Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

Similar documents
Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Keynes Chapter Twenty-Two: A System Dynamics Model

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

Lessons V and VI: FX Parity Conditions

Chapter 13. Introduction. Goods Market Equilibrium. Modeling Strategy. Nominal Exchange Rate: A Convention. The Nominal Exchange Rate

Lessons V and VI: Overview

International Monetary Policy

Chapter 17 Appendix A

Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot.

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * September 2000

Formulating Models of Simple Systems using VENSIM PLE

Financial markets in the open economy - the interest rate parity. Exchange rates in the short run.

The Government and Fiscal Policy

18. Forwards and Futures

4. SOME KEYNESIAN ANALYSIS

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 10 Aggregate Demand I

This paper is part of a series that uses the authors' Keynes+Schumpeter

3. OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * First draft: September 2000 This draft: July 2001

Module 3: Factor Models

1) Real and Nominal exchange rates are highly positively correlated. 2) Real and nominal exchange rates are well approximated by a random walk.

Homework Assignment #3: Answer Key

TIM 50 Fall 2011 Notes on Cash Flows and Rate of Return

Chapter 12 Consumption, Real GDP, and the Multiplier

THE KEYNESIAN MODEL IN THE SHORT AND LONG RUN

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

INTEREST RATES Overview Real vs. Nominal Rate Equilibrium Rates Interest Rate Risk Reinvestment Risk Structure of the Yield Curve Monetary Policy

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

2. THE KEYNESIAN THEORY OF DETERMINATION OF NATIONAL INCOME

Putting the Economy Together

14.02 Quiz #2 SOLUTION. Spring Time Allowed: 90 minutes

Bank Forex Exposure and Capital Requirements. Kevin Davis. Colonial Mutual Professor of Finance. Department of Accounting and Finance

11. Short Run versus Medium Run Determinants of Exchange Rates

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Ocean Hedge Fund. James Leech Matt Murphy Robbie Silvis

8: Economic Criteria

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

Chapter 19 MONEY SUPPLIES, PRICE LEVELS, AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Forward Foreign Exchange

Corporate Exposure to Exchange Rates

Exam #2 Review Questions (Answers) ECNS 303 October 31, 2011

International Economics Fall 2011 Exchange Rate Determination, Part 1. Paul Deng Sept. 27/29, 2011

HOMEWORK 8 (CHAPTER 16 PRICE LEVELS AND THE EXCHANGE RATE IN THE LONG RUN) ECO41 FALL 2015 UDAYAN ROY

Closure in CGE Models

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Theory of the rate of return

Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises

Equity Valuation APPENDIX 3A: Calculation of Realized Rate of Return on a Stock Investment.

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

9. ISLM model. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations CHAPTER 9. slide 0

The Zero Lower Bound

Lecture 5: Flexible prices - the monetary model of the exchange rate. Lecture 6: Fixed-prices - the Mundell- Fleming model

CHAPTER 23 OUTPUT AND PRICES IN THE SHORT RUN

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals.

The Professional Forecasters

The Dornbusch overshooting model. The short run and long run together

Please respond to: LME Clear Market Risk Risk Management Department

Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts

Cost Shocks in the AD/ AS Model

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

1 The Solow Growth Model

Midterm - Economics 160B, Fall 2011 Version A

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach Assume uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), which is implied by perfect capital substitutability 1.

Correlation vs. Trends in Portfolio Management: A Common Misinterpretation

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions:

UNIT II: THE KEYNESIAN THEORY OF DETERMINATION OF NATIONAL INCOME

Cash Flow and the Time Value of Money

University of Siegen

Exam #2 Review Answers ECNS 303

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

APPENDIX 3A: Duration and Immunization

Notes on the Monetary Model of Exchange Rates

CHAPTER 16. EXPECTATIONS, CONSUMPTION, AND INVESTMENT

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions.

