Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World

Similar documents
Defining Eligibility for Social Pensions 1

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

The World Bank in Pensions Executive Summary

Inclusive growth in Russia: Achievements and Challenges

BOX 1.3. Recent Developments in Emerging and Developing Country Labor Markets

UNIVERSITY OF WAIKATO. Hamilton New Zealand. An Illustration of the Average Exit Time Measure of Poverty. John Gibson and Susan Olivia

Will Growth eradicate poverty?

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

Comment on Counting the World s Poor, by Angus Deaton

Day 6: 7 November international guidelines and recommendations Presenter: Ms. Sharlene Jaggernauth, Statistician II, CSO

What is So Bad About Inequality? What Can Be Done to Reduce It? Todaro and Smith, Chapter 5 (11th edition)

Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized

All social security systems are income transfer

Indicator 1.2.1: Proportion of population living below the national poverty line, by sex and age

Poverty and income inequality

A Measured Approach to Ending Poverty and Boosting Shared Prosperity Concepts, Data, and the Twin Goals

2. SAVING TRENDS IN TURKEY IN INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON

Assisting the Elderly Poor: Social Pensions? or Social Assistance?

Poverty among children and the elderly in developing countries. Angus Deaton Christina Paxson

Executive summary WORLD EMPLOYMENT SOCIAL OUTLOOK

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006

Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A Statistical Brief

Monitoring Socio-Economic Conditions in Argentina, Chile, Paraguay and Uruguay CHILE. Paula Giovagnoli, Georgina Pizzolitto and Julieta Trías *

Poverty: Analysis of the NIDS Wave 1 Dataset

Chapter 5 Poverty, Inequality, and Development

Institutional information. Concepts and definitions

WOMEN AND FINANCIAL INCLUSION: Results from the Global Findex Asli Demirguc-Kunt, Leora Klapper, & Dorothe Singer

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

Closing the Gap: The State of Social Safety Nets 2017 Safety Nets where Needs are Greatest

Executive summary. Universal social protection to achieve the Sustainable Development Goals

Overview of Demographic Dividend. Andrew Mason Demographic Dividend Working Group Barcelona, Spain June 5 8, 2013

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

Potential impacts of climate change on $2-a-day poverty and child mortality in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia

Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality

ASPIRE: Atlas of Social Protection Indicators of Resilience and Equity

IDA s Lending Commitments, Disbursements, and Funding in FY01. I. Introduction

Development. AEB 4906 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics

Unemployment Compensation in a Worldwide Recession

Who Benefits from Water Utility Subsidies?

POVERTY ANALYSIS IN MONTENEGRO IN 2013

Pension Patterns and Challenges in Sub-Saharan Africa World Bank Pensions Core Course April 27, 2016

IMPACT OF GOVERNMENT PROGRAMMES USING ADMINISTRATIVE DATA SETS SOCIAL ASSISTANCE GRANTS

MONTENEGRO. Name the source when using the data

Poverty among the Elderly in Latin America and the Caribbean

1 For the purposes of validation, all estimates in this preliminary note are based on spatial price index computed at PSU level guided

MEASURING INCOME AND MULTI-DIMENSIONAL POVERTY: THE IMPLICATIONS FOR POLICY

PENSION NOTES No APRIL Non-contributory pension programs in Latin America

Public economics: inequality and poverty

2018 SYMBIOTICS MIV SURVEY A study of Global Microfinance Investment Funds

PPI data update note 28 November Private activity in infrastructure down, but still around peak levels

Multidimensional Elderly Poverty Index

Project Information Document/ Identification/Concept Stage (PID)

Adjusting for Differences in Needs and Economies of Scale in the Measurement of Poverty in Morocco

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

POVERTY PROFILES. Serbia National Poverty Analysis Workshop March 31 April 4, 2008

What Explains the U-Shape Form of Women s Labor Force Participation Rate?

Measuring Poverty in Latin America and the Caribbean

WHAT WILL IT TAKE TO ERADICATE EXTREME POVERTY AND PROMOTE SHARED PROSPERITY?

