Can the Laffer curve for consumption tax be hump-shaped?

Similar documents
Can the Laffer curve for consumption tax be hump-shaped?

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Credit, externalities, and non-optimality of the Friedman rule

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Capital Income Tax Reform and the Japanese Economy (Very Preliminary and Incomplete)

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Consumption Taxes and Divisibility of Labor under Incomplete Markets

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

How Far Are We From The Slippery Slope? The Laffer Curve Revisited

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Policy Uncertainty and the Cost of Delaying Reform: A case of aging Japan

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS

How Do Laffer Curves Differ Across Countries?

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Dynamic Analysis of Budget Policy Rules in Japan

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Volume 29, Issue 1. Juha Tervala University of Helsinki

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Interest Rate Peg. Rong Li and Xiaohui Tian. January Abstract. This paper revisits the sizes of fiscal multipliers under a pegged nominal

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation That Encourages Work and Saving

The Implications of a Greying Japan for Public Policy.

Saving Europe? Some Unpleasant Supply-Side Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Funded Pension Scheme, Endogenous Time Preference and Capital Accumulation

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Fiscal Policy Puzzle and Intratemporal Substitution among Private Consumption, Government Spending, and Leisure.

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

BGSE Macroeconomics I

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

The Effects of Financing Rules in Pay-As-You-Go Pension Systems on the Life and the Business Cycle

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Endogenous Managerial Ability and Progressive Taxation

The Zero Lower Bound

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

When Do We Start? Pension reform in aging Japan

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Transcription:

Can the Laffer curve for consumption tax be hump-shaped? Kazuki Hiraga Kengo Nutahara January 3, 207 We would like to thank Naohito Abe, John Anderson, Toni Braun, Hans Holter, Makoto Hanazono, Yunfang Hu, Masaru Inaba, Sagiri Kitao, Keiichiro Kobayashi, Noritaka Kudo, Kiminori Matsuyama, Tomomi Miyazaki, Kensuke Miyazawa, Tomoyuki Nakajima, Masao Ogaki, Etsuro Shioji, Daichi Shirai, Shuhei Takahashi, Harald Uhlig, Takashi Unayama, Yuichiro Waki, Eric Weese, Pavel Yakovlev and seminar participants at Hitotsubashi University, Keio University, Kobe University, Nagoya University, Asia Meeting of Econometric Society 206, The 9th Biennial Conference of Hong Kong Economic Association, and International Insutitute for Public Finance 206 for their helpful comments. Of course, the remaining errors are ours. Tokai University. Address: 4-- Kitakaname, Hiratsuka, Kanagawa 259-292, Japan. Senshu University. Address: 2-- Higashimira, Tama-ku, Kawasaki, Kanagawa 24-8580, Japan. E-mail: nutti@isc.senshu-u.ac.jp, Tel: 044-9-230, Fax: 044-9-23. The Canon Institute for Global Studies. Address: 5-- Marunouchi, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 00-65, Japan.

Abstract This paper characterizes the shape of the Laffer curve for consumption tax analytically. The Laffer curve for consumption tax can be hump-shaped if the utility function is an additively separable one in consumption and labor supply. Conversely, it cannot be hump-shaped if the utility function is the one employed by previous researchers. The difference in the utility functions has quantitatively significant effects on the peak tax rates of the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes. Keywords: Laffer curve; tax revenue; consumption tax JEL classification: E62; H20; H30 2

Introduction The main objective of this paper is to investigate the Laffer curve for consumption tax. As in Waninski (978), Arthur B. Laffer s conjecture is that the Laffer curve is humpshaped. This is because an increase in a tax rate would have two opposing effects on the tax revenue. In the first effect, the tax revenue would increase as a direct consequence of raising the tax rate. In the second effect, the tax revenue reduces because a high tax rate discourages economic activities of labor supply, capital accumulation, consumption, and output. Contrary to Laffer s conjecture, Trabandt and Uhlig (20, 203) recently show that the Laffer curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing, whereas the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes are hump-shaped. It is also found that the monotonically increasing Laffer curve for consumption tax is robust to some variations of the models. Their finding has a big impact on many kind of fiscal issues like fiscal limits and fiscal sustainability because those are affected by the maximum size of government tax revenue. However, most of results of Trabandt and Uhlig (20, 203) are based on numerical analyses, and it is not clear whether the Laffer curve for consumption tax is generally monotonically increasing or not. This paper characterizes the shape of the Laffer curve for consumption tax both in a simple static general equilibrium model and a standard neoclassical growth model. In a simple static model, output is produced by linear technology of labor, no capital stock, no government consumption, and the tax revenue is used only for the lump-sum transfer. In a neoclassical growth model, capital stock, investment expenditure, government debt, and net imports are introduced to the dynamic setting à la Trabandt and Uhlig (20). Both of the consumption tax revenue curve and the total tax revenue curve, including labor and capital tax revenues, are considered as the Laffer curves. There are two definitions of the Laffer curve. In this paper, the Laffer curve is defined as the tax revenue curve following Trabandt and Uhlig (20). On the other hand, in the textbooks of public finance, like Gruber (203), it is defined as the hump-shaped tax revenue curve. 3