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

1 Introduction. Term Paper: The Hall and Taylor Model in Duali 1. Yumin Li 5/8/2012

Econ 340. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Outline: Exchange Rates

Global Financial Management

covered warrants uncovered an explanation and the applications of covered warrants

INTERNATIONAL FINANCE

The Open Economy. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Answers to chapter 3 review questions

Futures and Forward Markets

Term Structure of Interest Rates. For 9.220, Term 1, 2002/03 02_Lecture7.ppt

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

ECON 3560/5040 Week 8-9

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

16. Foreign Exchange

Arbitrage is a trading strategy that exploits any profit opportunities arising from price differences.

Transcription:

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach John T. Harvey Professor of Economics Department of Economics Box 98510 Texas Christian University Fort Worth, Texas 7619 (817)57-730 j.harvey@tcu.edu Presented at the Association for Evolutionary Economics Conference Boston, Massachusetts, January 006

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach The theory of uncovered interest rate parity has enjoyed very little empirical support. Despite the fact that global financial markets trade seven days a week, twenty-four hours a day and communication takes place almost instantaneously, there are strong indications that differences in expected rates of return across countries can be non-zero and large for extended periods of time. However, these deviations display a pattern within which there is an important clue regarding their cause. Changes in the differences between expected rates of return across countries largely correspond to changes in the differences between national interest rates. In other words, when agents expect the rate of return (taking into account both interest rates and forecast exchange rate movements) to be higher in one country than another, that country also tends to have the higher interest rates. This means, as will be demonstrated below, that deviations from uncovered interest rate parity cannot be explained (as has been argued elsewhere) by relying on the assumption that agents perceive some assets to be riskier than others. A model of international financial flows that incorporates John Maynard Keynes concept of forecast confidence, however, has no difficulty explaining this commonly observed phenomenon. The purpose of this paper is to show the superiority of Keynes approach by comparing three system dynamics models of the relationship among interest and exchange rates: one based on traditional uncovered interest rate parity, one with risk, and one with forecast confidence. It will be demonstrated that only the last produces patterns consistent with those observed in the real world. This paper is an extension of the empirical study undertaken in Harvey (004).

Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Uncovered interest rate parity makes the seemingly innocuous claim that the return on interestbearing assets throughout the world must be identical once expected exchange rate movements are taken into account. This can be expressed (using the dollar and the euro to make the example more concrete) as shown in equation (1): (1) (1+r $ ) = (i/$)(1+r i )($/i) e where r $ is the rate of interest paid on dollar deposits, r i is the rate of interest paid on euro deposits, (i/$) is the spot price of dollars in euros, and ($/i) e is the market s expectation of the spot price of the euro (in dollars) at some future date (where the time horizon of the interest rates and the exchange rate expectation are the same). If one side exceeds the other it is then assumed that this sets into motion forces that will restore the equilibrium. Were the left side of (1) to exceed the right side, for example, this would create capital flows from the euro to the dollar, driving r $ down (as capital becomes less scarce), r i up (as capital becomes more scarce), and (i/$) up (as agents buy the dollar with the euro, causing the former to appreciate). Figure 1 shows a system dynamics model (written in Vensim) of the basic uncovered interest rate parity relationship introduced in equation (1). At the center is UIRP Deviation, which is measured as (1+r $ ) - (i/$)(1+r i )($/i) e (i.e., the amount by which the market expects that US returns will exceed foreign). If this number is zero, equilibrium prevails and nothing is transmitted along the single arrow emanating from UIRP Deviation. If instead, for example, US returns are expected to be greater than those of foreign assets, this will lead to a rise US Net Capital Inflows (hence the positive sign on the arrow linking UIRP Deviation and US Net Capital Inflows). This affects three variables in the model: the US interest rate (which is driven down as capital accumulates, as indicated by the negative

sign on the arrow; more on the construction of this variable below), the Foreign interest rate (which rises as capital becomes more scarce note the positive sign), and FX per USD, or units of foreign currency per dollar (this rises as agents buy the dollar in order to buy US interest-bearing assets; note the positive sign). I chose to model the exchange rate and the two interest rates as levels affected by rates. Delta on each is the amount by which the US Net Capital Inflows caused a change in this time period. Expected FX per USD is treated as exogenous, and FX per USD, Expected FX per USD, Foreign interest rate, and US interest rate feed back into UIRP Deviation so as to solve for the next period s deviation: (1+r $ ) - (i/$)(1+($/i) e. Delta FX per USD Delta Foreign Interest Rate + + Currency Market FX per USD - Foreign Interest Rate Foreign Financial Mkt + - + UIRP Deviation US Net Capital Inflows Expected FX per USD + + US Interest Rate + Market Forces US Interest Rate US Financial Mkt US Central Bank Policy Adjustment Delta US Interest Rate - Figure 1: Traditional UIRP model without risk or forecast confidence.