Recent developments. Note: The author of this section is Yoki Okawa. Research assistance was provided by Ishita Dugar. 1

CIRPÉE Centre interuniversitaire sur le risque, les politiques économiques et l emploi

A Lost Decade for Equality, Development and Human Rights? Assessing austerity and its alternatives 10 years after the global financial crisis

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

SESSION 8 Fiscal Incidence in South Africa

DESCRIPTION OF ALL THE GINIS DATASET (version Summer 2013) Created by Branko Milanovic World Bank, Research Department

Assessing Targeting and Poverty Performance

Medicare Beneficiaries and Their Assets: Implications for Low-Income Programs

Download the full paper»

School Attendance, Child Labour and Cash

Social Pensions. Robert Palacios, Lead Pensions, World Bank Pension Core Course, April 28, 2015

Inequality in China: Recent Trends. Terry Sicular (University of Western Ontario)

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Growth, Inequality, and Social Welfare: Cross-Country Evidence

Labour. Overview Latin America and the Caribbean. Executive Summary. ILO Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean

9FG jg\e[`e^ fe _\Xck_ ?fn cxi^\ `j k_\ dxib\k6

Growth in Labor Earnings Across the Income Distribution: Latin America During the 2000s

THE EVOLUTION OF POVERTY IN RWANDA FROM 2000 T0 2011: RESULTS FROM THE HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS (EICV)

Economic Consequence of Population Ageing in Asia

Part I Jobs and earnings of the poor

Insights from key databases and measurements of poverty and inequality

Appendix B: Methodology and Finding of Statistical and Econometric Analysis of Enterprise Survey and Portfolio Data

BLS Spotlight on Statistics: International Labor Comparisons

Leora Klapper, Senior Economist, World Bank Inessa Love, Senior Economist, World Bank

They grew up in a booming economy. They were offered unprecedented

CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION. decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of household

Global Aging and Financial Markets

Growth and Poverty Revisited from a Multidimensional Perspective

THE SENSITIVITY OF INTERNATIONAL POVERTY COMPARISONS

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

POVERTY IN AUSTRALIA: NEW ESTIMATES AND RECENT TRENDS RESEARCH METHODOLOGY FOR THE 2016 REPORT

A Toolkit for Informality Scenario Analysis: A User Guide

The Elderly Population in Vietnam during Economic Transformation: An Overview

Social Protection: An Indispensable Tool for a New Social Contract

Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Concepts and Measurement

ECON 450 Development Economics

Economics 448 Lecture 13 Poverty and Malnutrition

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Income Distribution Database (

OLD AGE POVERTY IN THE INDIAN STATES: WHAT THE HOUSEHOLD DATA CAN SAY? May 4, 2005

Transcription:

Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized The note is a joint product of the Social Protection and Labor & Poverty and Equity Global Practices. Abstract 1,2 This note shows that based on headcount poverty rates, at the household level, households with elderly members are roughly equally poor to non-elderly households, though with variation when using more detailed compositions, and the elderly are less poor than children in 98 percent of the countries sampled when comparing different age groups. Further, as a share of the poor, elderly average only 10 percent, children 36 percent, and adults 54 percent. Moderate equivalence adjustments result in a four percentage point change in the number of countries with children better off than elderly. (A separate note provides detailed sensitivity analysis.) 3 These results can be seen as a starting point for further analysis that would look at the reasons behind differences between countries as well as age sub-groups within countries. The findings provide preliminary evidence that households with elderly, and especially elderly individuals are often not the most poor. The analysis is relevant to countries considering new policies or reforms of existing programs targeting particular age groups, such as the elderly or children. I. Background Pensions & Social Insurance Social Protection & Labor Policy Note June 2015 Number 18 Highlight Survey data from 62 developing countries is used that represents more than half the world s population. Poverty head count by age varies by the unit of analysis. Ranking by individuals, we find that children are the poorest group in all but one country, while households with and without elderly are equally poor. Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World Brooks Evans and Robert Palacios Whether the elderly are poor relative to children and adults in society has important implications for social and economic policy. Large components of social protection systems can be traced to society s concern about poverty among the elderly and children, often viewed as the most at-risk groups. Both contributory and non-contributory pension programs emerged in the wake of urbanization and industrialization as traditional patterns of old-age income support became less relevant for workers that depended 1 Citation guideline: Evans, B. and Palacios, P. 2015. Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World. World Bank. Washington D.C. JEL Codes: B410, D040, D600, H550, O150, O200 2 The note was written by Brooks Evans (bevans2@worldbank.org) and Robert Palacios (rpalacios@ worldbank.org). Peer review comments provided by Margaret Grosh, Phillippe Leite, and Kinnon Scott. Additional comments were provided during a May 5, 2015 Social Protection & Labor and Poverty cosponsored discussion on Who is Poorer? Age-based Poverty Patterns and Measurement: Findings & Implications for Bank Operations & Clients. 3 See Evans, B. 2016. Equivalence Sensitivity of Age-Based Poverty Measures. World Bank. Washington D.C. 1