The Laffer curve for consumption tax can be hump-shaped if the utility function is an additively separable one in consumption and labor supply, whereas this is not so if the utility function is the one employed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20). The key parameters for the hump-shaped Laffer curve are the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (hereafter IES), that is, the inverse of the relative risk aversion in our models, and the labor supply elasticity in the utility function. For the hump-shaped Laffer curve, IES and labor supply elasticity should be sufficiently high. An increase in the consumption tax rate has a negative effect on the tax revenue in that it reduces aggregate labor supply and aggregate consumption. Thus, the parameter of labor supply elasticity in the utility function is important. The aggregate labor supply and aggregate consumption elasticities can be greater than one under sufficiently high values of IES and labor supply elasticity parameters in the case of an additively separable utility function, whereas this cannot be the case for the Trabandt-Uhlig utility. The difference in the functional form of the utility has quantitatively significant effects on the peak tax rates of the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes. The quantitative impacts of the difference in the utility function on the peak tax rates of the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes are about 0% when the Laffer curve for consumption tax is not hump-shaped. They exceed 30% when the Laffer curve is hump-shaped. Both additively separable and Trabandt-Uhlig utility functions are often employed in macroeconomics. For examples, Gali (2008) employs the additively separable utility, whereas King and Rebelo (999) employed Trabandt-Uhlig utility. It is rare to focus on the effect of the difference in utility functions. However, this paper illustrates an example where the difference in the utility functions has a significant effect on the Laffer curves. The Laffer curve has been investigated by various researchers. Ireland (994) find that the hump-shaped Laffer curve for capital income tax using an AK model. Schmitt- Grohè and Uribe (997) derivate the hump-shaped Laffer curve for labor income tax in a neoclassical growth model. Trabandt and Uhlig (20, 203) estimate the Laffer curves 4

for consumption, labor, and capital taxes for the U.S. and EU4 using a neoclassical growth model. Nutahara (205) applies the model of Trabandt and Uhlig (20) to the Japanese economy. Fève, Matheron, and Sahuc (203) investigate the Laffer curves for consumption, labor, and capital taxes in an incomplete-market economy. Holter, Krueger, and Stepanchuk (204) focus on the effect of households heterogeneity and progressive tax scheme on the peak tax rate of the Laffer curve for labor income tax using an overlapping generations model. This paper is closely related to the papers by Trabandt and Uhlig (20, 203) and Nutahara (205), who estimate the Laffer curve for consumption tax. They employ a utility function with constant labor supply elasticity and use numerical analyses to show that the Laffer curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. Kobayashi (204) investigates whether the consumption tax revenue is bounded using a neoclassical growth model with the log utility function. He finds that although the fixed supply of production factor affects the boundedness of the consumption tax revenue, the Laffer curve continues to be monotonically increasing in his model. In the paper by Fève, Matheron, and Sahuc (203), the Laffer curve for consumption tax is not hump-shaped because they employ the log utility function. The main contribution of the present paper is to find that the Laffer curve for consumption tax can be hump-shaped if the utility is additively separable. Our finding has implications on the literature of fiscal reform because the consumption tax is receiving a lot of attention as a useful tool to finance the government expenditure as in Braun and Joines (205), Hansen and Imrohoroglu (206) and Kitao (206). In this literature, the consumption tax is highlighted because the welfare loss from the consupmtion tax is less than those from other distortionary taxes, and because the Laffer curves for other taxes, like labor income tax, are hump-shaped and the tax revenues are limited. According to our finding, the consumption tax might not be useful if the Laffer curve for consumption tax is hump-shaped. 5

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the simple static model and shows the main result. Section 3 extends the result of Section 2 to a dynamic setting à la Trabandt and Uhlig (20). Section 4 discusses the results. Section 5 concludes. 2 Simple static economy Assuming a simple static economy, the Laffer curve for consumption tax is characterized in this section. 2. Model The representative households supply labor n to firms and earn wage rate w. They also receive government transfers s. Let τ c t denote consumption tax. The budget constraint of households is ( + τ c ) c wn + s, () where c denotes consumption. The firms are perfectly competitive. Their production function is y = n, (2) where y denotes output. The government budget constraint is s T, (3) where total tax revenue T is defined by T = τ c c. (4) 6

Since there is no investment and government consumption, the resource constraint of this closed economy is y = c. (5) Two types of utility functions are considered. The one is an additively separable one such that U AS = c η η κn+λ, where η is the relative risk aversion (that is the inverse of the IES under a dynamic setting), and /λ is the labor supply elasticity. 2 This type of utility function is often employed in the literature on the new Keynesian business cycle (see Gali, 2008). The other is one, called Trabandt-Uhlig utility function in this paper, such that U TU = {c [ η κ( η)n +λ] } η, η which is a static version employed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20). If η =, these two utility functions are identical. Otherwise, these two specifications are different. 2.2 Laffer curve for consumption tax in a static economy First, consider the consumption tax revenue curve as the Laffer curve. The key element here is the elasticity of aggregate consumption to the consumption tax rate. If it is greater than one, an increase in the consumption tax rate increases the consumption tax revenue, and vice versa. In this model, consumption equals labor supply by the resource constraint and production function. In the case of the additively separable utility function, the optimization condition for the consumption labor choice is κ( + λ)c η n λ = w. (6) + τc 2 In this paper, /λ is called the labor supply elasticity, but it is often interpreted as Frisch elasticity in the literature. A discussion on this topic appears in Section 4. 7

Solving this condition yields c = n = [κ( + λ)( + τ c )] /(η+λ), (7) and the elasticity of aggregate consumption to the consumption tax rate is dc/c dτ c /τ c = η + λ τ c + τ. (8) c It is easily shown that dc/c is increasing in τ c, dτ c /τ dc/c = 0 if τ c = 0, and c dτ c /τ dc/c c dτ c /τ c converges to η+λ as τc approaches infinity. Therefore, the Laffer curve for consumption tax can be hump-shaped if is greater than one. η+λ The following is a formal statement of a necessary and sufficient condition for a hump-shaped consumption tax revenue curve for consumption tax. Proposition. Suppose that the utility function is additively separable; U AS. The consumption tax revenue curve for consumption tax is hump-shaped if and only if η + λ <, and the revenue is maximized at τ c = curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. Proof. Note that η+λ. Otherwise, the consumption tax revenue η λ dc/c dτ c /τ c = η + λ τ c [ ( η λ)τ c (η + λ) ]. (9) + τ c Suppose that η + λ =. In this case, dc/c dτ c /τ c < 0 and the consumption tax revenue is monotonically increasing. Suppose η + λ. In this case, ( ) ( dc/c η λ dτ c /τ c = η + λ If η + λ, then dc/c dτ c /τ c. τ c + τ c ) ( τ c η + λ ). η λ If η + λ <, then dc/c dτ c /τ c for τ c (η + λ)/( η λ), and dc/c dτ c /τ c > for τ c > (η + λ)/( η λ). 8