Note that US Interest Rate is affected by an exogenous force and an endogenous one. US Interest Rate is simply the sum of Market Forces US Interest Rate (whose construction is parallel to that of Foreign Interest Rate) and US Central Bank Policy Adjustment. This was done so that external shocks to the interest rate could be introduced through the latter. An equivalent policy variable for Foreign Interest Rate was not created since US Central Bank Policy Adjustment is sufficient to create changes in interest rate differentials. I chose to measure the interest rates as decimal numbers (0.06 for 6%, for example) and the exchange rates (both actual and expected) as indices beginning with 100. To give a sense of the behavior the parameters and starting values create, suppose we start with model with FX per USD = 100, Expected FX per USD = 100, Foreign interest rate = 0.06, and US interest rate = 0.06. In that case, UIRP Deviation = 0 and the model sits in equilibrium (generating a flat line at zero for UIRP Deviation). To throw the model out of equilibrium, introduce a US Central Bank Policy Adjustment of -0.04, temporarily lowering US Interest Rate to 0.0. This means that there is now a UIRP Deviation of -0.04, causing agents expect US interest-bearing assets to earn (once exchange rate movements are taken into account) a 4% lower return than foreign ones. The first consequence of this change is that the arrow from UIRP Deviation to US Net Capital Flows now carries a non-zero signal. As I chose to measure the latter as a simple index wherein net capital flows would be equal to 100 times the deviation, US Net Capital Flows are now - 4 (-0.04 times 100). The -4 is carried out in three separate directions. In terms of the impact of capital flows on interest rates, I opted to have 10% of any given deviation be corrected per round (which represents one hour). For example, when the -4 is fed into Delta US Interest Rate, it is multiplied by - 0.001. This means that the US interest rate will rise by 0.4%, or 1/10 of the absolute value of the -4%

deviation. Meanwhile, the -4 is multiplied by 0.001 in Delta Foreign Interest Rate, so that the adjustment is also 0.4% (albeit in the other direction), again 1/10 of the deviation. With respect to the exchange rate, there the -4 is multiplied by 0.1, meaning that (since the initial value for FX per USD is set at an index of 100) it falls to 99.6. This, too, is 1/10 of the way back to equilibrium (the value of FX per USD that would eliminate the deviation is 96., or roughly 96). With these values and parameters it requires 41 hours for the system to return to equilibrium at UIRP Deviation = 0 (the use of hours as the time period does not affect the behavior of the model; one could imagine this as minutes, instead). Figure shows what was described above (ignore Interest Rate Differential for the moment). In periods 1 through 50, Foreign Interest Rate = US Interest Rate = 0.06 and FX per USD = Expected FX per USD = 100. Therefore, UIRP Deviation = 0 and simulation is flat at that value. In period 51, however, there is a US Central Bank Policy Adjustment of -0.04, so that the US Interest Rate falls to 0.0. This lowered UIRP Deviation to -0.04, but the adjustment begins immediately. It is complete by period 9. 0.04 UIRP Deviation vs. Interest differential 0.0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1-0.0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1-0.04 1 10 19 8 37 46 55 64 73 8 91 100 Hour Interest Rate Differential : Current UIRP Deviation : Current 1 1 1 1 1 1 percentage points percentage points Figure : Traditional UIRP, pattern of UIRP deviation compared to interest rate differential.

