Wealth Returns Dynamics and Heterogeneity

Similar documents
Wealth Returns Persistence and Heterogeneity

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Internet Appendix for Heterogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth

Heterogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Poverty and Income Distribution

vio SZY em Growing Unequal? INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN OECD COUNTRIES

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

The Distribution of US Wealth, Capital Income and Returns since Emmanuel Saez (UC Berkeley) Gabriel Zucman (LSE and UC Berkeley)

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth Inequality in the Netherlands: Observed vs Capitalized Wealth

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FIRM-RELATED RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY SAVING RESPONSE. Andreas Fagereng Luigi Guiso Luigi Pistaferri

Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of. Wealth Inequality

Measuring Income and Wealth at the Top Using Administrative and Survey Data

Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of Wealth Inequality

Real Median Family Income is Falling. Family incomes have stagnated since the mid-1980s. Income in 2012 ($51,017) is lower than in 1989 ($51,681).

Capitalists in the Twenty-First Century

Wealth distribution and social mobility: A quantitative analysis of U.S. data

USE IT OR LOSE IT: EFFICIENCY GAINS FROM WEALTH TAXATION

THE STATISTICS OF INCOME (SOI) DIVISION OF THE

Distribution of Wealth: Mechanisms

The intergenerational transmission of wealth

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data

Intergenerational Consequences of Wealth Inequality

Online Appendix to The Dynamics of Inequality Xavier Gabaix, Jean-Michel Lasry, Pierre-Louis Lions, Benjamin Moll August 4, 2016

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Andreas Fagereng. Charles Gottlieb. Luigi Guiso

Measuring Wealth Inequality in Europe: A Quest for the Missing Wealthy

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

A. Data Sample and Organization. Covered Workers

Appendix A. Additional Results

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth

The Demographics of Wealth

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

Age, Luck, and Inheritance

RECENT TRENDS IN THE SIZE AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF INHERITED WEALTH IN THE UK

Wealth - why do we care and what do we know?

THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

Bequests and Retirement Wealth in the United States

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WEALTH DISTRIBUTION AND SOCIAL MOBILITY IN THE US: A QUANTITATIVE APPROACH. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo

Private Reallocations. Andrew Mason

STATISTICS ON INCOME AND LIVING CONDITIONS (EU-SILC))

Lifetime Wealth Taxation of the Very Rich

Worker Betas: Five Facts about Systematic Earnings Risk

The Inequality Lab. Discussion Paper

Inequality in 3D: Income, Consumption, and Wealth

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Inequality: Why should we care?

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

Strictness of Tax Compliance Norms: A Factorial Survey on the Acceptance of Inheritance Tax Evasion in Germany

Working paper series. Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo.

TOP INCOMES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA OVER THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

Asymmetries in earnings, employment and wage risk in Great Britain

In or out? Poverty dynamics among older individuals in the UK

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit

Provincial Taxation of High Incomes: What are the Impacts on Equity and Tax Revenue?

USE IT OR LOSE IT: EFFICIENCY GAINS FROM WEALTH TAXATION

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

Slipping and Sliding: Wealth of U.S. Households Over the Financial Crisis

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

EIEF Working Paper 18/07 June Investment in Financial Information and Portfolio Performance

TAXABLE INCOME RESPONSES. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for MSc Public Economics (EC426): Lent Term 2014

Source: Oxfam Issue Briefing, Having It All and Wanting More, January 2015

Income Distribution Database (

Cambridge University Press Getting Rich: America s New Rich and how they Got that Way Lisa A. Keister Excerpt More information

Inequality Dynamics in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Asset-Related Measures of Poverty and Economic Stress

While real incomes in the lower and middle portions of the U.S. income distribution have

Income and Wealth Inequality in America,

Wealth Distribution. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. Econ821. February 9, / 25

Income Inequality in Korea,

Internet Appendix to Do the Rich Get Richer in the Stock Market? Evidence from India

TRICKLE-DOWN CONSUMPTION. Marianne Bertrand (Chicago Booth) Adair Morse (Berkeley)

Who Is a Top Earner and For How Long? Top Income Mobility in Switzerland

Many studies have documented the long term trend of. Income Mobility in the United States: New Evidence from Income Tax Data. Forum on Income Mobility

Wealth Analysis: Introduction to Household Portfolios

Wealth Distribution and Taxation. Frank Cowell: MSc Public Economics 2011/2

FINANCIAL LITERACY AND VULNERABILITY: LESSONS FROM ACTUAL INVESTMENT DECISIONS. Research Challenge Technical Report

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory. Costas Azariadis. Costas Azariadis. Lecture 3: Productivity and Labor

Working paper series. Simplified Distributional National Accounts. Thomas Piketty Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman. January 2019

Higher Taxes at the Top: The Role of Entrepreneurs

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

Graduate Public Finance

Do the Rich Get Richer in the Stock Market? Evidence from India

According to the life cycle theory, households take. Do wealth inequalities have an impact on consumption? 1

