Non-semimartingales in finance

Similar documents
Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Hedging under Arbitrage

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON ARBITRAGE BY CHANGING THE STOCK EXCHANGE

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Hedging under arbitrage

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The stochastic calculus

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

Fractional Brownian Motion as a Model in Finance

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Risk Neutral Measures

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

The Black-Scholes Model

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

The Black-Scholes Model

On Leland s strategy of option pricing with transactions costs

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Fractional Brownian Motion as a Model in Finance

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Path Dependent British Options

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lévy models in finance

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

King s College London

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

King s College London

BLACK SCHOLES THE MARTINGALE APPROACH

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

MARTINGALES AND LOCAL MARTINGALES

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

The Black-Scholes Model

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Risk-Neutral Valuation

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Transcription:

Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology 1 / 34

Motivation Why Use Non-Semimartingales in Finance? Reasons against non-semimartingales: In stochastic finance one needs integration theory to define self-financing trading strategies. The semimartingale theory for integration is well-suited for stochastic finance. Also, since semimartingales are the largest class of integrators that have continuous integrals, one expects arbitrage with non-semimartingales. It is an economic axiom that there should be no arbitrage. 2 / 34

Motivation Why Use Non-Semimartingales in Finance? Reasons for non-semimartingales: Some stylized facts (e.g. long range dependence) are difficult to incorporate into the semimartingale world. Even with semimartingales one does not use actual probabilities (but the so-called equivalent martingale measure). So, the role of probability in stochastic finance is small, if it even exists. And semimartingale is a probabilistic concept. 3 / 34

Outline 1 Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging 2 Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation 3 Classical Black Scholes Model 4 Replication with Non-Semimartingales 5 No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales 4 / 34

Outline 1 Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging 2 Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation 3 Classical Black Scholes Model 4 Replication with Non-Semimartingales 5 No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales 5 / 34

Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging Assets Let (B t ) t [0,T ] be the bond, or bank account. We work in the discounted world: B t = 1 for all t [0, T ]. The bank account is riskless, i.e. non-random. Let S = (S t ) t [0,T ] be the stock. The stock is risky, i.e. random. 1 Classical assumption: S is a (continuous) semimartingale, typically the geometric Brownian motion. 2 Our assumption: S is continuous and has quadratic variation (We elaborate what we mean by quadratic variation later.) 6 / 34

Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging Options Definition (Option) Option is simply a real-valued mapping S G(S). The asset S is the underlying of the option G. Example G = (S T K) + is a call-option, G = (K S T ) + is a put-option, G = S T K is a future. T is the time of maturity and K is the strike-price. 7 / 34

Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging Trading strategies Definition (Self-financing Trading Strategy) Trading strategy Φ = (Φ t ) t [0,T ] is an S-adapted stochastic process that tells the units of the underlying asset S the investor has is her portfolio at any time t [0, T ]. The wealth of a self-financing trading strategy Φ satisfies the forward differential dv t (Φ) = Φ t ds t. (1) Remark (1) corresponds to the budget constraint V t+ t = Φ t S t+ t + (V t Φ t S t ). 8 / 34

Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging Replication or Hedging Replication principle is used to hedge and price options. Definition (Replication principle) Let G be an option. Suppose that there is a trading strategy Φ with wealth V t (Φ) at time t such that G = V T (Φ) at time T. Then the price of the option G at time t is V t (Φ). The replication requirement G = V T (Φ) can be written as T G = V t (Φ) + Φ s ds s, t where the integral is a forward integral (to be defined properly in the next section). 9 / 34

Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging Arbitrage No-arbitrage principle can be used to price options. Definition (Arbitrage) Arbitrage is a self-financing trading strategy Φ such that V 0 (Φ) = 0, P[V T (Φ) 0] = 1, and P[V T (Φ) > 0] > 0. Definition (No-Arbitrage Principle) No-Arbitrage Price of an option is any price that does not induce arbitrage into the market when the option is considered as a new asset. 10 / 34

Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging Arbitrage Remark If an option has a replication price then its no-arbitrage price must be the same. Otherwise one could make arbitrage by buying or selling the option with the no-arbitrage price and then replicating the option (or the minus option ). The price difference would be arbitrage. It is possible in theory that an option has a replication price but no no-arbitrage prices. It this case the market already has arbitrage. It is also possible to have no-arbitrage prices, but no replication prices. In this case there are many no-arbitrage prices. 11 / 34

