Pension Wealth and Household Saving in Europe: Evidence from SHARELIFE

Similar documents
Pension Wealth and Household Savings in Europe: Evidence from SHARELIFE

What do we learn about redistribution effects of pension systems from internationally comparable measures of Social Security Wealth?

Uncertain Pension Income and Household Saving

Eelco Zandberg Retirement Replacement Rates and Saving Behavior

Online Appendix to Grouped Coefficients to Reduce Bias in Heterogeneous Dynamic Panel Models with Small T

Wealth at the End of Life: Evidence on Estate Planning and Bequests

The Displacement Effect of Compulsory Pension Savings on Private Savings

Effects of working part-time and full-time on physical and mental health in old age in Europe

HOUSEHOLD DEBT AND CREDIT CONSTRAINTS: COMPARATIVE MICRO EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

LIFE-COURSE HEALTH AND LABOUR MARKET EXIT IN THIRTEEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES: RESULTS FROM SHARELIFE

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Retirement expectations, pension reforms, and their impact on private wealth accumulation

REPRODUCTIVE HISTORY AND RETIREMENT: GENDER DIFFERENCES AND VARIATIONS ACROSS WELFARE STATES

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. Bounds on the Return to Education in Australia using Ability Bias

Saving During Retirement

The Effect of Public Pension Wealth on Saving and Expenditure

Wealth Inequality in the Netherlands: Observed vs Capitalized Wealth

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Corporate Socialism Around the World

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population

Lifetime Income Inequality: quantile treatment effect of retirement on the distribution of lifetime income.

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Adaptation, Anticipation and Social Interactions in Happiness: An Integrated Error-Correction Approach. Maarten Vendrik Maastricht University IZA

Financial Advisors: A Case of Babysitters?

Financial Literacy and the Demand for Financial Advice

Labour Supply and Taxes

Poverty and transitions in key areas of quality of life. Michał Myck (CenEA) joint work with Maja Adena (WZB & CenEA)

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Wealth and the Effect of Subjective Survival Probability

Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement?

Time-varying wage Phillips curves in the euro area with a new measure for labor market slack

The model is estimated including a fixed effect for each family (u i ). The estimated model was:

The Effect of Public Pension Wealth on Saving and Expenditure: Evidence from Poland s 1999 Pension Reform 1

Retirement and Cognitive Decline: Evidence from Global Aging Data

Optimal portfolio choice with health-contingent income products: The value of life care annuities

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany

Does Broadband Internet Affect Fertility?

Does Homeownership Promote Wealth Accumulation? *

Empirical Appendix to The Impact of Regulatory Changes on Mortgage Risk: Evidence from India

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

Online Appendix. Long-term Changes in Married Couples Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from the US and Europe Since the 1980s

Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany

Online Appendix A: Derivations and Extensions of the Theoretical Model

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

Individual Income and Remaining Life Expectancy at the Statutory Retirement Age of 65 in the Netherlands

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

TAX EXPENDITURES Fall 2012

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

Does Raising Contribution Limits Lead to More Saving? Evidence from the Catch-up Limit Reform

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

An estimated model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints

Subjective Expectations and Income Processes in Rural India

Economics Bulletin, 2014, Vol. 34 No. 1 pp Introduction

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

The Effects of EU Formula Apportionment on Corporate Tax Revenues

Policy Brief Estimating Differential Mortality from EU- SILC Longitudinal Data a Feasibility Study

Who earns minimum wages in Europe? New evidence based on household surveys

Exploring differences in financial literacy across countries: the role of individual characteristics, experience, and institutions

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

The Retirement-Consumption Puzzle and the German Pension System - A Regression Discontinuity Approach

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

The Implications of a Greying Japan for Public Policy.

Problem Set # Due Monday, April 19, 3004 by 6:00pm

THE RESPONSE OF HOUSEHOLD SAVING TO THE LARGE SHOCK OF GERMAN REUNIFICATION. Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln

Online Appendix. Long-term Changes in Married Couples Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from the US and Europe Since the 1980s

How do Households Respond to Income Shocks?