Returning to the thesis of this paper, the key issue is whether or not changes UIRP Deviation tend to mimic those of the simple interest rate differential, US Interest Rate minus Foreign Interest Rate. The plot of the interest rate differential in Figure offers evidence to the contrary, the particular problem being the behavior of UIRP Deviation. One can temporarily throw it out of equilibrium, as occurs at hour 51, and in a manner that is consistent with real-world observations (i.e., UIRP Deviation and the interest rate differential move in the same direction and both are, in this case, negative). But UIRP Deviation soon returns to zero. We do not see the model settling into an equilibrium wherein UIRP Deviation and the interest rate differential are both non zero and of the same sign. Traditional interpretations of UIRP cannot account for the patterns observed in the real world because UIRP Deviation must always return to zero. A common (and reasonable) modification of UIRP is to add risk. This is accomplished by intercepting the signal from UIRP Deviation to US Net Capital Flows and altering it to reflect agents concerns about the assets of a particular country. The modification to Figure 1 is illustrated in Figure 3 (to save space just the change is shown the rest of the model is identical to that shown in Figure 1). Risk on US Assets is measured in decimal form and represents the premium that US asset issuers must pay in order to convince agents to hold them despite their greater risk. This number is then subtracted from UIRP Deviation in Deviation Adjusted for Risk to create the value that affects US Net Capital Flows. Figure 3: Link from UIRP Deviation to US Net Capital Inflows, adjusted for risk. Figure 4 shows the plot of model with the adjustment for risk. The behavior is the same as that shown in Figure but, because of the 0.0 risk premium on US assets, UIRP Deviation is drawn

toward % rather than 0% (note that I started the model with US Interest Rate at 0.08 rather than 0.06 so that this simulation would begin in equilibrium). When the US Central Bank Policy Adjustment becomes -0.04 in hour 51, UIRP Deviation settles at % and the interest rate differential returns to equilibrium at -1.36%. UIRP Deviation and the interest rate differential are both non zero, but they are the opposite sign. The key of course is that regardless of what we introduce with respect to the interest rate differential, UIRP Deviation must always return to % (or whatever value we select) because it simply reflects the risk premium on US assets. Depending on the shocks we introduce into the system, interest rate differential can come to rest at a number of different values; UIRP Deviation, however, will inevitably find its equilibrium at %. Since there is no reason to assume that the risk premium will invariably be the same sign as the simple interest rate differential (though it can by coincidence), this approach also comes up short in terms of generating patterns consistent with what we observe in the real world. 0.06 UIRP Deviation vs. Interest Differential 0.04 0.0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1-0.0 1 10 19 8 37 46 55 64 73 8 91 100 Hour Interest Rate Differential : Current 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 UIRP Deviation : Current 1 Figure 4: Traditional UIRP with risk, pattern of UIRP deviation compared to interest rate differential.

Modifying the model according to the observations made by John Maynard Keynes in the General Theory (1964; see especially chapter twelve), however, yields an approach that is perfectly consistent with empirical observations. There, he argues that agents confidence in their forecasts is an important and overlooked consideration. Recall the construction of UIRP Deviation. All of the component variables are known by market participants to be accurate except one: Expected FX per USD. It is necessarily a forecast, and an extremely important one given the potential for substantial exchange rate movements over the time horizon in question. So, by virtue of the fact that Expected FX per USD is one of its components, UIRP Deviation is a forecast, and forecasts are never certain. In general, the more confidence agents have in their predictions, the more funds they are willing to commit in speculation. The most realistic way to incorporate this into the model would be to make capital flows (for a given UIRP Deviation) go from a trickle to a strong flow as forecast confidence increased. To make the exposition simple, however, I elected instead to let portfolio investment flow either unimpeded or not at all depending on whether the absolute value of UIRP Deviation exceeded a critical value. I modeled the latter as an inverse function of market confidence and expressed it as a forecast error. For example, market participants may expect a UIRP Deviation of 0.03, but with an anticipated forecast error of +/-0.0. In other words, they believe that the return on U.S. interest-bearing assets will be 3%, though they would not be surprised if it were as low as 1% (i.e., 3%-%) or as high as 5% (i.e., 3%+%). I then supposed a simple rule of thumb for agents in the model: whenever the absolute value of the UIRP Deviation exceeds the absolute value of Forecast Error, agents should unhesitatingly buy the assets of the nation with the higher expected return (and capital flows unabated). This is so because even under the worst-case scenario one still profits. On the other hand, when the absolute value of the UIRP Deviation is less than the absolute value of Forecast Error, agents should not enter the market