Outline 1 Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging 2 Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation 3 Classical Black Scholes Model 4 Replication with Non-Semimartingales 5 No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales 12 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Forward Integral Definition (Forward Integral) Let (Π n ) be a sequence of partitions of [0, T ] such that mesh(π n ) = sup t k t k 1 0, n. t k Π n Forward integral of f w.r.t. g on [0, T ] is T 0 f (t) dg(t) = lim n t k Π n f (t k 1 ) (g(t k ) g(t k 1 )). Forward integral of f w.r.t. g on [a, b] [0, T ] is b a f (t) dg(t) = T 0 f (t)1 [a,b] (t) dg(t). 13 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Existence of Forward Integrals Remark The existence (and maybe even the value) of forward integral depends on the particular choice of the sequence of partitions. In what follows the sequence of partitions is assumed to be refining. The forward integral is a pathwise (almost sure) Ito integral if the sequence of partitions is chosen properly and the integrator is a semimartingale. In general case there is nothing the will a priori ensure the existence of the forward integral. We will see soon that if the integrator has quadratic variation then certain kind of forward integrals will exist. 14 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Quadratic Variation Definition (Quadratic Variation) Let (Π n ) be a sequence of (refining) partitions of [0, T ] such that mesh(π n ) 0. Quadratic variation of f on [0, t] is f (t) = lim n t k Π n,t k t (f (t k ) f (t k 1 )) 2. Remark Quadratic covariation can be defined in the same way or by using the polarization formula f, g = 1 4 ( f + g f g ). 15 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Rules for Quadratic Variation Lemma Let f and g be continuous quadratic variation functions. 1 For standard Brownian motion W t = t a.s., if the sequence of partitions is refining. 2 If f is smooth then f = 0. 3 If g = 0 then f + g = f. 4 If f is smooth then f g (t) = t 0 f ( g(s) ) 2 d g (s). 5 If g = 0 then f, g = 0. 16 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Rules for Quadratic Variation Proof. Item 1 This is a well-know fact from stochastic analysis (and too tedious to prove here). Item 2 follows from the mean value theorem: (f (tk ) f (t k 1 )) 2 =: ( f (tk )) 2 = ( f (ξ k ) ) 2 (tk t k 1 ) 2 4 f 2 mesh(π n )t. 17 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Rules for Quadratic Variation Proof. Item 3 follows from Cauchy Schwarz inequality: ( (f + g)) 2 = ( f + g) 2 = ( f ) 2 + ( g) 2 + 2 f g ( f ) 2 + ( g) 2 + 2 ( f ) 2 ( g) 2. Item 4 follows from the mean value theorem: ( f (g(t k ))) 2 = f (g(ξ k )) 2 ( g(t k )) 2. Item 5 follows directly from the Cauchy Schwarz inequality. 18 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Ito Formula for Quadratic Variation Theorem (Ito s Formula) Let X = (X 1,..., X n ) be a.s. continuous quadratic covariation process, and let f : R n R be smooth. Then, a.s., df (X t ) = n i=1 f x i (X t )dx t + 1 2 n i,j=1 2 f x i x j (X t) d X i, X j t. Proof. Taylor is all you need! 19 / 34

Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation Ito Formula for Quadratic Variation Remark The Ito formula implies that the forward integral exists and has a continuous modification. The Ito formula for quadratic variation processes is formally the same as the Ito formula for the continuous semimartingales. The differences between the forward world and the semimartingale worlds are: The existence of the quadratic variation (limit in probability) is guaranteed for semimartingales. In the forward world the integrals are always defined a.s. 20 / 34

Outline 1 Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging 2 Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation 3 Classical Black Scholes Model 4 Replication with Non-Semimartingales 5 No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales 21 / 34

Classical Black Scholes Model The Model Let W be the standard Brownian motion. Definition (Black Scholes Model) In the Classical Black Scholes model the stock price process is a geometric Brownian motion or as an Ito differential S t = S 0 e µt σ2 /2t+σW t, ds t = S t (µ dt + σ dw t ). 22 / 34