The parameters in the utility function, η and λ, should be small because the humpshaped consumption tax revenue curve can be understood by the optimization condition for the consumption labor choice (6). The consumption tax revenue curve can be humpshaped if an increase in the consumption tax rate reduces the labor supply by a sufficient amount. The key parameter is the inverse of λ, that is, the labor supply elasticity to the effective after-tax wage rate w/( + τ c ), that is also interpreted as the relative price of leisure with respect to consumption. Then, a low value of λ implies a highly distorted increase in the consumption tax rate. In general equilibrium, consumption c is closely related to the labor supply n through the resource constraint and production function. In the current setting, c = n. Then, the parameter η (the inverse of the IES) works as the inverse of the aggregate labor supply elasticity. As a result, the inverse of η + λ is the elasticity of the aggregate labor supply in general equilibrium as in (7). Then, the inverse of η + λ is the maximum of the elasticity of consumption since c = n. In the case of the Trabandt-Uhlig utility function, the optimization condition for the consumption labor choice is ( ) κcn λ η ( + λ) = κ( η)n +λ Solving this condition yields w. (0) + τc c = n = [ τ c ηκ ( + λ) + κ(ηλ + ) ] /(+λ), () and the elasticity of consumption to the consumption tax rate is dc/c dτ c /τ c = τ c ηκ τ c ηκ ( + λ) + κ(ηλ + ). (2) Contrary to Proposition, the Trabandt-Uhlig utility function cannot generate a hump- shaped Laffer curve for consumption tax as in Proposition 2, since dc/c < for τ c 0. dτ c /τ c Proposition 2. Suppose that the utility function is Trabandt-Uhlig; U TU. The consumption tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. 9

Proof. It is obvious that dc/c dτ c /τ c = τ c ηκ τ c ηκ ( + λ) + κ(ηλ + ) <. So far, the consumption tax revenue curve is considered to be a Laffer curve. By introducing labor income tax, the Laffer curve refers to the total tax revenue. In this case, the budget constraint of a household becomes ( + τ c ) c ( τ n )wn + s, (3) and the total tax revenue is T t = τ c c + τ n wn. (4) Propositions 3 and 4 are analogues of Propositions and 2. Proposition 3. Suppose that the utility function is additively separable; U AS. The total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is hump-shaped if and only if τ n < η + λ < and the revenue is maximized at τ c = η+λ τn η λ. If η + λ τn <, the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically decreasing. Otherwise, the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. Proof. See Appendix A. Proposition 4. Suppose that the utility function is Trabandt-Uhlig; U TU. The total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. Proof. See Appendix B. As in the consumption tax revenue curve, the condition η+λ < is necessary for the hump-shaped total tax revenue curve for consumption tax in the case of the additively separable utility function U AS, and in the case of Trabandt-Uhlig utility function, the 0

total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. Note that the consumption tax revenue curve might be monotonically decreasing if labor income tax rate is sufficiently high (η + λ τ n ). This is interpreted as the case where the peak consumption tax rate that maximizes the total tax revenue (τ c = η+λ τn ) of the hump- η λ shaped total tax revenue curve is negative. 3 Dynamic economy à la Trabandt and Uhlig (20) In this section, the result of Section 2 is extended to a neoclassical growth model à la Trabandt and Uhlig (20). 3. Model The representative households hold capital stock k t and debt b t as assets at the beginning of the period. They supply labor n t and capital stock k t to firms, and earn the wage rate w t, rental rate of capital d t, and interest rate on debt R b t. They also receive government transfers s t and transfers from abroad m t. The latter can be interpreted as net imports as discussed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20). Let τ c t, τ n t, and τ k t denote the consumption tax, labor tax, and capital tax rates, respectively. The budget constraint of households is ( + τ c t )c t + x t + b t ( τ n t )w t n t + ( τ k t )(d t δ)k t + δk t + R b t b t + s t + m t, (5) where c t denotes consumption, δ denotes the depreciation rate of capital, and x t is investment. The capital stock evolves according to the following equation. k t = ( δ)k t + x t. (6) The firms are perfectly competitive. Their production function is y t = ξ t k θ t n θ t, (7)

where ξ denotes the technology growth rate, and θ denotes the capital share in production. The profit maximization problem implies The government budget constraint is w t = ( θ) y t n t and (8) d t = θ y t k t. (9) g t + s t + R b t b t b t + T t, (20) where g t denotes the government consumption, and the total tax revenue T t is defined by The resource constraint of this economy is T t = τ c t c t + τ n t w t n t + τ k t (d t δ)k t. (2) y t = c t + x t + g t m t. (22) The additively separable utility function for this dynamic economy is U AS = β t c η t η κψt( η) n +λ t + v(g t ), t=0 where ψ t( η) guarantees the existence of a balanced growth path, and v( ) is an increasing function. The Trabandt-Uhlig utility function is [ U TU = β t { [ ] c η t κ( η)n +λ η } ] t + v(g t ). η t=0 Following Trabandt and Uhlig (20), the Laffer curve for consumption tax is given by the relationship between the tax revenue and tax rate on the balanced growth path. Let the growth rate on the balanced growth path be ψ = ξ /( θ). It is assumed that government debt b t is on the balanced growth path; b t that g t = ϕ g y t and m t = ϕ m y t. 3 described in Appendix C. = ψ t b. It is also assumed The equilibrium system at the balanced growth path is 3 Trabandt and Uhlig (20) employ alternative assumptions: g t = ψ t ḡ and m t = ψ t m. The constant 2