on wages. In the high income countries, this has resulted in large transfer systems and generally low poverty rates for the elderly relative to the population. This has led some OECD countries to question transfers from relatively poor households with adults often with children, to relatively well-off elderly households via payroll taxes. In most low and middle income countries, 4 pension systems have failed to achieve high coverage, and the majority of the elderly continue to depend on traditional income support sources, especially family.⁵ Along with children and the disabled, the elderly are often considered to be vulnerable to poverty. The ILO recommends that its Minimum Floor be applied specifically to the elderly as well as these other vulnerable groups. Previous evidence as to whether the elderly are poorer than other age groups generally shows this is often not the case, with children most frequently the poorest. In his review of studies available at the time, Whitehouse (2000), found that most studies show that the old are represented proportionally or under-represented among the poor. His analysis focused mainly on middle and higher income countries, but similar findings have been presented for low income countries such as India and many countries in Sub-Saharan Africa.⁶ This note provides comparative poverty rankings, mainly using per capita welfare, of elderly and non-elderly households and individuals in 62 developing countries. Recognizing the shortcomings of per capita welfare, a companion note investigates how the two most common parametric equivalence scale adjustments economies of scale and composition, affect the distribution and measures of poverty by age. 7 II. Methodology The data are from the World Bank s ASPIRE, ECAPOV, and SEDLAC databases, which are based on household survey data.⁸ While over 70 surveys were available, only 62 are used since only these contained basic demographic individual information needed for age-based poverty analysis. The surveys have been harmonized in terms of coding and to the extent possible, variable definitions. There are some 4 The developing country regions included are Sub-Saharan Africa (AFR), East Asia and the Pacific (EAP), Eastern Europe and Central Asia (ECA), Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC), Middle East and Northern Africa (MNA), and South Asia (SAR). 5 See Evans. B and Palacios, R. 2015. An Examination of Elderly Coresidence in the Developing World. World Bank. Washington D.C. for the extent of family support. 6 See Deaton (1997) and Pal and Palacios (2011) for India and Kakwani and Subbarao (2005) for Africa. 7 The use of per capita welfare with its inherent assumptions, has clear limitations as discussed in Deaton and Paxson (1997) and many others. 8 See www.worldbank.org/aspire, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/ sedlac, and http://povertydata.worldbank.org/poverty/region/eca. 9 See Evans, B. 2016. Using Household Surveys for Age-based Poverty, Pensions, and Social Assistance Analysis. World Bank. Washington D.C., which can be downloaded at www.worldbank.org/pensions. differences between the instruments. These are discussed in a separate methodological note.⁹ Age groupings are also harmonized to allow for comparability across countries. Child is defined as age 0-14, Adult 15-59, and Elderly 60+. Welfare aggregate: While recognizing the tradeoffs inherent to welfare measurement, monetary based welfare per capita is used as a baseline, as this is among the most commonly used approaches. 10 All regions in the sample use expenditure except for Latin America and the Caribbean, where only income data is available. Welfare per capita is calculated by taking a household s consumption expenditure or income 11 and dividing by the number of household members. 12 The formula, if consumption is used is: Per capita expenditure = household consumption expenditure houshehold size This calculation implicitly assumes 1) that there is no benefit from living in in larger households, such as sharing housing, cooking supplies or transportation costs (i.e. economies of scale do not exist); and 2) all household members have equal income or consumption needs and access, and so a fiveyear-old consumes the same as an adult in labor intensive employment (i.e. no economies of composition exist.) 13 Although these assumptions can and have been contested, there is no agreement on the best approach. This note crossreferences a detailed analysis of the sensitivity to different assumptions about composition and scale economies and presents a feasible adjustment derived from that analysis (0.75 economies of scale and composition). Poverty lines: Relative poverty rates are used here as this note focuses on comparing poverty rates of different age groups and household compositions in the sample countries. An absolute poverty line is not used, as poverty rates would be close to zero percent in higher income countries, such as in ECA and some in LAC, while there would be higher poverty rates in low income countries. 14 The choice of any poverty line will affect the percentage of people that are poor. Two measures of relative poverty are used: the share of households and individuals that (i) fall within the poorest two quintiles of the distribution and (ii) those that fall below half of median per capita expenditure/income. The latter poverty line will tend to capture more of the distributional dynamics in a country. Poverty lines are generated both at the individual and household level. 10 Sen (1985) and others define poverty based on concepts of capabilities and functioning. 11 Consumption expenditure is generally seen as a more robust measure of welfare (see for example Deaton 1997). Here, the term per capita welfare refers to consumption unless only income is available. 12 These surveys do not provide data that would allow us to look at intrahousehold distribution of resources. 13 Adult equivalent adjustment are often used, for example, children and/or elderly can be assumed to consume a fraction of adults, such as 50 percent, and would each be 0.5 adult equivalents, which decreases the effective household size. 14 Commonly used absolute poverty lines are $1.25 and $2.50 USD a day. 2

