Hedging under Arbitrage

Similar documents
Hedging under arbitrage

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Non-semimartingales in finance

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Risk Neutral Measures

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

MARTINGALES AND LOCAL MARTINGALES

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

The stochastic calculus

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Path Dependent British Options

Martingale Measure TA

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

The British Russian Option

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Conditional Full Support and No Arbitrage

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

American Spread Option Models and Valuation

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Sample Path Large Deviations and Optimal Importance Sampling for Stochastic Volatility Models

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Forward Dynamic Utility

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Implementing the HJM model by Monte Carlo Simulation

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Enlargement of filtration

4 Risk-neutral pricing

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Risk Neutral Valuation

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Law of the Minimal Price

King s College London

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lévy models in finance

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

An application of an entropy principle to short term interest rate modelling

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Monte Carlo Simulations

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Transcription:

Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011

Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous Markovian dynamics. If there does not exist an equivalent local martingale measure can we have the concept of hedging? Answer: Yes, if a square-integrable market price of risk exists. If there exists an equivalent local martingale measure and a stock price process is a strict local martingale what is the cheapest way to hold this stock at time T? Answer: Delta-hedging. How can we compute hedging prices? Answer: PDE techniques, (non-)equivalent changes of measures Techniques: Itô s formula, PDE techniques to prove smoothness of hedging prices, Föllmer measure

Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous Markovian dynamics. If there does not exist an equivalent local martingale measure can we have the concept of hedging? Answer: Yes, if a square-integrable market price of risk exists. If there exists an equivalent local martingale measure and a stock price process is a strict local martingale what is the cheapest way to hold this stock at time T? Answer: Delta-hedging. How can we compute hedging prices? Answer: PDE techniques, (non-)equivalent changes of measures Techniques: Itô s formula, PDE techniques to prove smoothness of hedging prices, Föllmer measure

Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous Markovian dynamics. If there does not exist an equivalent local martingale measure can we have the concept of hedging? Answer: Yes, if a square-integrable market price of risk exists. If there exists an equivalent local martingale measure and a stock price process is a strict local martingale what is the cheapest way to hold this stock at time T? Answer: Delta-hedging. How can we compute hedging prices? Answer: PDE techniques, (non-)equivalent changes of measures Techniques: Itô s formula, PDE techniques to prove smoothness of hedging prices, Föllmer measure

Two generic examples Reciprocal of the three-dimensional Bessel process (NFLVR): d S(t) = S 2 (t)dw (t) Three-dimensional Bessel process: ds(t) = 1 dt + dw (t) S(t)

Strict local martingales A stochastic process X ( ) is a local martingale if there exists a sequence of stopping times (τ n ) with lim n τ n = such that X τn ( ) is a martingale. Here, in our context, a local martingale is a nonnegative stochastic process X ( ) which does not have a drift: dx (t) = X (t)somethingdw (t). Strict local martingales (local martingales, which are not martingales) do only appear in continuous time. Nonnegative local martingales are supermartingales.

We assume a Markovian market model. Our time is finite: T <. Interest rates are zero. The stocks S( ) = (S 1 ( ),..., S d ( )) T follow ( ) K ds i (t) =S i (t) µ i (t, S(t))dt + σ i,k (t, S(t))dW k (t) k=1 with some measurability and integrability conditions. Markovian but not necessarily complete (K > d allowed). The covariance process is defined as K a i,j (t, S(t)) := σ i,k (t, S(t))σ j,k (t, S(t)). k=1 The underlying filtration is denoted by F = {F(t)} 0 t T.

An important guy: the market price of risk. A market price of risk is an R K -valued process θ( ) satisfying We assume it exists and T µ(t, S(t)) = σ(t, S(t))θ(t). 0 θ(t) 2 dt <. The market price of risk is not necessarily unique. We will always use a Markovian version of the form θ(t, S(t)). (needs argument!)

