The Analytics of Information and Uncertainty Answers to Exercises and Excursions

Similar documents
Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

Bivariate Birnbaum-Saunders Distribution

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Information Aggregation in Dynamic Markets with Strategic Traders. Michael Ostrovsky

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

1 Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MORE REALISTIC FOR STOCKS, FOR EXAMPLE

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Persuasion in Global Games with Application to Stress Testing. Supplement

Quantitative Risk Management

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Carnegie Mellon University Graduate School of Industrial Administration

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

EXTRA PROBLEMS. and. a b c d

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

B. Online Appendix. where ɛ may be arbitrarily chosen to satisfy 0 < ɛ < s 1 and s 1 is defined in (B1). This can be rewritten as

1 No-arbitrage pricing

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Technical Appendix to Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy

Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Games when Players Belief Are Not in Equilibrium

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Black-Litterman Model

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Midterm 1, Financial Economics February 15, 2010

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Lecture 3: Return vs Risk: Mean-Variance Analysis

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Choice under Uncertainty

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory

In Diamond-Dybvig, we see run equilibria in the optimal simple contract.

Yao s Minimax Principle

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Online Shopping Intermediaries: The Strategic Design of Search Environments

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Risk Aversion and Wealth: Evidence from Person-to-Person Lending Portfolios On Line Appendix

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

1 Dynamic programming

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Mean-Variance Analysis

MATH362 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance. Topic 1 Mean variance portfolio theory. 1.1 Mean and variance of portfolio return

Characterization of the Optimum

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Attitudes Toward Risk. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/16. (Lecture 11, Micro Theory I)

Pakes (1986): Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

6. Martingales. = Zn. Think of Z n+1 as being a gambler s earnings after n+1 games. If the game if fair, then E [ Z n+1 Z n

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10.

Supplementary Material for Combinatorial Partial Monitoring Game with Linear Feedback and Its Application. A. Full proof for Theorems 4.1 and 4.

Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty

Slides III - Complete Markets

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Transcription:

The Analytics of Information and Uncertainty Answers to Exercises and Excursions Chapter 6: Information and Markets 6.1 The inter-related equilibria of prior and posterior markets Solution 6.1.1. The condition for equilibrium for an non-informative situation is j sm v(c)/ c smg j s m v(c)/ c s m g = P smg P s m g. For informative equilibrium, we first write down the agent s utility maximization problem for the sake of completeness. Let P I smg denote the posterior price after receiving message m, and P 0 smg denote the prior price. The agent solves s.t. max q m π s m v(c smg ) c smg, c smg m Psmgc I smg = Psmg c I smg, sg sg Psmg c 0 smg = W. smg The agent optimizes in two steps. First, he trades the contingent bundle c, and later, after he receives message m, he trades c smg over all s, g, with the budget being the contingent wealth of c given m. Let λ m and µ be the Lagrange multipliers of the first and second constraints, respectively. first-order condition is given by s m The q m π s m v (c smg ) = λ m P I smg λ m P I smg = µp 0 smg. Hence, given s, m, we have and given s, g, we have v (c smg ) v (c smg ) = P I smg P I smg j sm v (c smg ) j sm v (c sm g) = λ m λ m = P 0 smg P 0 smg, P I smg P I sm g = P smg 0 Psm 0. g Since the allocation (c smg ) is already optimal under the prices (P 0 smg) before and after one receives the message m, no posterior trade is needed. Proposition 1 still holds. 1

Solution 6.1.. If the information is revealed prematurely, there will be no chance to trade and individuals of one type are very adversely affected. In particular, each agent s expected utility is as EU i = 0.6 ln 400 + 0.4 ln 0 =. Similar for agent j. Hence their willingness to pay for the information not to be revealed is infinite. Solution 6.1.. First we calculate the CCM equilibrium. Note that for v(n, f) = ln n + ln f, the demand is given by c g = π s (W/)/P gs, where g {n, f}. Since both agents have the same endowment, their wealth is the same. The market clearing condition is Using the normalization + P n = 1, we get 0.5 W/ + 0.6 W/ = 00 0.5 W/ P n + 0.4 W/ P n = 00 0.5 W/ + 0.6 W/ = 400 0.5 W/ P n + 0.4 W/ P n = 160 (, P n, P f1, P f ) = ( 11 0, 9 0, 11 40, 9 16 ). Under such prices the wealth of each agent is W = 00. To attain the CCM allocation using an NCM regime, note that in CCM the contingent wealth implied by the optimal allocation is W s = π s W. We now show that under NCM with the same prior and posterior price, the agents can achieve the same contingent wealth. Let c i ns be agent i s prior round trade of good n. For agent 1, he has W s = 100 for all s. So we need and Thus we obtain A similar argument for agent implies 00 11 40 + c1 n1 11 0 = 100 80 9 16 + c1 n 9 0 = 100. c 1 n1 = 900 11, c1 n = 1100 9. c n = 100 11, c n = 700 9. Note that the prior round market clears under the given prices and allocations. Hence with the above prior round trade, the agents will be able to attain the CCM equilibrium allocation.