3.2 Laffer curve for consumption tax in the dynamic economy Propositions 5 and 6 refer to the consumption tax revenue curve in the dynamic economy. Proposition 5. Suppose that the utility function is additively separable; U AS. The consumption tax revenue curve for consumption tax is hump-shaped if and only if η + λ <, and the revenue is maximized at τ c = curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. η+λ. Otherwise, the consumption tax revenue η λ Proof. See Appendix D. Proposition 6. Suppose that the utility function is Trabandt-Uhlig; U TU. The consumption tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing. Proof. See Appendix E. Note that these two propositions are the same as Propositions and 2, while the dynamic economy has far richer structure (capital, investment, debt evolution, etc.) than the static economy in Section 2. Propositions 7 and 8 refer to the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax. Proposition 7. Suppose that the utility function is additively separable; U AS. The total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is hump-shaped if and only if ( [ ( )] y k η + λ < and τ c) n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) < η + λ, y steady-state ratio of government consumption to GDP is interpreted as the government controls g t /y t as in Hayashi and Prescott (2002). The constant steady-state ratio of net imports to GDP would be interpreted as net imports being closely related to the total income of the home country. These assumptions of constant steady-state ratios are used to prove Propositions 5 8. Under these assumptions, an increase in the consumption tax rate decreases both output and government consumption. This decrease in government consumption implies a positive wealth effect and then consumption increases. Therefore, the Laffer curve for consumption tax is more unlikely to be hump-shaped than those under the assumptions employed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20). 3

where and the revenue is maximized at τ c = η λ [ ] ψ η d = τ k β + δ. k y = θ d, c y = [ ψ ( δ) ] θ d ϕ g + ϕ m, { (η + λ) ( y c ) [ τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)]}. Otherwise, the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is U-shaped if η + λ > and ( ) [ y c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)] > η + λ. monotonically increasing if η + λ > and ( ) [ y c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)] η + λ. monotonically increasing if η + λ = and ( ) [ y c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)] < η + λ. flat if η + λ = and ( ) [ y c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)] = η + λ. monotonically decreasing if η + λ = and ( ) [ y c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)] > η + λ. monotonically decreasing if η + λ < and ( ) [ y c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k y)] η + λ. Proof. See Appendix F. Proposition 8. Suppose that the utility function is Trabandt-Uhlig; U TU. The total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is monotonically increasing if and only if ( ) k τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) η ( ) c y η ( θ)( τn ) + ( + λ), y where [ ] ψ η d = τ k β + δ. k y = θ d, c y = [ ψ ( δ) ] θ d ϕ g + ϕ m. Otherwise, the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is U-shaped. 4

Proof. See Appendix G. Propositions 7 and 8 imply that there is a possibility that the total tax revenue curve might be U-shaped under some parameter values. Under this situation, the total tax revenue is decreasing and increasing if the consumption tax rate is low and sufficiently high, respectively. The U-shaped total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is generated when the labor and capital income tax rate are high. The decreases in these tax revenues associated with an increase in the consumption tax rate dominate the increase in consumption tax revenue if the consumption tax rate is low. 4 Discussion 4. Likelihood of a hump-shaped Laffer curve for consumption tax According to Propositions, 3, 5, and 7, it is necessary for η + λ < to generate a hump-shaped Laffer curve for consumption tax. For this condition, both η and λ should be less than one. The likelihood of this condition is discussed in this subsection. The condition η < might be supported by the empirical findings of Mulligan (2002), Vissing-Jorgensen and Attanasio (2003), Bansal and Yaron (2004), and Gruber (203), whereas it is standard to set η in macroeconomics. These papers find that the IES, that is the inverse of η, is greater than one. Kobayashi, Nakajima, and Inaba (202) find that the IES must be greater than one, and set η = /2 in order to generate a positive response of the asset price to the news shock about future productivity in their theoretical research. The parameter λ should not be not restricted by evidence on the Frisch elasticity as claimed by Christiano, Trabandt, and Walentin (200), although it is often interpreted as the inverse of Frisch elasticity, and the values are set depending on the estimations using micro data analyses. Empirical evidence from micro data implies that the Frisch 5

elasticity is very small. However, as in the seminal works by Hansen (985) and Rogerson (988), even if the individual elasticity of labor supply is zero, the aggregate labor supply can be sensitive to the changes in the real wage rate. Christiano, Trabandt, and Walentin (200) estimate this parameter for the U.S. economy by using Bayesian impulse response matching, and find that λ is around 0.. Therefore, some recent empirical evidence supports small values of η and λ. It would imply that a hump-shaped Laffer curve for consumption tax is possible. 4.2 Numerical results of the Laffer curve for consumption tax Sections 2 and 3 characterize the shape of the Laffer curve for consumption tax and show that the Laffer curve can be hump-shaped in the case of the additively separable utility. This subsection presents some numerical results. The parameter values are the same as those employed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20) for the U.S. economy. The capital share in the production function θ is 0.35. The depreciation rate of capital δ is 0.083. The steady-state ratio of debt to output b/y is 0.63. The steady-state ratio of government expenditure to output g/y is 0.08. The steady-state ratio of transfer from abroad to output m/y is 0.04. The balanced growth parameter ψ is.02. The steady-state real interest rate R is.04. The steady-state labor supply h is 0.2. The steady-state capital income tax rate is 0.36, labor income tax is 0.28, and consumption tax rate is 0.05. Figure summarizes the shape of the tax revenue curve for consumption tax in the dynamic model. The horizontal axis is η, and the vertical axis is λ. I denotes the region of the monotonically increasing total tax revenue curve, D, the region of the monotonically decreasing curve, H, the region of the hump-shaped curve, and U, the region of the U-shaped curve. At the point F, that is the intersection of the two lines, the total tax revenue is flat. The panels on the left and right are the cases of the additively separable utility U AS and the Trabandt-Uhlig utility U TU, respectively. The 6

