer and producer surplus: W = Q2 2 +( Q)Q (q2 0 + q2 ) T, 2 (2) where T ( tq) is the tax revenue. 6 From the first-order conditions, the Cournot Nash equilibrium outputs of both firms can be obtained as follows: 2( t) q 0 =, 5 (3) q = t 5. (4) 5 To focus on the tax revenue, neither efficiency nor the problem of entry is taken into consideration, so we ignore fixed cost. 6 Following De Fraja (99), in this paper we assume that the public firm only cares about the sum of consumer and producer surplus. If the public firm cares not only about the sum but also about the tax revenue or subsidy, T is cancelled out in equation (2), as in White (996), Fjell and Heywood (2004), and Mujumdar and Pal (998). Under this setting, even if the government puts a larger weight on the tax revenue than on the sum of both surpluses, it never privatizes the public firm. 2

The government s payoff is given by: U = W +(+α)t, (5) where α is the parameter representing the weight of the government preference for the tax revenue. Since we are interested in the case where the government puts a larger weight on T than on W, we set α 0. 7 If α =0, the government puts the same weight on W and T. In this case, because the government s payoff represents social welfare, the government is benevolent. To the contrary, the greater α becomes, the more the government cares about T. In particular, if α approximates infinity, the government cares only about T ; that is, the government is a Leviathan. From (2), (3) and (4) into (5), the government s payoff can be rewritten as follows: U = ( t)[8 + t(7 + 5α)]. (6) 25 When the government chooses t so as to maximize (6), the optimal tax rate in the mixed oligopoly can be obtained as follows: t m = 5α 2(7 + 5α). (7) If the weight of the government preference for the tax revenue is sufficiently large (in the case of α > /5), the optimal tax rate becomes positive. Conversely, when it is small (in the case of 0 α</5), the optimal tax rate becomes negative; in the case of α =/5, the optimal tax rate is zero. We find that the greater the weight of the government preference for the tax revenue, the higher the tax rate the government imposes. This result is intuitive and straightforward. From (3), (4), (6) and (7), we can show the following equilibrium outcomes in the mixed oligopoly: q 0m q m = 3( + α) 7+5α, (8) = 3( + α) 2(7 + 5α), (9) Q 9( + α) m = 2(7 + 5α), (0) Um 9( + α)2 = 4(7 + 5α). () 7 If α<0, we can consider the case where the government puts a larger weight on W than on T. However, we exclude this case because it is inconsistent with reality. 3

As shown, every equilibrium outcome depends only on α. It should be noted that as α becomes larger, the output of each firm, and therefore the total output, decreases. This is because from (7), the optimal tax rate is positively correlated with α. In addition, it is clear that the government s payoff is U- shaped with respect to α. 2.2 The privatized oligopoly Let us turn to the case of a privatized oligopoly where the public firm is privatized without cost. The privatized firm now plans to maximize its profit by choosing output. As in the case of the mixed oligopoly, both firms play a Cournot Nash game. The outputs of both firms are expressed as follows: q 0 = q = t 4. (2) From (2), (5) and (2), the government s payoff can be written as follows: U = ( t)[5 + t(3 + 8α)]. (3) 6 When the government chooses t so as to maximize (3), the optimal tax rate in the privatized oligopoly can be obtained as follows: t p = 4α 3+8α. (4) If α > /4, the optimal tax rate becomes positive; if 0 α</4, the optimal tax rate becomes negative and therefore the government subsidizes both firms; and if α =/4, the optimal tax rate becomes zero. This optimal tax rate in the privatized oligopoly is also increasing in α as in the mixed oligopoly. From (2), (3) and (4), the outputs of both firms, the total output and the government s payoff in the equilibrium can be written as q0p = qp = +α 3+8α, (5) Q 2( + α) p = 3+8α, (6) Up ( + α)2 = 3+8α, (7) respectively. As α becomes large, the optimal tax rate increases, and the outputs of both firms thereby decrease. In addition, the government s payoff is U-shaped with respect to α. These features are similar to the mixed oligopoly case. 4

