Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Similar documents
American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

Properties of American option prices

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Convexity Theory for the Term Structure Equation

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

VOLATILITY TIME AND PROPERTIES OF OPTION PRICES

MARGIN CALL STOCK LOANS

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

The Uncertain Volatility Model

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Robustness of Delta hedging for path-dependent options in local volatility models

Hedging under arbitrage

Non-semimartingales in finance

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Enlargement of filtration

PDE Methods for the Maximum Drawdown

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Chapter 1. Introduction and Preliminaries. 1.1 Motivation. The American put option problem

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Valuing American Options by Simulation

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Path Dependent British Options

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Hedging under Arbitrage

The interpolation of options

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Citation: Dokuchaev, Nikolai Optimal gradual liquidation of equity from a risky asset. Applied Economic Letters. 17 (13): pp

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

The British Russian Option

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

The Azema Yor embedding in non-singular diusions

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

EARLY EXERCISE OPTIONS: UPPER BOUNDS

Optimal Selling Strategy With Piecewise Linear Drift Function

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

A SIMPLE DERIVATION OF AND IMPROVEMENTS TO JAMSHIDIAN S AND ROGERS UPPER BOUND METHODS FOR BERMUDAN OPTIONS

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Optimal Order Placement

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Risk Neutral Measures

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio

American-style Puts under the JDCEV Model: A Correction

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Conditional Full Support and No Arbitrage

Risk-Neutral Valuation

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Transcription:

Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 6, 2012, no. 112, 5597-5602 Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities Nasir Rehman Department of Mathematics and Statistics Allama Iqbal Open University, H-8 Islamabad nasirzainy1@hotmail.com Sultan Hussain COMSATS Institute of Information Technology Abbotabad, Pakistan sultanhussain@ciit.net.pk Wasim Ul-Haq Department of Mathematics Abdul Wali Khan University Mardan, Pakistan wasim474@hotmail.com Abstract We compare value functions of the American put options with different strikes, maturities and volatilities based on systematic use of the Dynamic Programming Principle together with the monotonicity in volatility property for the value functions of the American options. Since volatility and strike prices play a vital role in option pricing so these comparisons are also important from practical point of view. Mathematics Subject Classification: 60G40, 60G48, 91B28 Keywords: American Option, Optimal Exercise Boundary, Value Function, Volatility 1 Introduction We consider a probability space (Ω, F, P) and a standard Wiener process (W t ), 0 t T, on it. It is assumed that the time horizon T is finite and the filtration F =(F t )0 t T is the augmentation of the natural filtration

5598 N. Rehman, S. Hussain and W. Ul-Haq of (W t ), 0 t T. On the filtered probability space (Ω, F, F t, P), 0 t T, we consider a financial market with two assets (B t,s t ), 0 t T where B t is the value of the unit bank account at time t and S t is the stock value at time t. The evolution of these values obeys the stochastic differential equations db t = r(t) B t dt, 0 t T,B 0 =1 (1.1) ds t = r(t) S t dt + S t σ(t, S t ) dw t, 0 t T,S 0 > 0, (1.2) where the continuous interest rate r(t), 0 t T satisfies 0 <r r(t) r, 0 t T, (1.3) and σ(t, x) is continuous function with respect to pair (t, x) from [0,T] [0, ) to(0, ), such that the diffusion function σ(t, x) =x σ(t, x) ishölder continuous with exponent 1/2 with respect to x uniformly in t. σ(t, y) σ(t, x) c y x 1 2, (1.4) and 0 <σ σ(t, x) σ. (1.5) We shall state the American put option problem following the general framework of chapter 2 in Karatzas,Shreve [7]. Consider at first the discounted payoff process X t = e R t 0 r(v)dv (K S t ) +, 0 t T, (1.6) which is obviously bounded continuous process. Theorem 5.8, chapter 2 of Karatzas, Shreve [7] states that the value process V t at time t equals V t = e R t 0 r(v)dv Y t, (a.s.) (1.7) where the process (Y t, F t ), 0 t T is the so-called Snell envelope of the process (X t, F t ), 0 t T, that is the minimal supermartingale majorizing the latter process. According to theorem D.7 of the Appendix D [7] the Snell envelope (Y t, F t ), 0 t T has rightcontinuous paths and for arbitrary (F t ) 0 t T stopping time τ the following equality is valid: Y τ = ess sup E(X σ /F τ ), (a.s.) (1.8) τ σ T where the essential supremum is taken over all (F t ) 0 t T stopping times σ such that τ σ T. Moreover as the filtration (F t ) 0 t T, is generated by Brownian motion (W t ), 0 t T, from Theorem D.13,Appendix D [7] we get that actually the Snell envelope (Y t, F t ), 0 t T has almost surely continuous paths.