Related is the stochastic discount factor. The stochastic discount factor corresponding to θ is denoted by ( t Z θ (t) := exp θ T (u, S(u))dW (u) 1 t ) θ(u, S(u)) 2 du. 0 2 0 It has dynamics dz θ (t) = θ T (t, S(t))Z θ (t)dw (t). If Z θ ( ) is a martingale, that is, if E[Z θ (T )] = 1, then it defines a risk-neutral measure Q with dq = Z θ (T )dp. Otherwise, Z θ ( ) is a strict local martingale and classical arbitrage is possible. From Itô s rule, we have d ( ) Z θ (t)s i (t) = Z θ (t)s i (t) K (σ i,k (t, S(t)) θ k (t, S(t))) dw k (t) k=1

Everything an investor cares about: how and how much? We call trading strategy the number of shares held by an investor: η(t) = (η 1 (t),..., η d (t)) T We assume that η( ) is progressively measurable with respect to F and self-financing. The corresponding wealth process V v,η ( ) for an investor with initial wealth V v,η (0) = v has dynamics dv v,η (t) = d η i (t)ds i (t). i=1 We restrict ourselves to trading strategies which satisfy V 1,η (t) 0.

The terminal payoff Let p : R d + [0, ) denote a measurable function. The investor wants to have the payoff p(s(t )) at time T. For example, market portfolio: p(s) = d i=1 s i money market: p 0 (s) = 1 stock: p 1 (s) = s 1 call: p C (s) = (s 1 L) + for some L R. We define a candidate for the hedging price as [ Z ] h p (t, s) := E t,s θ (T )p(s(t )), where Z θ (T ) = Z θ (T )/Z θ (t) and S(t) = s under the expectation operator E t,s.

Non path-dependent European claims Assume that we have a contingent claim of the form p(s(t )) 0 and that for all points of support (t, s) for S( ) with t [0, T ) we have h p C 1,2 (U t,s ) for some neighborhood U t,s of (t, s). Then, with η p i (t, s) := D ih p (t, s) and v p := h p (0, S(0)), we get V v p,η p (t) = h p (t, S(t)). The strategy η p is optimal in the sense that for any ṽ > 0 and for any strategy η whose associated wealth process is nonnegative and satisfies V ṽ, η (T ) p(s(t )), we have ṽ v p. Furthermore, h p solves the PDE t hp (t, s) + 1 2 d i=1 j=1 d s i s j a i,j (t, s)di,jh 2 p (t, s) = 0 at all points of support (t, s) for S( ) with t [0, T ).

The proof relies on Itô s formula. Define the martingale N p ( ) as N p (t) := E[Z θ (T )p(s(t )) F(t)] = Z θ (t)h p (t, S(t)). Use a localized version of Itô s formula to get the dynamics of N p ( ). Since it is a martingale, its dt term must disappear which yields the PDE. Then, another application of Itô s formula yields dh p (t, S(t)) = d D i h p (t, S(t))dS i (t) = dv v p,η p (t). i=1 This yields directly V v p,η p ( ) h p (, S( )).

Proof (continued) Next, we prove optimality. Assume we have some initial wealth ṽ > 0 and some strategy η with nonnegative associated wealth process such that V ṽ, η (T ) p(s(t )) is satisfied. Then, Z θ ( )V ṽ, η ( ) is a supermartingale. This implies ṽ E[Z θ (T )V ṽ, η (T )] E[Z θ (T )p(s(t ))] = E[Z θ (T )V v p,η p (T )] = v p

Non-uniqueness of PDE Usually, t v(t, s) + 1 2 d i=1 j=1 does not have a unique solution. d s i s j a i,j (t, s)di,jv(t, 2 s) = 0 However, if h p is sufficiently differentiable, it can be characterized as the minimal nonnegative solution of the PDE. This follows as in the proof of optimality. If h is another nonnegative solution of the PDE with h(t, s) = p(s), then Z θ ( ) h(, S( )) is a supermartingale.

Corollary: Modified put-call parity For any L R we have the modified put-call parity for the calland put-options (S 1 (T ) L) + and (L S 1 (T )) +, respectively, with strike price L: E t,s [ Z θ (T )(L S 1 (T )) +] + h p1 (t, s) = E t,s [ Z θ (T )(S 1 (T ) L) +] + Lh p0 (t, s), where p 0 ( ) 1 denotes the payoff of one monetary unit and p 1 (s) = s 1 the price of the first stock for all s R d +.