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

To Leave or Not to Leave: The Distribution of Bequest Motives

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Session III Differences in Differences (Dif- and Panel Data

Credit Discrimination in European Households

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

EFFICIENCY OF PUBLIC SPENDING IN SUPPORT OF R&D ACTIVITIES

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

For Online Publication Additional results

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix

Retirement Saving, Annuity Markets, and Lifecycle Modeling. James Poterba 10 July 2008

CHAPTER 4 DATA ANALYSIS Data Hypothesis

Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data

Investment in Financial Literacy, Social Security and Portfolio Choice

The Social Costs of Unemployment: Accounting for Unemployment Duration

Private Wealth and Planned Early Retirement: A Panel Data Analysis for the Netherlands,

Home Production and Social Security Reform

SHARE and SHARELIFE The collection of longitudinal data on older adults in Europe

Macroeconomic Experiences and Risk-Taking of Euro Area Households

Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss

Examining the Changes in Health Investment Behavior After Retirement

MULTIVARIATE FRACTIONAL RESPONSE MODELS IN A PANEL SETTING WITH AN APPLICATION TO PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION. Michael Anthony Carlton A DISSERTATION

Financial Literacy and Savings Account Returns *

How do households respond to income shocks?

Transcription:

Pension Wealth and Household Saving in Europe: Evidence from SHARELIFE Rob Alessie, Viola Angelini and Peter van Santen University of Groningen and Netspar PHF Conference 2012 12 July 2012

Motivation The life cycle/permanent income hypothesis suggests people save for retirement Social security and occupational pensions should therefore affect household wealth accumulation We try to estimate the Displacement effect : How much do households save more (or less) when pension wealth is reduced? Crucial parameter to evaluate the effects of pension reforms in Europe, for households and economy-wide SHARE and SHARELIFE in particular provide the necessary information to estimate the displacement effect

Literature and our contribution Feldstein (1974, JPE): US aggregate time-series data Gale (1998, JPE): US cross-sectional data Attanasio and Rohwedder (2003, AER) and Attanasio and Brugiavini (2003, QJE): time series of cross sectional data for the UK and Italy Kapteyn, Alessie, Lusardi (2005, EER): Dutch panel data Engelhardt and Kumar (2011, JHR): US administrative data with information on past labour earnings Estimates of displacement effect vary not only in magnitude, but also in sign! Contributions 1 New estimates for Europe, using retrospective survey data 2 Wrong sign likely to occur if measurement error not taken seriously

Literature and our contribution Feldstein (1974, JPE): US aggregate time-series data Gale (1998, JPE): US cross-sectional data Attanasio and Rohwedder (2003, AER) and Attanasio and Brugiavini (2003, QJE): time series of cross sectional data for the UK and Italy Kapteyn, Alessie, Lusardi (2005, EER): Dutch panel data Engelhardt and Kumar (2011, JHR): US administrative data with information on past labour earnings Estimates of displacement effect vary not only in magnitude, but also in sign! Contributions 1 New estimates for Europe, using retrospective survey data 2 Wrong sign likely to occur if measurement error not taken seriously

Literature and our contribution Feldstein (1974, JPE): US aggregate time-series data Gale (1998, JPE): US cross-sectional data Attanasio and Rohwedder (2003, AER) and Attanasio and Brugiavini (2003, QJE): time series of cross sectional data for the UK and Italy Kapteyn, Alessie, Lusardi (2005, EER): Dutch panel data Engelhardt and Kumar (2011, JHR): US administrative data with information on past labour earnings Estimates of displacement effect vary not only in magnitude, but also in sign! Contributions 1 New estimates for Europe, using retrospective survey data 2 Wrong sign likely to occur if measurement error not taken seriously

A stylized model max c τ s.t. = L (1 + ρ) τ=1 1 τ c1 γ τ 1 γ L (1 + r) 1 τ c τ = τ=1 R (1 + r) 1 τ E τ + τ=1 (1a) L (1 + r) 1 τ y τ (1b) τ=1 L τ=r+1 (1 + r) 1 τ B τ (1c) c τ denotes consumption at age τ, y τ income, E τ pre retirement earnings (labour income), B τ pension benefits, R exogenous retirement date, L maximum length of life, ρ the discount rate, γ coefficient of relative risk aversion, r constant real interest rate.