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

Income Inequality and Poverty (Chapter 20 in Mankiw & Taylor; reading Chapter 19 will also help)

Transcription:

Wealth Returns Dynamics and Heterogeneity Andreas Fagereng (Statistics Norway) Luigi Guiso (EIEF) Davide Malacrino (Stanford) Luigi Pistaferri (Stanford)

Wealth distribution In many countries, and over long time periods, the wealth distribution is extremely skewed and displays a long thick tail.1.15.2.25 US (Saez and Zucman, 2015) 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 year Norway Norway vs. US US, Saez-Zucman

Wealth distribution In many countries, and over long time periods, the wealth distribution is extremely skewed and displays a long thick tail.1.15.2.25 US (Saez and Zucman, 2015) 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 year Norway Norway vs. US US, Saez-Zucman

What explains the long thick tail? Idiosyncratic earnings risk/skewness and precautionary saving response Why do the rich save so much? narratives Non homothetic bequests Entrepreneurship Heterogeneity in discount rates These explanations, in isolation, have trouble fitting the data If they do, it is at the cost of some very strong or counterfactual assumptions

Stochastic wealth returns? Recent work by Benhabib, Bisin and various coauthors suggests that a possible way of reproducing the skewed long thick tail of the wealth distribution (and the extent of intergenerational correlation in wealth levels) is to allow for heterogeneous wealth returns (along with some of the features listed before) Important questions: How much heterogeneity in wealth returns? How much persistence? Are wealth returns correlated with wealth itself? Is there any intergenerational correlation in returns? Measurement and conceptual issues This paper: Measurement

Our data We use Norwegian population tax record data from 1993 to 2013 Norwegian residents pay a wealth tax, so tax records include: Information on income earned (from labor and capital) Capital income distinguished by broad source Detailed information on asset holdings Also distinguished by broad source For most sources, tax value market value For non listed stocks, etc., tax value market value Third party reports Scope for tax evasion limited

Advantages of data We have administrative longitudinal population data Measurement error limited No attrition (apart from death and migration) Even the very top tail is in data set Long panel data Family id allows us to match parents with children when the latter form independent households

Wealth returns: Measurement (1) Tax returns include income from capital earned in calendar year t: They also include the stock of wealth at the beginning of year t ( end of period t 1 ): If no accumulation/decumulation of wealth during the year, the return would simply be:

Wealth returns: Measurement (2) To correct for the fact that some of the capital income may come from assets sold or purchased over the year, we define returns on capital as: /2 We follow the same approach to measure returns on safe assets and on risky assets Moreover: We drop returns of households with < $350 equivalent wealth We censor at the top and bottom 1% of returns distribution This should, if anything, reduce the extent of returns heterogeneity For stocks, the error come from tax treatment of capital gains/losses Focus on the returns fixed effect, however, should reduce the concern

The distribution of wealth returns: 2013 Mean =0.03 Median =0.02 s.d. =0.04 P 10 =0 P 90 =0.05

Risky vs Safe assets (2013) Mean =0.05 Median =0 s.d. =0.15 P 10 =0 P 90 =0.16 Mean =0.02 Median =0 s.d. =0.02 P 10 =0 P 90 =0.04

The correlation between returns and wealth levels (2013) Median return.005.01.015.02.025.03 0 20 40 60 80 100 Percentile of the wealth distribution

Why a correlation between returns and wealth levels? Wealthy investors are more risk tolerant (applies to both stockholders and entrepreneurs) Wealthy investors have access to different (more lucrative) investment opportunities than retail investors For example, return on safe assets have a premium for those depositing above a threshold Some (more lucrative?) mutual funds have an entry requirement Wealthy investors can buy the services of financial experts

Time variation: Mean and median return 0.01.02.03.04.05 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Year Mean return Median return

Time variation: s.d. of returns.02.03.04.05.06 St.dev. returns 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Year

Time variation: Mean, median, s.d. of returns on risky & safe assets 0.05.1.15.2 Risky assets 0.05.1.15.2 Safe assets 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Year 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Year Median St.dev. Mean Median St.dev. Mean

Time variation: The correlation between returns and wealth levels Report median return for selected percentiles of the wealth distribution Returns are persistently higher when we move up in the wealth distribution Spearman rank correlation ranges between 0.162 and 0.384 0.02.04.06 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Year Median return, 10th pctl. Median return, 50th pctl. Median return, 90th pctl. Median return, 25th pctl. Median return, 75th pctl.

Modeling returns heterogeneity We consider a simple statistical regression model: We break unobservables determinants of returns into a permanent component (a fixed effect) and a transitory component: How much returns heterogeneity is explained by observables, fixed effects, and remaining unobservables?