Social Protection & Labor World Bank Group Poverty measure: Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (FGT) measures are used for calculating the poverty headcount (FGT0), gap (FGT1), and severity (FGT2). This measurement approach is commonly used, and allows for sub-group decomposition, such as analysis by differing household types or age groups. The note focuses primarily on poverty headcount. and 34 percent), while AFR is lowest (23 percent). Only five percent of households have only elderly members. These figures are highest in ECA at 10 percent, while averaging one to three percent in the other regions. Households with adult members and children are the largest group in all regions (averaging 53 percent of households in sample countries). Household-level poverty III. Results The following section presents the findings of the population shares of different household types, and poverty rankings of households. This is followed by individual-level analysis. Household types Table 1 shows the composition of households in the sample of countries used for this analysis. The data are presented by region using simple averages with the important caveat that the regional samples vary in size and are therefore not fully representative. Table 1: Household types by region (%) AFR EAP ECA LAC MNA SAR Avg Elderly only - lone 1 1 4 1 0 0 2 Elderly only - 2+ 1 1 6 2 0 1 3 Elderly & Adult 4 7 14 10 6 6 10 Elderly & Children 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 3-Generation 16 18 16 14 19 27 17 Adult only 9 13 24 15 5 9 16 Adult & Children 69 59 36 56 69 57 53 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Source: Authors calculations. Avg in final column refers to simple average for all sample countries. Poverty rates among elderly households. Figure 1a and 1b show per capita poverty rates for households with elderly based on the two poverty lines. Each bar represents a country. Figure 1a refers to the share of households with elderly with less than half the median welfare per capita. Figure 1b refers to the share of households with elderly that can be found in the bottom two quintiles of the distribution. There is significant cross-country variation: the range for the 50 percent of median per capita measure is between 4 percent and 26 percent. Between 29 percent and just over one half of households with elderly are in the bottom 40 percent of the distribution. On average, 13 percent of households with any elderly are poor based on the 50 percent median measure, while an average of 41 percent of households with elderly are found in the bottom 40 percent of the distribution. 15 Figure 1a: Households with elderly, poverty rates using 50% of median Share of households with elderly below poverty line 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Source: Authors' calculations, poverty line set at 50% median. Figure 1b: Households with elderly, poverty rates using 40th percentile Share of households with elderly below poverty line 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% The share of households in our sample with any elderly members averages 32 percent. The difference between regions is not as high as might be expected given the shares of elderly people in the total population: Notably ECA and SAR have the highest share of households with elderly (40 percent Source: Authors' calculations, poverty line set at 40th percentile. 15 Since 50 percent median poverty lines capture national distribution shapes, high variation in poverty lines and rates is expected. 3