Optimal consumption ( ( ) ) 1 + r 1/γ τ 1 c τ = c 1 τ = 2,..., L (2a) 1 + ρ ( L ) c 1 = (1 + r) 1 τ y τ (2b) λ = τ=1 λ τ 1) 1 ( L τ=1 ((1 + r)/(1 + ρ))1/γ 1 + r Standard result: consumption path is flat when r = ρ (2c)

Optimal wealth By definition, wealth at age t equals A t = Plug in optimal consumption to obtain ( t A t = (1 + r) t τ E τ Q(λ, t) τ=1 t τ=1 (1 + r) t τ (y τ c τ ). ) R (1 + r) t τ E τ τ=1 } {{ } z1t L Q(λ, t) (1 + r) t τ B τ τ=r+1 } {{ } z2t where the so-called Gale (1998) s Q is defined as ( L ) Q(λ, t) = λ τ 1 τ=1 λ τ 1) 1 ( t τ=1 (3) (4)

Equation to be estimated A t = β 0 + β 1 z 1t + β 2 z 2t + x tγ + ε t (5) The life cycle model predicts full displacement (β 2 = 1) and β 1 = 1 SHARE(LIFE) contains sufficient retrospective and prospective information to proxy z1t (present value of lifetime earnings) and z2t (pension wealth) However, severe measurement error problems bias the results, leading to spurious rejection of the life cycle model

Measurement error I We observe z 1 = z 1 + η 1 and z 2 = z 2 + η 2 A = β 0 + β 1 z 1 + β 2 z 2 + x γ + ε β 1 η 1 β 2 η 2 (6) Most likely, Cov(η 1, η 2 ) = σ η1 η 2 0, not a classical measurement error problem! We show in the paper that, under the validity of the life cycle model, the OLS estimator ˆβ 1 OLS may easily become negative, and ˆβ 2 OLS may become positive Main reason: correlated measurement errors amplify impact of measurement error in any single regressor

Measurement error II To limit the impact of measurement error, we impose the restriction β 1 = 1 and estimate A z 1 = β 0 + β 2 z 2 + x γ + ε η 1 β 2 η 2 (7) The bias in the OLS estimator now equals (+) ( ) ( ) plim ˆβ OLS 2 β 2 = (σ η1 η 2 + β 2 σ 2 η 2 ) c Presumably, we still face attenuation bias towards zero. We perform the cleanest test of the life cycle model using a subsample of retirees for which σ η1 η 2 0. A significantly negative estimate of β 2 for this group strongly suggests (at least partial) displacement

SHARELIFE Retrospective survey conducted in 13 European countries on 50+ individuals as part of the SHARE project: review social, economic and health events occurred during life Interviewers use life history calendar to guide respondents to answer questions as accurately as possible E.g. first questions: date of birth of children We use information on job history: start date of each job in career, first wage earned on the job, end date, main job in career, last wage main job, current wage if employed Combined with waves 1 and 2 ( standard socio-economic survey) we obtain a potentially very rich dataset

Sample selection Our sample: 3,590 males participating in SHARELIFE Those with no wage or just one wage reported are dropped Those who have worked for less than 20 years are dropped Age restriction: 55-75 years old in wave 2 Household non pension wealth (A t ): Net worth, net financial wealth All 5 imputations are used, estimates and standard errors corrected

Data I Compounded labour income: t (1 + r) t τ E τ τ=1 From SHARELIFE, we construct a panel with one observation per year per individual, from birth to 2009 First monthly wage on each job Last monthly wage on main job / current wage Wage from wave 2 (if still employed) All amounts PPP-adjusted German Euros of 2006 Interpolation between all wages to obtain complete wage path Period 1: first year in first job Retirement: first year receiving pension benefits (if retired) Labour income compounded using r = 3%

Data II Future labour income (from now to retirement): R (1 + r) t τ E τ τ=t+1 Only needed for those still working in wave 2 Retirement (R): expected retirement age from wave 2 or statutory retirement age by country if missing Simplifying assumption: future real wage path is flat All future amounts weighted by survival probabilities from country-specific HMD life tables