The contribution of observable characteristics We control for: Demographics (age, gender, years of schooling, type of education, geographical indicators) Common shocks (time effects) Occupation (whether employed and whether owning some business wealth) Portfolio composition at the beginning of the period These observables explain 7% of the total variation in wealth returns

Regression results

Fixed effects Conceptually, why fixed effects in wealth returns? That is: What makes certain individuals reaping persistently higher/lower returns than the average? Preferences High risk tolerance leading certain individuals to invest in highrisk/high return financial instruments (and preferences for risk are very stable over time). Talent Better stock picking Better financial education Business income: It s a function of the entrepreneur s own ability, which may have a strong persistent component

Fixed effects: Evidence Fixed effects are jointly statistically significant They explain about 18% of total variation in returns Their distribution differs significantly across key sub groups Business owners vs non owners Low vs. high years of schooling Bottom vs. top 10% wealth distribution

Distribution of the fixed effects

Any serial correlation left? From, additional persistence in returns may in principle come from We plot for all The moments for are all economically undistinguishable from 0 Consistent with returns being basically unpredictable once controlling for demographics and fixed effects

Intergenerational correlations: Wealth, Returns, Fixed effects Our data can be used to study mobility (or intergenerational correlation) in wealth related variables We focus here on Wealth levels Overall returns on wealth Persistent component of wealth returns (fixed effects)

Intergenerational correlation in wealth 30 40 50 60 70 80 0.29 0 20 40 60 80 100 Father's wealth percentile Average son's wealth percentile 45-degree line Predicted son's percentile

Intergenerational correlation in returns to wealth 45 50 55 60 0.08 0 20 40 60 80 100 Father's return percentile Average son's return percentile 45-degree line Predicted son's percentile

Intergenerational correlation in the persistent component of the returns to wealth 45 50 55 60 0.09 0 20 40 60 80 100 Father's FE percentile Average son's FE percentile 45-degree line Predicted son's percentile

Why the intergenerational correlation? Parents with above average returns may be more likely to own profitable private businesses that they share with (or transfer to) their kids Kids of successful parents (in terms of returns on wealth) may simply imitate parents investment strategies Persistence may reflect correlation of returns with wealth the wealthy may earn higher average returns. Since wealth persists, e.g. through inheritances, so do returns to wealth Intergeneration transmission of preferences for risk or talent for investment

Implications of returns heterogeneity for the debate on wealth inequality We consider two implications of the evidence presented so far: 1. Does it have an impact on measurement of wealth inequality based on the capitalization approach? 2. Can it explain the gap between wealth and income inequality?

Returns heterogeneity and the measurement of wealth inequality Saez and Zucman (2015) have access to US tax records There is information on capital income, but no wealth information To recover wealth they use an imputation procedure based on a capitalization approach. Since, they can impute wealth assuming that returns are homogenous (within broad asset classes), i.e. Given our evidence of substantial heterogeneity in returns to wealth and their correlation with wealth levels, how reliable is the capitalization method? We can compare actual wealth inequality with imputed wealth inequality

Theoretical results With independence between returns to wealth and wealth levels, both Gini and top wealth shares are overstated With correlation between returns to wealth and wealth levels, Gini still overstated, but top wealth shares may be overstated or understated

How large are the biases in practice? We replicate Saez and Zucman s capitalization approach to impute wealth (excluding housing, which is of higher quality only after 2010) in the Norwegian case We then compute Gini indexes, and shares of wealth owned by the top 5%, 1%, 0.1% Results: Gini indexes systematically overstate the degree of wealth inequality For top shares, results depend on how far in the tail we go

Gini The Gini based on imputed wealth captures sufficiently well the long term trends in actual wealth inequality However, it overstates true inequality by a 1.05 factor on average It tends to do significantly worse in the middle of the sample period due to the introduction of a shareholder tax in 2006 (with some announcement effects at work since 2001)

Top wealth shares The evidence on top shares is more nuanced The larger the share we consider, the larger the overestimation However, the degree of overestimation declines (and even becomes underestimation) if we consider smaller and smaller fractiles This seems to agree with the presence of correlation between returns and wealth levels

The bias for the top 1% and 0.1% shares

Regression evidence Between 1978 and 2012, the top 0.1% wealth share increases by 15 p.p. in the US (Saez and Zucman, 2015) Ceteris paribus, an increase in corr(returns,wealth) of 0.07 (say, from 0.01 to 0.08) could explain the entire increase in the share assuming the top (actual) wealth share had remained constant which of course it wouldn t (at least in the long run) But generally: An increase in the correlation between wealth and returns may exaggerate the evidence of increase in wealth concentration at the very top Also: Top wealth shares vs. Gini

Conclusions Returns to assets vary substantially across households (even conditioning on demographics, portfolio composition, private business ownership). Moreover: a) They vary over time b) They have a persistent component ( fixed effect ) c) They are correlated with the level of wealth d) They are correlated intergenerationally, but mildly so Features b) and c) have usually being ignored What are the consequences of these findings for the debate on what determines the increase in wealth inequality and its extreme fat right tail?