upper panels are the benchmark case with τ n = 0.36. The middle and lower panels are the cases of τ n = 0.7 and τ n = 0.9, respectively. [Insert Figure ] Figure 2 shows a numerical example of the total tax revenue curves for consumption tax and components (consumption tax revenue, labor income tax revenue, and capital income tax revenue) in the dynamic model. The procedure to calculate the tax revenue curves is described in Appendix H. The horizontal axes are consumption tax rates. The vertical axes are normalized tax revenue. (The tax revenues are normalized such that the total tax revenues in the case of the baseline consumption tax rate τ c = 0.05 are 00.) The circles denote the peak tax rates that maximize the total tax revenues. The vertical dotted lines show the baseline consumption tax rate of 5%. The utility function parameters are set such that η = /2 and λ = 0.. The value of η is consistent with Gruber (203), and that of λ is consistent with the value estimated by Christiano, Trabandt, and Walentin (200). As already shown in Sections 2 and 3, the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax is hump-shaped in the case of the additively separable utility function U AS, and it is monotonically increasing for the Trabandt-Uhlig utility function U TU. The peak tax rate that maximizes the total tax revenue of the additively separable utility is 45.84%, whereas the consumption tax revenue is maximized at 50%, that is (η + λ)/( η λ). [Insert Figure 2] 4.3 Quantitative significance of the difference in utility functions on the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes Propositions 8 show that the difference in the functional form of the utility has significant effects on the shape of the Laffer curve for consumption tax. In this subsection, the 7

quantitative effects of this difference on the total tax revenue curves for labor and capital income taxes are examined. Figure 3 shows the total tax revenue curves for labor income tax in the cases of the additively separable and Trabandt-Uhlig utility functions in the dynamic model. The left-hand panel shows the case of η = 2 and λ =, employed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20), and the right, of η = /2 and λ = 0., which generate the hump-shaped total tax revenue curves for consumption tax. The real lines are the total tax revenue curves in the case of the additively separable utility U AS. The dotted lies are the total tax revenue curves in the case of the Trabandt-Uhlig utility U TU. The total tax revenues are normalized such that those are 00 at the baseline labor income tax rate τ n = 0.28. The other parameter values are the same as in the previous subsection. Figure 3 tells that the difference in the utility functions has significant effects on the the peak tax rates of the total tax revenue curves for labor income tax. These peak tax rates are 7.5% (additively separable utility) and 59.26% (Trabandt-Uhlig utility) for η = 2 and λ =. Notably, the difference in the peak tax rates is more than 0% even for Trabandt and Uhlig s (20) parameter values. This impact is much strengthened for η = /2 and λ = 0.: the peak tax rates are 32.93% (additively separable utility) and 58.99% (Trabandt-Uhlig utility). [Insert Figure 3] It is noticed that the peak tax rate of the total tax revenue curve for labor income tax of the additively separable utility is greater than that of the Trabandt-Uhlig utility it η = 2 and λ =. On the other hand, that of the additively separable utility is less than that of the Trabandt-Uhlig utility if η = /2 and λ = 0.. This difference is accounted for by the difference in the equilibrium elasticity of labor supply with respect to labor income tax rate. Remark. Let the equilibrium elasticity of labor supply with respect to labor income tax rate in the case of the additively separable utility U AS be εn AS, and that in the case of 8

the Trabandt-Uhlig utility U TU be ε TU n. ε AS n ε AS n < ε TU n if η >, ε TU n if η. Proof. See Appendix I. Figure 4 shows the capital income tax analogue of Figure 3. The total tax revenues are normalized such that those are 00 at the baseline capital income tax rate τ k = 0.36. The peak tax rates in the case of η = 2 and λ = are 7.% (additively separable utility) and 59.32% (Trabandt-Uhlig utility), and the difference is more than 0% as well. This impact is much strengthened for η = /2 and λ = 0.: the peak tax rates are 20.49% (additively separable utility) and 78.8% (Trabandt-Uhlig utility). [Insert Figure 4] Finally, Figures 3 and 4 show that the difference in the utility functions has quantitatively significant effects on the peak tax rates of the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes. 5 Concluding remarks This paper has characterized the shape of the Laffer curve for consumption tax. The Laffer curve for consumption tax can be hump-shaped if the utility function is an additively separable in consumption and labor supply. On the other hand, it cannot be hump-shaped if the utility function is the one employed by Trabandt and Uhlig (20). This is because the aggregate labor supply and consumption elasticities with respect to the consumption tax rate can be greater than one under sufficiently high parameter values of the IES and labor supply elasticity if the utility is additively separable, whereas the opposite stands when the utility is Trabandt-Uhlig. 9

This paper has also shown that the Laffer curve for consumption tax can be humpshaped under empirically relevant parameter values. At the same time, the difference in the functional form of the utility has quantitatively significant effects on the peak tax rates of the Laffer curves for labor and capital income taxes. References [] Bansal, R., and Yaron, A. 2004. Risks for the long run: A potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. Journal of Finance 59(4), 48 509. [2] Braun, R.A., and Joines, D.H. 205. The implications of a graying Japan for government policy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 57, 23. [3] Christiano, L.J., Trabandt, M., and Walentin, K. 200. DSGE Models for Monetary Policy Analysis. In: Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics 3(3). Elsevier, Amsterdam, 285 367. [4] Fève, P., Matheron, J., and Sahuc, J. 203. The Laffer Curve in an Incomplete- Market Economy. Banque de France Working Paper No. 438. [5] Gali, J., 2008. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework and Its Applications. Princeton University Press. [6] Gruber, J., 203. A tax-based estimate of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. Quarterly Journal of Finance, 3(). [7] Gruber, J., 205. Public Finance and Public Policy, 5th Edition. Worth Publishers. New York. [8] Hansen, G.D., 985. Indivisible labor and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 6(3), 309 327. 20