Role of Markovian market price of risk Let M 0 be a random variable measurable with respect to F S (T ). Let ν( ) denote any MPR and θ(, ) a Markovian MPR. Then, with [ Z M ν ν ] [ (T ) (t) := E Z ν (t) M Z F t and M θ θ ] (T ) (t) := E Z θ (t) M F t for t [0, T ], we have M ν ( ) M θ ( ) almost surely.

Proof We define c( ) := ν( ) θ(, S( )) and c n ( ) := c( )1 {τn } for some localization sequence τ n. Then, Z ν (T ) Z ν (t) = lim Z cn (T ) n Z cn (t) ( T exp θ T (dw (u) + c n (u)du) 1 2 t T Since T 0 cn (t)dt is bounded, Z cn ( ) is a martingale. Fatou s lemma, Girsanov s theorem and Bayes rule yield M ν (t) lim inf n EQn [ exp ( T t θ T dw n (u) 1 2 t T Since σ(, S( ))c n ( ) 0 the process S( ) has the same dynamics under Q n as under P. t ) θ 2 du. ) 2 du M F t

We can change the measure to compute h p There exists not always an equivalent local martingale measure. However, after making some technical assumptions on the probability space and the filtration we can construct a new measure Q which corresponds to a removal of the stock price drift. Based on the work of Föllmer and Meyer and along the lines of Delbaen and Schachermayer.

Theorem: Under a new measure Q the drifts disappear. There exists a measure Q such that P Q. More precisely, for all nonnegative F(T )-measurable random variables Y we have ] E P [Z θ (T )Y ] = E [Y Q 1 { } 1. Z θ >0 (T ) Under this measure Q, the stock price processes follow ds i (t) = S i (t) K σ i,k (t, S(t)) d W k (t) k=1 up to time τ θ := inf{t [0, T ] : 1/Z θ (t) = 0}. Here, t τ θ W k (t τ θ ) := W k (t τ θ ) + θ k (u, S(u))du 0 is a K-dimensional Q-Brownian motion stopped at time τ θ.

What happens in between time 0 and time T : Bayes rule. For all nonnegative F(T )-measurable random variables Y the representation [ ] E Q Y 1 {1/Z θ (T )>0} F(t) = E P [Z θ 1 (T )Y F(t)] Z θ (t) 1 {1/Z θ (t)>0} holds Q-almost surely (and thus P-almost surely) for all t [0, T ].

After a change of measure, the Bessel process becomes Brownian motion. We look at a market with one stock: ds(t) = 1 dt + dw (t). S(t) We have S(t) > 0 for all t 0. The market price of risk is θ(t, s) = 1/s. The inverse stochastic discount factor 1/Z θ becomes zero exactly when S(t) hits 0. Removing the drift with a change of measure as before makes S( ) a Brownian motion (up to the first hitting time of zero by 1/Z θ ( )) under Q.

The optimal strategy for getting one dollar at time T can be explicitly computed. For p(s) p 0 (s) 1 we get [ Z h p0 (t, s) = E P θ (T ) Z θ (t) 1 t] F ( ) s = 2Φ 1. T t S(t)=s This yields the optimal strategy ( ) η 0 2 s (t, s) = φ. T t T t = E Q [1 {1/Z θ (T )>0} F t ] S(t)=s The hedging price h p satisfies on all points {s > 0} the PDE t hp (t, s) + 1 2 D2 h p (t, s) = 0.

Conclusion No equivalent local martingale measure needed to find an optimal hedging strategy based upon the familiar delta hedge. Sufficient conditions are derived for the necessary differentiability of expectations indexed over the initial market configuration. The dynamics of stochastic processes under a non-equivalent measure and a generalized Bayes rule might be of interest themselves. We have computed some optimal trading strategies in standard examples for which so far only ad-hoc and not necessarily optimal strategies have been known.

Thank you!