Poverty rates of elderly compared to other households. Figures 2a and 2b show the difference in poverty rates of households with and without elderly. These figures hide significant differences in poverty rates among differing household arrangements. In most countries, for example, households with only elderly members are not as poor as households with both elderly and non-elderly members. The results show that the share of countries with elderly and non-elderly households poorest is roughly equal, though with some variation. In Figure 2b, in over a third of the countries, the poverty rates differ by two and a half percentage points or less. Poverty rates differ substantially in only about one in eight countries, depending on the cutoff applied. Elderly-only households are the least poor household type in the majority of the countries, and so most of the poor households with elderly contain non-elderly members. The combination of the financial ability to live alone, and the more mechanical explanation that household welfare is only divided by fewer people in elderly only households explains much of this result. Figure 2a: Difference in poverty rates at 50% median Not surprisingly, households with only elderly and children are poorer than other households as these are not prime working ages. 16 This is followed by three-generation households, while adult-only households are the least poor. When considering population shares, adult with children households are the largest population group and represent the highest share of poor households (55%), followed by elderly with children (19.6%), while the smallest shares are elderly with adult (0.2%) and elderly-lone households (0.8%). Individual-level poverty Ranking individuals rather than households allows for more a direct comparison of poverty rates among age groups. 17 Figures 3a and 3b compares poverty rates for children, adults and elderly individuals in each country. The orange line shows the poverty rates of adult individuals, and the x-axis moves from left to right starting with the lowest overall poverty rate. The higher line refers to children poverty rates while the bottom line refers to elderly poverty rates. Figure 3a: Poverty rates by age using 50% median Non-elderly minus elderly househld poverty rate 20.0% 15.0% 10.0% 5.0% 0.0% -5.0% -10.0% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Children Adults Elderly -15.0% Source: Authors' calculations, poverty line 50% median. Figure 2b: Difference in poverty rates, bottom two quintiles Source: Authors' calculations with poverty line 50% median. Figure 3b: Poverty rates by age using 40 th percentile 25.0% 70% Non-elderly minus elderly househld poverty rate 20.0% 15.0% 10.0% 5.0% 0.0% -5.0% -10.0% -15.0% -20.0% -25.0% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Children Adults Elderly Source: Authors' calculations, poverty line 40th centile. Source: Authors' calculations with poverty line set at 40th percentile in each country. 16 Economies of scale also have an effect, as larger households are generally poorer when using per capita, which assumes not resources are shared. 17 Though still subject to measurement issues since data is collected at the household and extrapolated to the individual level, and per capita fails to capture scale or composition economies. 4