[9] Hansen, G.D., and Imrohoroglu, S., 206. Fiscal reform and government debt in Japan: A neoclassical perspective. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 20 224. [0] Hayashi, F., and Prescott, E. C., 2002. The 990s in Japan: A Lost Decade. Review of Economic Dynamics, 5, 206 235. [] Holter, Hans A., Krueger, D., and Stepanchuk, S., 204. How does tax progressivity and household heterogeneity affect Laffer curves? NBER Working Paper No. 20688. [2] Ireland, P., 994. Supply-side economics and endogenous growth, Journal of Monetary Economics, 33, 559 57. [3] King, R. S., Rebelo, S. T., 999. Resuscitating real business cycles. In: Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. B. Elsevier, Amsterdam, 927 007. [4] Kitao, S., 206. Policy uncertainty and cost of delaying reform: A case of aging Japan. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 6 E 03. [5] Kobayashi, K., 204. There is no natural debt limit with consumption tax. RIETI Discussion Paper 4 E 043. [6] Kobayashi, K., Nakajima, T., and Inaba, M. 202. Collateral constraint and newsdriven cycles. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 6(5), 752 776. [7] Mulligan, C., 2002. Capital, interest, and aggregate intertemporal substitution. NBER Working Paper 9373. [8] Nutahara, K., 205. Laffer curves in Japan. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 36, 56 72. 2

[9] Rogerson, R., 988. Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium. Journal of Monetary Economics, 2(), 3 6. [20] Schmitt-Grohè, S., and Uribe, M., 997. Balanced-budget rules, distortionary taxes, and aggregate instability. Journal of Political Economy, 05(5), 976 000. [2] Trabandt, M, and Uhlig, H., 20. The Laffer curve revisited. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58, 305 327. [22] Trabandt, M, and Uhlig, H., 203. How Do Laffer Curves Differ Across Countries? NBER Chapters: Fiscal Policy After the Financial Crisis. editors A. Alesina and F. Giavazzi, University of Chicago Press. [23] Vissing-Jorgensen, A., and Attanasio, O., 2003. Stock-market participation, intertemporal substitution, and risk aversion. American Economic Review, 93(2), 383 39. [24] Wanniski, J., 978. Taxes, revenues, and the Laffer curve. The Public Interest, 50, 3 6. Appendix A Proof of Proposition 3 Proof. The optimization condition for the consumption labor choice, indicates that κ( + λ)c η n λ = τn + τ c w, c = [ ] κ( + λ) τ ( + η+λ n τc ). 22

Since the total tax revenue is T = τ c c + τ n wn [ = (τ c + τ n ) κ τ n ( + τc ) ] η+λ, then [ ] dt κ( + λ) dτ = c τ ( + n τc ) η+λ ( κ( + λ) τ n ) [ τ c ( η + λ η + λ ) + η + λ τn η + λ ]. Suppose η + λ =, then dt dτ c > 0. Suppose η + λ, then [ ] dt κ( + λ) dτ = c τ ( + η+λ ( κ( + λ) n τc ) τ n ) ( η + λ η + λ ) [τ c η + λ ] τn. η λ If η + λ >, then dt dτ c > 0. If η + λ <, then dt dτ c > 0 for τ c < η+λ τn dt, and η λ dτ c < 0 for τ c > η+λ τn η λ. B Proof of Proposition 4 Proof. By the optimization condition for the consumption labor choice, it follows that ( η ( + λ) κcn λ κ( η)n +λ ) = τn + τ c w, c = ( τ n ) /(+λ) [ τ c ηκ ( + λ) + κ(ηλ + ) τ n κ( η) ] /(+λ). The total tax revenue is T = τ c c + τ n wn = (τ c + τ n )( τ n ) /(+λ) [ τ c ηκ ( + λ) + κ(ηλ + ) τ n κ( η) ] /(+λ). 23

Then, dt dτ c = ( τn ) /(+λ) [ τ c ηκ ( + λ) + κ(ηλ + ) τ n κ( η) ] /(+λ) [ τ c ηκλ + κ(ηλ + τ n ) ] > 0. C Equilibrium system of the dynamic model The equilibrium system of the dynamic model is ( + τ c t )λ t = u (c t, n t ), λ t ( τ n t )w t = u 2 (c t, n t ), λ t = βe t { λt+ [ ( δ) + ( τ k t+ )(d t+ δ) + δ ]}, λ t = βe t [ λt+ R b t+], k t = ( δ)k t + x t, y t = ξ t [k t ] θ n θ t, w t = ( θ) y t n t, d t = θ y t k t, y t = c t + x t + g t m t, T t = τ c t c t + τ n t w t n t + τ k t (d t δ)k t, where the marginal utilities are defined by u (c t, n t ) (c t ) η, u 2 (c t, n t ) κ( + λ)ψ t( γ) n λ t 24

if the utility function is the additively separable U AS, and by u (c t, n t ) (c t ) [ ] η κ( η)nt +λ η, { u 2 (c t, n t ) η ( + λ) (c t ) [ ] η κ( η)n +λ η } t κn λ t if the utility function is Trabandt-Uhlig U TU. Detrend the equilibrium system by ψ = ξ /( θ), and let a t /ξ t ã t (except for k t k t /ξ t and λ). The detrended equilibrium system is ( + τ c t ) λ t = u ( c t, n t ), λ t ( τ n t ) w t = u 2 ( c t, n t ), λ t = βψ η E t { λ t+ [ ( δ) + ( τ k t+ )(d t+ δ) + δ ]}, λ t = βψ η E t [ λ t+ R b t+], ψ k t = ( δ) k t + x t, t = [ k t ] θ n θ t, w t = ( θ) t n t, d t = θ t k t. t = c t + x t + g t m t, T t = τ c t c t + τ n t w t n t + τ k t (d t δ) k t. 25