Sensitivity of American option prices 5599 Let us introduce for any t, 0 t T, the stopping time τ t τt = inf{u t : Y u = X u }, 0 t T. (1.9) Theorems D.9 and D.12 of Appendix D [7] assert the fundamental Dynamic Programming Principle for the optimal stopping problem, namely that the stopped supermartingale (Y u τ t, F u ),t u T, is indeed a martingale and hence (a.s.) E(Y u τ t /F t )=Y t (1.10) for arbitrary t [0, T]. From the previous considerations we conclude that the value process (V t, F t ), 0 t T, of the American put option is related to the optimal stopping problem of the discounted payoff process (X t, F t ), 0 t T, by the relationship V t = ess sup E ( e R τ ) t r(v)dv (K S τ ) + /F t (a.s.) (1.11) t τ T for arbitrary t, 0 t T. To evaluate the latter expression we have to introduce the family of the solutions of the stochastic differential equation (1.2) with arbitrary initial condition x 0 and starting instant t, 0 t T, ds u (t, x) =r(u) S u (t, x)du + S u (t, x) σ ( u, S u (t, x) ) dw u, (1.12) t u T,x 0,S t (t, x) =x. Note that by Proposition 2.13,chapter 5 of Karatzas, Shreve [8] thanks to condition (1.4) on the diffusion coefficient σ(t, x), there exists a unique strong solution for the latter stochastic differential equation. Let us introduce now the American put value function v(t, x) = sup E[e R τ t K S τ (t, x) )+ ], (1.13) t τ T 0 t T, x 0, the so-called continuation set D T = {(t, x) :0 t<t,x>0:v(t, x) >g(x) =(K x) + } and the stopping region C T = {(t, x) :0 t T,x 0:v(t, x) =g(x)}. Define also the optimal exercise boundary b T (t), 0 t<t,as follows b T (t) = inf{x :0 x K : v(t, x) >g(x)}, 0 t<t. The objective of this paper is to prove a new type of comparison result for the value functions (1.13) of the American put options with different strikes, maturities and volatilities.

5600 N. Rehman, S. Hussain and W. Ul-Haq The basic idea in our approach consists in combining the Dynamic Programming Principle with the systematic use of presently well known monotonicity in volatility property of the European as well as American options value functions with convex payoffs as originally established by Bergman,Grundy and Wiener [2] and by El-Karoui, Jeanblanc-Picque and Shreve [4] and afterwards generalized and refined by Hobson [5], Janson and Tysk [6] and Ekstrom [3] in case of the local volatility, which is only Hölder(1/2) continuous in x. 2 The comparison result for the value functions of the American put options There exists a well-known relationship between the value process V u,s u T, and the value function v(u, x) (see equality (2.12) [9]) V u = v ( u, S u (s, x) ), s u T. Hence the stopping time τs introduced in (1.9) can be written in the following manner τs = inf{u s : v ( u, S u (s, x) ) = g ( S u (s, x) ) }. Then the stopped stochastic process e R τ s u s r(v)dv v ( τ s u, Q τ s u (s, x) ), s u T, x 0, is a martingale on the time interval [s, T ]. Using the latter property at u = s and u = t we get v(s, x) =Ee R τ s t s r(v)dv v ( τ s t, S τ s t(s, x) ),s t T. (2.1) This equality is a variant of the Dynamic Programming Principle in optimal stopping and will be used in the present article. Now we are going to state the main result which consists in comparison of the value functions of American puts with different strikes, maturities and volatilities. It is inspired by similar result of Achdou [1], Lemma 3.6, concerning the comparison of the solutions of certain variational inequalities. For the formulation of this result we need to consider the solution S u (s, x) of the stochastic differential equation (1.12) with constant volatility σ ds u (s, x) =S u (s, x) r(u) du+s u (s, x) σ dw u,s u T,S s (s, x) =x, x 0, and to introduce the value function of the corresponding optimal stopping problem for arbitrary time interval [s, t],s t T, and arbitrary strike price