Social Protection & Labor World Bank Group The figures shows that with only two exceptions (Iraq for 50 percent median, and Bhutan for the 40th percentile), per capita, the poverty rates of children are always higher than for either adults or elderly. While not in the figure, older elderly, defined as age 75 and above, are poorer than younger elderly in three-quarters of the countries sampled. It is interesting to note that the countries where the disparity between poverty rates of children and the elderly are highest are all located in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, East Asia and the Pacific, and Latin America (in particular in the Southern Cone countries). 18 In Brazil, for example, the relative poverty rate of children is more than three and a half times the rate of the elderly (61 percent and 17 percent respectively). The lowest differentials are found in South Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa. Looking beyond the headcount poverty rates, the poverty gap is on average the lowest for elderly and highest for children. This means that on average, of the elderly that are poor, they are less poor, as they lie closer to the poverty line than children. As measured by the poverty gap, in all regions, poor children are the poorer than poor elderly. As has been shown, the poverty headcount of children is higher than adults and elderly in nearly all sample countries, and this result is accentuated when accounting for population shares. Elderly average just over 12 percent of the population, while children over two and a half this at 29 percent, and adults five times at 59 percent. The poverty headcount of children averages 16 percentage points above elderly and 14 percentage points above adults. When looking the distribution among the poor, the highest headcount and second highest population share results in children representing 36 percent of the poor. Elderly by contrast have the smallest share of the poor at 10 percent due to both the lowest incidence and population size. Adults represent 54 percent of the poor, which is mainly driven by their population share that average just under 60 percent. On a per capita basis, the findings show that elderly are the least poor and smallest share of the poor, while children have the highest poverty measures (headcount and gap) and are the second largest group among the poor. Comparative poverty rates at the household and individual level Another approach of analysis is to focus on poverty rates of individuals compared to households. Figure 4, based on the poverty line set at half of the median, shows that as expected, while the correlation between individual elderly and elderly household poverty rates is high, the latter are generally higher. (The outlier is Iraq.) Sensitivity of the results As mentioned earlier, the results presented here will be affected by assumptions about the effects of household economies of scale and composition on welfare. Economies of scale, through the shared use of resources such as stoves or bulk purchases, could justify adjustments to the welfare used to compare households and individuals. Larger household sizes appear better-off as greater scale economies are assumed. Lower consumption needs of children and the elderly may also justify using equivalence scales in these comparisons. A companion note Equivalence Sensitivity of Age-Based Poverty Measures reviews the relevant literature and tests the results to a wide range of possible adjustments. A general finding regarding the comparison of children and the elderly is that the most important impact appears to come from scale economy adjustments. Source: Authors calculations with poverty line 50% median. 18 Countries where child poverty is greater than 40 percentage points above elderly include Brazil (44 percent) and Uruguay (43 percent). 5

Figure 5: Illustration of sensitivity of poverty differentials (elderly & children) to 0.75 equivalence 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% Equivalized 0.75 20.0% India Hungary Argentina 10.0% 0.0% -10% 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% Moldova Bhutan Bosnia Croatia -10.0% Per capita Source: Authors calculations using 0.75 equivalence. A positive percent means that the children poorer than elderly. With this in mind, Figure 5 highlights the differential between poverty rates of elderly and children based on the 40th percentile cutoff line with and without an equivalence adjustments for scale and composition. Clearly, the effect favors children and reduces the difference between poverty among children and elderly (as shown by the fact that all but one point lies below the 45 degree line). Of note is that even with the moderate 0.75 equivalence adjustment, children remain poorest in all but four countries, a slight decrease from children being poorest in all by one country using per capita. 19 In a small number of countries, the poverty rate differential becomes negative. In other words, poverty rates are higher for elderly than for children. This group is made up of ECA countries (Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia and Moldova), and elderly in Bhutan remain poorer than children. In a second group of countries, there is a large change in the differential, but elderly still have lower poverty rates. A third group has elderly poverty fall relative to children, which only includes India. The last and largest group of countries show only a small effect as they remain close to the 45 degree line. As economies of scale have been observed at 0.5 and assuming children and elderly consume 50 percent of adults may be realistic, future research examines more extreme equivalence adjustments to demonstrate the age poverty ranking effect. 19 As shown in the companion note, with a more substantial economies of scale value of 0.5, elderly become poorer than children in most countries. 6