On the balanced growth path, the system becomes ( + τ c ) λ = u ( c, n), λ( τ n ) w = u 2 ( c, n), = βψ η [ ( δ) + ( τ k )(d δ) + δ ], = βψ η R b, ψ k = ( δ) k + x, = [ k ] θ n θ, w = ( θ) n, d = θ k. = c + x + g m t, T = τ c t c + τ n wn + τ k (d δ) k. The balanced growth path values are obtained by R b = ψη β, d = τ k [ R b + δ ], k = θ d, x = [ ψ ( δ) ] k, c = x g + m, n [ ] θ/( θ) =, k w = ( θ) ñ, given g/ = ϕ g and m/ = ϕ m. From this system, the following lemma is obtained from the balanced growth path equilibrium system. 26

Lemma. On the balanced growth path, the dividend (d), capital output ratio (k/y = k/), investment output ratio (x/y = x/), consumption output ratio (c/y = c/), and labor output ratio (n/) are independent from the consumption tax rate (τ c ). D Proof of Proposition 5 Proof. By the optimization condition for the consumption labor choice, it follows that κ( + λ) c η n λ = τn + τ c w, = ( + τ c ) /(η+λ) θ κ( + λ) ( τn ) ( c ) η ( ) λ /(η+λ) n. Since c/ = c/y and h/ are independent of τ c as in Lemma of Appendix C, it follows that d c/ c dτ c /τ = d/ c dτ c /τ = c η + λ τ c + τ. c Then, d c/ c dτ c /τ c = η + λ τ c { } ( η λ)τ c (η + λ). + τ c Suppose η + λ =. In this case, d c/ c dτ c /τ c < 0. Suppose η + λ. In this case, d c/ c dτ c /τ c = η λ η + λ If η + λ, then d c/ c dτ c /τ c for τ c 0. τ c { τ c + τ c η + λ }. η λ If η + λ <, then d c/ c dτ c /τ c for τ c (η + λ)/( η λ), and d c/ c dτ c /τ c > for τ c > (η + λ)/( η λ). 27

E Proof of Proposition 6 Proof. The optimization condition for the consumption labor choice, { } κ cn λ η ( + λ) = τn ( θ) κ( η)n +λ + τc h, yields that = ( ) [ (κ) /(+λ) ( η) + n θ ( c ) η( + λ) + ] /(+λ) τc. τ n Since > 0 for τ c 0, ( η) + θ ( ) c η( + λ) τ > 0. n Since c/ = c/y is independent of τ c as in Lemma of Appendix C, it follows that Letting d c/ c dτ c /τ = d/ c dτ c /τ c = Ψ = ( η) + θ θ ( η) + θ ( ) c η ( + τ c τ n ( c ) η τ c τ n ( c ) η ( +τ c τ n ) ( + λ). ) ( + λ) > 0, it follows that d c/ c dτ c /τ c = Ψ { ( η) + θ ( ) c η( + λ) τ + n θ ( ) } c η τc τ λ < 0. n F Proof of Proposition 7 Proof. The total tax revenue is T = τ c c + τ n wn + τ k (d δ) k [ ( ) ( )] c k = τ c + τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ). 28

Since c/ = c/y and k/ = k/y are independent of τ c as in Lemma of Appendix C, the first-order derivative is Since d T dτ c = ( ) [ ( ) c c + τ c + τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) = ( + τ c ) /(η+λ) θ κ( + λ) ( τn ) ( c ( )] k d dτ. c ) η ( ) λ /(η+λ) n, then d T dτ = ( + c τc ) /(η+λ) θ ( c κ( + λ) ( τn ) ( ) { ( ) c η + λ + τ c ( η + λ η + λ c ) η ( ) λ /(η+λ) n ) [ τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )]} k. Suppose that η + λ =. Then, d T dτ = ( + c τc ) /(η+λ) θ κ( + λ) ( τn ) ( ) { c ( η + λ η + λ c ( ) η ( c n ) [ τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )] k < η + λ, then, d T > 0. dτ c If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )] k > η + λ, then d T > 0. dτ c If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )] k = η + λ, then d T = 0. dτ c Suppose that η + λ. It follows that d T dτ = ( + c τc ) /(η+λ) θ ( c κ( + λ) ( τn ) [ {( ) [ τ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) η + λ c ) λ /(η+λ) ( k )]}. ) η ( ) λ /(η+λ) ( ) ( n c η + λ η + λ ( )] }] k (η + λ). Suppose that η + λ >. If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )] k η + λ, then d T > 0 for τ c 0. dτ c If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k )] > η + λ, 29 )

then d T dτ c < 0 for τ c < η+λ and d T dτ c 0 for τ c > η+λ {( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( } k )] (η + λ), {( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( } k )] (η + λ). Suppose that η + λ <. If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )] k η + λ, then d T > 0 for τ c 0. dτ c If ( ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k )] < η + λ, { ( then d T > 0 for τ c < dτ c η λ (η + λ) ) [ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k )]}, and d T dτ c < 0 for τ c > η λ { (η + λ) ( c ) [ τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( k )]}. G Proof of Proposition 8 Proof. The total tax revenue is T = τ c c + τ n wn + τ k (d δ) k [ ( ) ( )] c k τ c + τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ). Since c/ = c/y and k/ = k/y are independent of τ c as in Lemma of Appendix C, the first-order derivative is ( d T c dτ = c ) + [ ( ) c τ c + τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( )] k d dτ. c Since = ( ) [ κ /(+λ) ( η) + n θ ( ) c η( + λ) ( )] + τ c /(+λ), τ n it follows that d dτ = ( ( c c θ n) Then, d T ( c dτ = c n { τ c λ τ n ) κ /(+λ) [ ( η) + ( c ) [ θ ( c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ) ηκ /(+λ) [ ( η) + θ ( ) c η( + λ) ) ] /(+λ) η( + λ)( + τ c ) ( k ) ( )] + τ c /(+λ). θ τ n ( ) ( c η η ( θ)( τn ) ( + λ) 30 ( c τ n )]}. ) η

If τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( ) k η ( θ)( η τn ) + ( + λ) ( ) c, then d T 0. dτ c If τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( ) k > η ( θ)( η τn ) + ( + λ) ( c ), ( then d T < 0 for τ c < ) [ dτ c λ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( ) k η ( θ)( η τn ) ( + λ) ( c )], ( and d T > 0 for τ c > ) [ dτ c λ c τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) ( ) k η ( θ)( η τn ) ( + λ) ( c )]. H Procedure for the numerical calculations Given the steady-state labor supply n = 0.2, the parameter of disutility of labor, κ, is calibrated as follows. First, the steady-state values are calculated by [ ] ψ η d = τ k β + δ, k = θ d, x = [ ψ ( δ) ] k, c = x g + m, [ ] θ/( θ) n k =, ( ) n = n. If the utility is additively separable U AS, κ is given by ( ) θ τ n η ( ) λ c n κ =. η+λ ( + λ) + τ c If the utility is Trabandt-Uhlig U TU, κ is given by ( ) +λ [ κ = (+λ) ( η) + ( ) c η( + λ) + ] τc. n θ τ n Given the value of κ, the output is given by = ( + τ c ) /(η+λ) θ κ( + λ) ( τn ) ( c ) η ( ) λ /(η+λ) n, 3

if the utility is additively separable U AS. If the utility is Trabandt-Uhlig U TU, the output is given by = ( ) [ κ /(+λ) ( η) + n θ ( c The associated capital stock and consumption are k = k, c = c, respectively. Finally, the total tax revenue is given by T = τ c c + τ n wn + τ k (d δ) k = τ c c + τ n ( θ) + τ k (d δ) k. ) η( + λ) + ] /(+λ) τc. τ n I Proof of Remark Suppose that the additively separable utility U AS. In this case, as in Appendix D, = ( + τ c ) /(η+λ) θ κ( + λ) ( τn ) ( c ) η ( ) λ /(η+λ) n. Since /n is independent from τ n as in Lemma, the equilibrium elatiscity of labor supply with respect to labor income tax rate is εn AS = dn/n dτ n /dτ n = d/ dτ n /dτ n = η + λ τ n τ. n It is easily found that dn/n dτ n /τ n is increasing in τ n. dn/n dτ n /τ n = 0 if τ n = 0 and dn/n dτ n /τ n if τ n. Suppose that the Traband-Uhlig utility U TU, In this case, the equilibrium output is given by = ( ) [ (κ) /(+λ) ( η) + n θ 32 ( c ) η( + λ) + ] /(+λ) τc, τ n

as in Appendix E. Since /n is independent from τ n as in Lemma, the equilibrium elatiscity of labor supply with respect to labor income tax rate is ( ε TU n = dn/n dτ n /dτ n = d/ dτ n /dτ n = + λ τ n c τ θ y) η( + λ) +τ c τ ( n n ( η) + c θ y) η( + λ) +τ c τ n Then, dn/n dτ n /τ n is increasing in τ n. dn/n dτ n /τ n = 0 if τ n = 0, and dn/n dτ n /τ n if τ n. Suppose that η >. In this case, Then, ε TU n > ε AS n. η + λ < + λ < + λ Suppose that η. In this case, η + λ + λ + λ ( c θ y) η( + λ) +τ c τ n ( η) + θ ( c y) η( + λ) +τ c ( c θ y) η( + λ) +τ c τ n ( η) + θ τ n. ( c y) η( + λ) +τ c τ n Then, ε TU n ε AS n. 33

Figure : Shape of the total tax revenue curve for consumption tax Additively separable (tau n = 0.28) Trabandt-Uhlig (tau n = 0.28) I lambda 0.5 H lambda 0.5 I D 0 0 0.5 eta Additively separable (tau n = 0.7) U 0 0 0.5 eta Trabandt-Uhlig (tau n = 0.7) lambda 0.5 D F I H lambda 0.5 I 0 0 0.5 eta Additively separable (tau n = 0.9) 0 0 0.5 eta Trabandt-Uhlig (tau n = 0.9) U I lambda 0.5 D lambda 0.5 I 0 0 0.5 eta 0 U 0 0.5 eta Note - I: monotonically increasing, H: hump-shaped, D: monotonically decreasing, U: U-shaped, F: flat. 34

Figure 2: Total tax revenue curve for consumption tax: η = /2 and λ = /0 Additively separable utility Trabandt-Uhlig utility Normalized tax revenue 00 80 60 40 20 Normalized tax revenue 200 50 00 50 total tauc taun tauk 0 0 20 40 60 80 00 % 0 0 20 40 60 80 00 % 35

Figure 3: Total tax revenue curves for labor income tax 60 eta=2, lambda= 60 eta=/2, lambda=0. Normalized total tax revenue 40 20 00 80 60 40 20 Additively separable utility Trabandt-Uhlig utility Normalized total tax revenue 40 20 00 80 60 40 20 0 0 20 40 60 80 00 % 0 0 20 40 60 80 00 % 36

Figure 4: Total tax revenue curves for capital income tax 20 eta=2, lambda= 20 eta=/2, lambda=0. Normalized total tax revenue 00 80 60 40 20 Additively separable utility Trabandt-Uhlig utility Normalized total tax revenue 00 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 00 % 0 20 40 60 80 00 % 37