2.3 Comparisons In this subsection, we compare the mixed and privatized oligopoly equilibria. The differences in the optimal tax rates (or, possibly, the optimal subsidy rate), the total outputs and the government s payoffs can be calculated as t m t p = ( + α) > 0, (8) 2(3 + 8α)(7 + 5α) Q m Q p = ( + α)(2α ) 2(3 + 8α)(7 + 5α), (9) U m U p = ( + α)2 (2α ) 4(3 + 8α)(7 + 5α), (20) respectively. These results lead to the following two findings. First, as long as α is finite, the optimal tax rate in the mixed oligopoly is always higher than that in the privatized oligopoly. In addition, the difference in the optimal tax rates between the mixed and privatized oligopoly cases becomes smaller, when α becomes larger. Note that if α approaches infinity, the optimal tax rates in both the mixed and privatized oligopoly cases are the same: t m = t p =/2 (see Figure ).8 t t m t p t m t p 5 4 Α Figure : The comparison of the optimal tax rates Second, if α>/2, both total output and the government s payoff in the mixed oligopoly are larger than those in the privatized oligopoly. In this 8 If α approaches infinity, the government chooses the tax rate so as to maximize the tax revenue. The first-order condition is d(tq)/dt = Q( + ɛ) = 0, where ɛ represents the elasticity of output with respect to the tax rate. Because the elasticities obtained in the mixed and privatized oligopoly cases are the same, these tax rates are also identical. 5

case, the government does not have an incentive to privatize the public firm. In contrast, if 0 α</2, both total output and the government s payoff in the mixed oligopoly are smaller than those in the privatized oligopoly, so the government will privatize the public firm. Obviously, if α = /2, Q m = Q p =3/22 and U m = U p = 69/528 hold, then the government is indifferent to the choice regarding privatization. We have summarized these results in Figure 2 and 3. Q Q m Q p Q m Q p 2 Figure 2: The comparison of total outputs Α U U m U p U m U p 2 Figure 3: The comparison of the government s payoffs It should be noted that when total output in the mixed oligopoly is larger than that in the privatized oligopoly, the government s payoff in the mixed oligopoly is also larger than that in the privatized oligopoly. From (3), (4) and (2), the difference in total outputs can be represented as a function of t m and t p : Q m Q p =( 6t m +5t p )/0. Therefore, we can see that the difference is decreasing in t m and increasing in t p. If the government puts a 6 Α

sufficiently larger weight on tax revenue than on the sum of both surpluses, i.e., if α>/2, the difference in the optimal tax rates is small. In this case, the government does not privatize the public firm. In contrast, if the government puts a moderately larger weight on tax revenue than on the sum of both surpluses, i.e., if 0 α</2, the government will privatize the public firm, because the difference in the optimal tax rates is sufficiently large. 3 Conclusion In this analysis we used a mixed oligopoly model to examine the relationship between the privatization of a public firm and the government preferences for tax revenue. If the government sufficiently prefers the tax revenue to the sum of the consumer and producer surplus, it will not privatize the public firm. This result may indicate that differences in the progress of privatization in various countries depend on government preferences for tax revenue. References Brennan, G. and J. M. Buchannan, (980) Power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution, (Cambridge University Press). De Fraja, G., (99) Efficiency and privatization in imperfectly competitive industries Journal of Industrial Economics 39, 3-32. De Fraja, G. and F. Delbono, (990) Game theoretic models of mixed oligopoly Journal of Economic Survey 4, -7. Fjell, K. and J. Heywood, (2004) Mixed oligopoly, subsidization and the order of firm s moves: the relevance of privatization Economics Letters 53, 4-46. Matsumura, T., (998) Partial privatization in mixed duopoly Journal of Public Economics 70, 473-483. Mujumdar, S. and D. Pal, (998) Effects of indirect taxation in a mixed oligopoly Economics Letters 58, 99-204. White, M., (996) Mixed oligopoly, privatization and subsidization Economics Letters 53, 89-95. 7