IV. Conclusions and Future Research The key results presented in this note can be summarized as follows: 1. Poverty rates of elderly individuals and households with elderly members vary widely across countries. 2. There is no strong pattern for if households with or without elderly are poorer, though there is for certain household compositions. Adult with child households represent the largest share of poor households, while the smallest shares are elderly with adult and elderly-lone households. 3. Per capita children are poorer than the elderly in nearly all countries both by headcount and share of the poor. In some cases, particularly in the demographically older countries of Latin America, the difference is very high. Elderly individuals average the smallest share of the poor averaging 10 percent, children 36 percent, and adults with the largest share of 54 percent. 4. Old elderly are poorer than younger elderly in most countries. 5. The relative position of children versus the elderly changes in a few countries, especially in ECA, if moderate equivalence adjustments are applied. These results raise a number of important policy questions and suggest areas for further research. 1. Should countries with high levels of spending on programs for the elderly and high poverty rate differentials with children poorer reconsider their overall social protection policies? 2. Given high co-residence rates among the poor (see note on co-residence) 20, is there a case for targeting social pensions to poor households in many countries? 21 3. To what extent does dependence on payroll tax based contributory pensions as the main source of income for the elderly lead to the observed welfare disparities between the elderly and children? 4. How does the provision of health services and insurance affect this analysis given its importance for the elderly and children? 5. How will falling pension coverage in Eastern Europe and Central Asia change the relative poverty position of the elderly? 6. How will aging populations affect the share of poor and policies in different regions and countries? 6. Even with these adjustments, the difference between the poverty rates of children and the elderly persists, with children poorer than elderly in over 90 percent of the sample countries. 20 See Evans, B. and Palacios, R. 2014. An examination of elderly co-residence in the developing world. World Bank. Washington D.C. 21 A related issue is the potential impact of transfers to the elderly on intrahousehold allocation of resources as shown by the evidence on transfers to women in other programs. 7

References Deaton, A. and C. Paxson, 1997. Poverty Among Children and the Elderly in Developing Countries. Research Programme in Development Studies Working Paper No. 179, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University. Deaton, Angus S & Muellbauer, John, 1986. On Measuring Child Costs: With Applications to Poor Countries, Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 94(4), pages 720-44, August. Deaton, A. and C. Paxson, 1998. Economies of Scale, Household Size and the Demand for Food. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106, pp: 897-930. Evans, B. 2016. Using Household Surveys for Age-based Poverty, Pensions, and Social Assistance Analysis. World Bank. Washington D.C. Evans. B 2016. Equivalence Sensitivity of Age-Based Poverty Measures. World Bank. Washington D.C. Evans. B and Palacios, R. 2015. An Examination of Elderly Coresidence in the Developing World. World Bank. Washington D.C. Gasparini et al. 2007. Poverty Among the elderly in Latin America and the Caribbean. CEDLAS. Universidad Nacional de La Plata. La Plata, Argentina. Foster, J. Greer, J. Thorbecke E. 1984. A Class of Decomposable Poverty Indices. Econometrica 52, pp.761-766. Lanjouw, J.O., P. Lanjouw, B. Milanovic and S. Paternostro, 2004. Relative Price Shifts, Economies of Scale and Poverty During Economic Transition. Economics of Transition, Vol. 12(3), pp: 509-536. Lanjouw, P. and M. Ravallion. 1995. Poverty and Household Size. Economic Journal; 105: 1415-34. Pal S. and R. Palacios (2011), Understanding Poverty among the Elderly in India: Implications for Social Pension Policy, in Journal of Development Studies, August, 2011. (http://dx.doi.or g/10.1080/00220388.2010.509783) Robalino, D. Rao, G.V. and Sluchynsky, O. 2008. Preventing Poverty among the elderly in MENA countries: Role and Optimal Design of Old-Age Subsidies. World Bank, Washington, D.C. Sen, A., 1985. Commodities and Capabilities. Oxford: Oxford University Press Whitehouse. E. 2000 How poor are the old? A survey of evidence from 44 countries. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Zimmer and Das. 2013. The Poorest of the Poor: Composition and Wealth of Older Person Households in Sub-Saharan Africa. Research on Aging. Kakwani, N. and Subbarao, K. 2005. Aging and Poverty and the Role of Social Pensions. World Bank. Washington D.C. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. 2015 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank 8