Classical Black Scholes Model Completeness Definition (Completeness) A market model is complete if all options can be replicated with a self-financing trading strategy. Theorem The Black Scholes market model is complete (at least for L 2 -options). Proof. This follows from the martingale representation theorem. 23 / 34

Classical Black Scholes Model No-Arbitrage Theorem The Black Scholes market model is free of arbitrage (for tame strategies). Proof. This follows from the fact that Ito integrals are (proper) martingales for tame integrators. Remark There is arbitrage in the Black Scholes model with e.g. doubling strategies. (The proponents of semimartingale approach do not like to talk too much about it.) 24 / 34

Outline 1 Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging 2 Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation 3 Classical Black Scholes Model 4 Replication with Non-Semimartingales 5 No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales 25 / 34

Replication with Non-Semimartingales Black Scholes BPDE Let G = g(s T ) be a path-independent option. (We can consider more complicated options. We talk about them later in the final section.) Assume that d S t = σ 2 S 2 t dt (2) Remark The classical Black Scholes model satisfies (2). Let ds t = S t (µdt + σw t + νz t ), where Z is a fractional Brownian motion with H > 1/2. This model also satisfies (2), but now S is no longer a semimartingale. 26 / 34

Replication with Non-Semimartingales Black Scholes BPDE By Ito formula, if v(t, x) is the solution to Black-Scholes BPDE v σ2 (t, x) t 2 x 2 2 v (t, x) = 0 x 2 with boundary condition v(t, x) = g(x), then V t (Φ) = v(t, S t ) and Φ t = v x (t, S t). 27 / 34

Replication with Non-Semimartingales The Feynman Kac Connection Remark Note that the prices and replications of (path-independent) options were derived from the quadratic variation property. Probability does not come into it! Remark It is true, by the Feynman Kac formula, that [ ( )] v(t, x) = E g xe σw T t σ2 2 (T t), where W is the standard Brownian motion. This does not imply that S is geometric Brownian motion of even log-normal! 28 / 34

Outline 1 Options, Their Pricing, and Hedging 2 Forward Integrals with Quadratic Variation 3 Classical Black Scholes Model 4 Replication with Non-Semimartingales 5 No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales 29 / 34

No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales The big picture No-arbitrage and completeness are opposite requirements: the more you want to hedge the more sophisticated trading strategies you must allow. The more sophisticated trading strategies you allow the more candidates for arbitrage you have. In classical semimartingale theory completeness and arbitrage is attained in the class of either integrable enough or bounded from below strategies. In the quadratic variation world we would then like to identify a class of strategies that is 1 Big enough to contain hedges for relevant options. 2 Small enough to exclude arbitrage opportunities. 3 Economically meaningful. 30 / 34

No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales The Status Quo At this moment we propose the following class of smooth strategies: Φ t = ϕ(t, S t, g 1 (t, S),... g n (t, S)), where ϕ is smooth and g i s are hindsight factors: 1 g i (, S) is S-adapted. 2 g i (, S) is continuous bounded variation process. 3 t 0 f (u)dg i (u, S) t 0 f (u)dg i (u, S) K f S S. 31 / 34

No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales The Status Quo Definition (Stopping-Smooth) Trading strategy is stopping-smooth if it is of the form Φ t = n Φ k t 1 (τk,τ k+1 ](t), k=1 where Φ k s are smooth and the stopping times τ k are locally continuous. A function f is locally continuous at point x if there exist an open set U such that x Ū and f (x n) f (x) whenever x n U. 32 / 34

No-Arbitrage with Non-Semimartingales The Status Quo Theorem There are no arbitrage opportunities in the class of stopping-smooth strategies if S has conditional full support: [ ] P S t η ε > 0 sup s [t,t ] for all positive paths η s.t. η(t) = S t. F S t 33 / 34

References 1 Bender, C., Sottinen, T. and Valkeila, E. (2008) Pricing by hedging and no-arbitrage beyond semimartingales. Finance and Stochastics 12, 441 468 2 Föllmer, H. (1980) Calcul d Itô sans probabilités. Seminar on Probability XV. 3 Sondermann, D. (2006) Introduction to stochastic calculus for finance. A new didactic approach. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems 579. Springer-Verlag, Berlin. 34 / 34