(and no capital will flow) since within the range of possible outcomes includes one that yields a loss. Again, this is a simplification over a specification that would allow for ranges of capital flow (from unhindered to zero), but it will be much simpler to model and still give the same basic result. Figure 5 shows the adjustment to Figure 1 necessary to incorporate Keynes confidence (it is possible to combine risk and confidence in the same model; I opted not to do so for simplicity and because it does not alter the results). Note that, unlike in the rest of the exposition, the signs on the arrows feeding into Trigger Point Determination are based on the absolute values of UIRP Deviation and Forecast Error. The arrow from Trigger Point Determination to US Net Capital Flows is in a sense simply a continuation of that from UIRP Deviation, the only difference being that if UIRP Deviation does not exceed Forecast Error, a zero signal be sent to US Net Capital Flows. Otherwise, the behavior is exactly as explained for Figure 1 and Trigger Point Determination has no effect on the signal from UIRP Deviation at all. Figure 6 shows the same scenario as set out in Figures and 4, but with confidence explicitly modeled. The forecast error is set at 1%, such that agents, for a given UIRP Deviation, believe that their forecast will fall within one percentage point of that value, plus or Figure 5: Link from UIRP Deviation to US Net Capital Inflows, adjusted for confidence. minus.

0.04 UIRP Deviation vs. Interest Differential 0.0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1-0.0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1-0.04 1 10 19 8 37 46 55 64 73 8 91 100 Day Interest Rate Differential : Current 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 UIRP Deviation : Current 1 Figure 6: UIRP with Keynes confidence, pattern of UIRP Deviation compared to interest rate differential. Finally, we observe what is commonly seen in the real world: UIRP Deviation moves with the raw interest rate differential. Both settle into equilibrium at negative values, with the interest rate differential at -.06% and UIRP Deviation at -1%. That the latter comes to rest at this level is a function of the fact that Forecast Error is 1%; capital will flow (and variables adjust) only when UIRP Deviation > Forecast Error; once UIRP Deviation is less than or equal to Forecast Error, the flow stops and hence the adjustment in UIRP Deviation stops. Figure 7 shows the same setup with multiple shocks to US Interest Rate ( US Central Bank Policy Adjustment is 0 in periods 1-4, 0.04 from 5-50, 0 from 51-75 and -0.04 from 76-100). Again, UIRP Deviation adjusts only up to the point that it is less than or equal to Forecast Error (1% in this example) in absolute value. The reader should note that it is possible to generate examples where UIRP Deviation and the interest rate

differential are not of the same sign in this specification, but, just as in the real world, it is the exception rather than the rule. In general, because agents lack the conviction to completely trust their exchange rate forecasts, UIRP Deviation is pulled in the direction of the raw interest rate movements and the subsequent deviation is not completely eliminated. 0.04 UIRP Deviation vs. Interest Differential 0.0 1 1 1 1 0-0.0-0.04 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 10 19 8 37 46 55 64 73 8 91 100 Day Interest Rate Differential : Current 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 UIRP Deviation : Current 1 Figure 7: UIRP with Keynes confidence, pattern of UIRP Deviation compared to interest rate differential with multiple shocks. Conclusion The empirical failure of uncovered interest rate parity has stood as a mystery for a very long time in financial economics. Attempts to solve the problem using risk have failed time and again. Reaching back to Keynes, however, offers a solution that is both up to the task and intuitively appealing. A realistic formulation of agents expectations (a variable, incidentally, to which very little attention has been paid up to this point) suggests that what we conclude from the standard approach to

uncovered interest rate parity (i.e., UIRP Deviation = 0) is the exception rather than the rule.

REFERENCES Harvey, John T. Deviations from uncovered interest rate parity: a Post Keynesian explanation. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 7, no.1 (Fall 004): 19-36. Keynes, John Maynard. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Publishers, 1964.