Data III Pension wealth: z 2t = L τ=r+1 For retired: pension benefits (1 + r) t τ B τ For employed: use expected replacement rate from wave 2, multiplied by current income Simplifying assumption: constant real pension benefits Future amounts weighted by survival probabilities Maximum age (L): 110

Some descriptives Figure : Wages and pensions in Europe 0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 Median income by country AT DE SE NL ES IT FR DK GR CH BE CZ PL Annual pension income Annual labour income

Main results Table : Estimates of the displacement effect (1) (2) Variables Robust regression Median regression Pension wealth -0.471*** -0.609*** (0.0878) (0.151) Age 55-60 -1.406*** -1.409*** (0.155) (0.173) Age 70-75 1.797*** 1.614*** (0.172) (0.177) Gaps in career -0.824*** -0.756*** (0.146) (0.164) Constant -4.786*** -4.385*** (0.329) (0.374) Observations 3590 3590 p-value β 2 = 1 0.000 0.011 p-value Country effects 0.000 0.000 Standard errors in parentheses; *** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1 Bootstrapped standard errors for median regression, 1000 replications. Additional controls: Second earner, Married, No children, Education, Bad Health, Country dummies

Robustness checks Table : Robustness checks displacement effect (1) (2) (3) (4) Variables Retired Old Low High sample sample educated educated Robust regression -0.205** -0.173* -0.215* -0.833*** (0.0936) (0.0965) (0.122) (0.153) p-value β 2 = 1 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.277 Median regression -0.296-0.306* -0.275-1.099*** (0.180) (0.177) (0.192) (0.286) p-value β 2 = 1 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.729 Observations 2487 2415 3590 3590 Standard errors in parentheses; *** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1 Bootstrapped standard errors for median regression, 1000 replications.

Results by country group Figure : Displacement effect across country groups Estimated displacement effect by country group Estimate, 90% CI 1.5 1.5 0.5 North Mid West South East Displacement effect Pooled displacement effect Lower bound/upper bound

Results by country group II Highest displacement in North, limited displacement in South and East Generous welfare systems less precautionary savings More access to capital markets relax liquidity constraints Jappelli (2010, Economic Journal): significant positive relationship between GDP/capita and economic literacy; highest literacy scores in Denmark, Switzerland and the Netherlands, lowest scores in Poland, Italy and Spain Table : Financial literacy: household surveys NL SE DE IT Russia 46.2% 26.7% 56.8% 28.3% 3.4%

An IV approach Pension wealth may be endogenous due to unobserved heterogeneity (taste for saving, patience) or endogenous retirement We compute median pension income by country and employment status (employee, civil servant, self employed) Transformed to pension wealth, using country- and time-specific statutory retirement age; no individual characteristics used in computation of the instrument Assumption: conditional on demographic characteristics, education, wealth and the country of residence, workers do not sort across employment sectors based on the taste for saving Chernozhukov-Hansen s median regression IV estimator

Variation in the instrument Figure : Instrument 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 Median pension income by country and work status AT DE SE NL ES IT FR DK GR CH BE CZ PL Employees Self employed Civil servants

IV results Table : IV Median regression estimates (1) (2) (3) Variable Full Retired Old sample sample sample Pension Wealth -1.232-0.622-0.955 (0.876) (0.863) (0.813) p-value β 2 = 1 0.804 0.684 0.960 F -statistic first stage 41.895 31.232 38.567 Observations 3590 2487 2414 Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses; 1000 replications

Concluding remarks We provide new estimates for the displacement effect using retrospective life history data for Europe We show that addressing measurement error problems is crucial to estimate the displacement effect when using survey data We find substantial displacement: each euro of pension wealth is associated with a 47 (61) cent decline in non pension wealth using robust (median) regression, with a lower bound of 17(30)%. Full displacement using IV median regression but not precisely estimated However, we cannot reject zero displacement for the low educated and for Southern and Eastern European countries Research agenda: eliminate remaining biases, due to both measurement error and endogeneity of retirement decision