Sensitivity of American option prices 5601 C v(s, x) = sup E [ e R τ s rd (v)dv (C S τ (s, x) ) +], 0 s t T,x 0. (2.2) s τ t The next theorem is important from practical viewpoint too since the volatilities and strikes are major ingredients in option pricing. We can see how American option prices fluctuate when we change maturity, volatility and strike. Theorem.The following relationship is valid between American put values with different strikes,maturities and volatilities v(s, x) v(s, x)+(k C), 0 s t, x 0, (2.3) where C is arbitrary constant such that 0 C b T (t), and b T (t) is the value at instant t of the optimal exercise boundary b T (u), 0 u<t,of the optimal stopping problem (1.13). Proof. Let us start from the Dynamic Programming Equation (see section 3 of [9]) v(s, x) =E [ e R τs t s r(v)dv (K ( S τ s t(s, x) ) ) + I (τ s t)+e R t r(v)dv v ( s t, S t (s, x) ) I (τ s >t)]. Now suppose τs >tthen from the definition of the latter stopping time τ s we obtain v ( t, S t (s, x) ) > ( K S t (s, x) )+, that is S t (s, x) >b T (t), and by the decreasing character of the value function v(t, x) inx we get v ( t, S t (s, x) ) v ( t, b T (t) ) = ( K b T (t) ) + K C, on the event (τs >t). Therefore v(s, x) E [ e R τs r(v)dv (K S t s τ s (s, x) )+ I (τ s t)+e R τs t s r(v)dv (K C) I (τ s >t)]. (2.4) Note that ( K Sτ (s, s x))+ (K C)+ ( C S τ s (s, x) )+, then the following estimate follows from the previous inequality v(s, x) E [ e R τ s t s r(v)dv (C S τ s (s, x) )+ I (τ s t)] +(K C) ṽ(s, x)+(k C), where ṽ(s, x) = sup E[e R τ s r(v)dv (C S τ (s, x) )+ ]. s τ t

5602 N. Rehman, S. Hussain and W. Ul-Haq By the monotonicity in volatility property of the American option value function we obtain ṽ(s, x) v(s, x).0 s t T,x 0, and from the previous inequality we arrive to the estimate (2.3), i.e. we have proved the theorem. References [1] Y. Achdou An inverse problem for a parabolic variational inequality arising in volatility calibration with American options, SIAM J. Control Optim., 43(5)(2005), 1583-1615. [2] Y.Z. Bergman, B.D. Grundy, Z. Wiener General properties of option prices, Journal of Finance, 51(1996), 1573-1610. [3] E. Ekstrom Properties of American option prices, Stoch. Process Appl., 114 (2)(2004), 265-278. [4] N. El-Karoui, M. Jeanblanc-Picque, S.E.Shreve Robustness of the Black and Scholes formula, Math Finance, 8(2)(1998), 93-126. [5] D.G. Hobson Volatility misspecification, option pricing and superreplication via coupling, Ann. Appl. Probab., 8(1)(1998), 193-205. [6] S. Janson, J. Tysk Volatility time and properties of option prices, The Annals of Applied Probability, 13(3)(2003), 890-913. [7] I. Karatzas, S.E. Shreve, Methods of Mathematical Finance, Springer, New York, 1998. [8] I. Karatzas, S.E. Shreve, Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, 2nd Edn. Springer-Verlag, New York, 1991. [9] N. Rehman, M. Shashiashvili The American Foreign Exchange Option in Time- Dependent One-Dimensional Diffusion Model for Exchange Rate, Appl. Math. Optim., 59(3)(2009), 329-363. Received: June, 2012