6. Speculation and future trading Solution 6..1. (A) Since under P = (0.6, 0.4, 0., 0.5) each agent s wealth is still 00, the optimal allocation under the CCM regime will remain the same. (B) It suffices to show that after the prior round trade the agent s contingent wealth is (W 1, W ) = (10, 80). Agent 1 s contingent allocation is now If s = 1, then his wealth is C = ( 800 Similarly, if s =, his wealth is 800, 150 + 800 1000 1000, 00, 160 ). 1000 0.6 + (00 ) 0. = 10. 150 0.4 50 0.5 = 80. (C) His state contingent wealth is exactly the same as that induced by the CCM allocation in the posterior round, hence with the same price vector he can obtain the optimal allocation. (D) He can use his wealth in the posterior round to buy goods to settle futures contracts. Solution 6... The martingale property in general does not hold. We will formally set up the agent s utility maximization problem and derive the equilibrium condition for prices. Let g n, g f denote the future trades of n, f in the prior round. The consumer s maximization problem is given by subject to max π s v(c ns, c fs ) c ns,c fs,g n,g f s Png 0 n + Pf 0 g f = 0 (1) s : Pnsc I ns + Pfsc I fs = Pns(c I ns + g n ) + Pfs(c I fs + g f ) () Let µ be the multiplier of (1) and λ s be the multipliers of () for each s. The first-order condition is

given by v(c ns, c fs ) c ns : π s c ns v(c ns, c fs ) c fs : π s c fs = λ s P I ns = λ s P I fs g n : µp 0 n + s λ s P I ns = 0 g f : µp 0 f + s λ s P I fs = 0 Hence, P 0 f P 0 n = s λ spfs I s λ spns I = E[ v/ c fs] E[ v/ c ns ], which shows that the prior-round price ratio of the goods equals the ratio of expected marginal utilities of the goods. If the numerator and denominator of the given equation is changed, one can check that the martingale property will also not hold. In general, let E[X/Y ] = a/b and f(z) = 1/z. Jensen s inequality implies E[Y/X] = E[f(X/Y )] f(e[x/y ]) = b/a. 6. The production and dissemination of information 6..1 Private information and the leakage problem Solution 6..1.1. (A) Because of log utility, the demand is (B) Note that the market clearing is given by c ω 1 = πω W = πω ( c ω 1 + P c ω ). () C I 1 + C U 1 = C I 1 + CU 1. Plugging in () to obtain Rearrange to obtain π I (C I 1 + P C I ) + πu (C U 1 + P C U ) = CI 1 + CU 1. P = (1 πu )C1 U + (1 πi )C1 I π U C U +. (4) πi C I 4

(C) Given P /, one can obtain π I from (4). (D) In this case, the price ratio becomes P = (1 πu )C U 1 + (1 πi )(C I 1 δ 1) π U C U + πi (C I δ ) But then the uninformed cannot infer π I from P /, unless δ 1, δ are known.. Solution 6..1.. (A) We have P A 1 = + P P A = z 1 + z P. Hence where P / is given by (4). P1 A P A = z 1 + z P = z P 1 + z + P 1 + P, (B) By observing P A 1 /P A, one can first infer P / from the above equation, and then obtain π I from (4). Solution 6..1.. (A) Similar to Ex 6..1.1(A), the price ratio is given by (B) Let P = (1 πu )C U 1 + (1 πa )C A 1 + (1 πb )C B 1 π U C U + πa C A + πb C B f(π A, π B ) = (1 πu )C1 U + (1 πa )C1 A + (1 πb )C1 B π U C U + πa C A +. πb C B The question amounts to whether, generically, f is a one-to-one function given that its domain (the set of possible (π A, π B )) is finite. It should be clear that if one randomly picks finitely many points in S = [0, 1] [0, 1], then, with probability one, f will be one-to-one. The above claim holds for arbitrary C I, C A, C B. For example, consider the case C A = C B = C I, then the value of f (the price ratio) is determined solely by π A + π B. So we can partition S into k [0,1] S k where S k = {(π A, π B ) S π A + π B = k}. Obviously, the probability of picking two points in the same S k is zero, since the index k is a continuum.. 5

(C) If one randomly picks a continuum of points, for example circle an area in S, one will with positive probability circle points (π A, π B ) that produce the same price ratio. 6.. Partial leakage with constant absolute risk aversion Solution 6...1. (A) Let Σ nn = [cov(r + ɛ i, R + ɛ j )], Σ 1n = (cov(r, R + ɛ 1 ),..., cov(r, R + ɛ n )) = (σ,..., σ ) and m µ a vector of length n with entries m i µ. A standard result for multivariate normal random variables implies that E[R m 1,..., m n ] = µ + Σ 1n Σ 1 nn(m µ). Observe that Σ nn is a matrix with diagonal entries σ +σ ɛ and off-diagonal entries σ. By symmetry, the inverse of Σ nn will also be of this form. This implies that Σ 1n Σ 1 nn will be a vector with all entries the same, say, β. Then E[R m 1,..., m n ] = µ + β( i m i nµ) = (1 βn)µ + βn m 1 +... + m n. n (B) Suppose there are n insiders and m outsiders. Then it follows from (6..5) that where n Plugging into (5) and rearranging ( n(σ + σɛ ) P σ σɛ Hence P is a function of i m i. E[R m i ] P m A i Var(R m i ) + σ ɛ E[R m i ] = σ + σɛ σ σ ɛ Var[R m i ] = σ + σɛ. + m ) A i σ = n 1 A i σ A i σɛ µ P A i σ = Q, (5) µ + σ σ + σɛ m i If every insider receives (m 1,..., m n ), then equation (6..5) becomes n E[R m 1,..., m n ] P m A i Var(R m 1,..., m n ) + By (A), the equilibrium price P is still linear in m i, n m i + mµ A i σ Q. µ P A i σ = Q. 6

(C) Suppose k out of n insiders purchase information. Then if one additional insider buys information he loses c units of riskless asset, but he can purchase the risky asset with E[R m 1,..., m k+1 ], Var[R m 1,..., m k+1 ] under the equilibrium price P (m 1,..., m k+1 ). If the expected equilibrium price of the risky asset rises, then there will be a trade-off. Hence one may guess that there is an optimal k. (D) Insiders now have different incentives to purchase information. If differences in risk aversion are small, then the answer will not differ much from that in (C). 7