Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Similar documents
Constructing Markov models for barrier options

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

SHORT-TIME IMPLIED VOLATILITY IN EXPONENTIAL LÉVY MODELS

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Probability in Options Pricing

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Risk Neutral Measures

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Calculating Implied Volatility

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Bruno Dupire April Paribas Capital Markets Swaps and Options Research Team 33 Wigmore Street London W1H 0BN United Kingdom

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Hedging under Arbitrage

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Pricing Implied Volatility

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Merton s Jump Diffusion Model

Local Variance Gamma Option Pricing Model

The Black-Scholes Model

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Forward Dynamic Utility

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Path Dependent British Options

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Barrier Options Pricing in Uncertain Financial Market

TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II. is non-stochastic and equal to dt. From these results we state the following:

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

SADDLEPOINT APPROXIMATIONS TO OPTION PRICES 1. By L. C. G. Rogers and O. Zane University of Bath and First Chicago NBD

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.cp] 9 Mar 2010

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Skewness in Lévy Markets

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Near-Expiry Asymptotics of the Implied Volatility in Local and Stochastic Volatility Models

Numerical Solutions to an integro-differential parabolic problem arising in the pricing of financial options in a Levy market

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

The British Russian Option

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

The stochastic calculus

Remarks on American Options for Jump Diffusions

Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models

King s College London

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Information, Interest Rates and Geometry

The Black-Scholes Model

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Stochastic Volatility Modeling

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Homework Assignments

Transcription:

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Rama Cont Yu Gu Abstract When the underlying asset is a continuous martingale, call option prices solve the Dupire equation, a forward parabolic PDE in the maturity and strike variables. By contrast, when the underlying asset is described by a discontinuous semimartingale, call prices solve a partial integro-differential equation (PIDE), containing a non-local integral term. We show that the two classes of equations share no common solution: a given set of option prices is either generated from a continuous martingale ( diffusion ) model or from a model with jumps, but not both. In particular, our result shows that Dupire s inversion formula for reconstructing local volatility from option prices does not apply to option prices generated from models with jumps. 1 Introduction Since the seminal work of Black, Scholes and Merton [3, 16] partial differential equations (PDE) have been used as a way of characterizing and efficiently computing option prices. In the Black- Scholes-Merton model and various extensions of this model which retain the Markov property of the risk factors, option prices can be characterized in terms of solutions to a backward PDE, whose variables are time (to maturity) and the value of the underlying asset. The use of backward PDEs for option pricing has been extended to cover options with path-dependent and early exercise features, as well as to multifactor models (see e.g. [1]). When the underlying asset exhibit jumps, option prices can be computed by solving an analogous partial integro-differential equation (PIDE) [, 9]. A second important step was taken by Dupire [1, 11] who showed that when the underlying asset is assumed to follow a diffusion process ds t = S t σ(t, S t )dw t, prices of call options (at a given date t ) solve a forward PDE C t T (T, K) = r(t )K C t K (T, K) + K σ(t, K) on [t, ) (, ) in the strike and maturity variables, with the initial condition Imperial College London, r.cont@imperial.ac.uk Columbia University, yg54@columbia.edu K > C t (t, K) = (S t K) +. C t (T, K) (1.1) K 1

This forward equation allows to price call options with various strikes and maturities on the same underlying asset, by solving a single partial differential equation. Moreover it has been widely used as a tool for model calibration: the local volatility function given by the Dupire formula [11] ( ) CT (t, K) + r(t)kc K (t, K) σ(t, K) := K, (1.) C KK (t, K) provides a candidate solution to the inverse problem of extracting information on volatility from observed option prices [6]. Given the theoretical and computational usefulness of the forward equation, there have been various attempts to extend Dupire s forward equation to other types of options and processes, most notably to Markov processes with jumps [, 5, 8, 14, 4]. Most of these constructions use the Markov property of the underlying process in a crucial way (see however [15]). As noted by Dupire [1], the forward PDE holds in a more general context than the backward PDE: even if the (risk-neutral) dynamics of the underlying asset is not necessarily Markovian, but described by a continuous Brownian martingale ds t = S t δ t dw t, then call options still verify a forward PDE where the diffusion coefficient is given by the local (or effective) volatility function σ(t, S) given by σ(t, S) = E{δt S t = S}. Recently Bentata and Cont [7] have derived a forward partial integro-differential equation for prices of call options in a model where the dynamics of the underlying asset under the pricing measure is described by a discontinuous semimartingale, extending Dupire forward equation to a large class of non-markovian models with jumps. In particular for the jump diffusion model, when the underlying process is given by T T T S T = S t + S t r t dt + S t σ t dw t + S t (e y 1)Ñ(dtdy), t t t with the compensated Poisson measure Ñ(dtdy) = N(dtdy) ν(dy)dt, the forward equation becomes C t T = r(t )K C t K + K σ(t, K) C t K + y C t K (T, dy)φ(ln(k )) (1.3) y with the same initial condition C t (t, K) = (S t K) +, where φ is the double exponential tail of the lévy measure ν defined as φ(x) = { x (ez e x )ν(dz) if x >, x (ex e z )ν(dz) if x <. (1.4) A natural question arises about whether the two classes of equations, i.e., (1.1) and (1.3), could generate the same option prices. If not, what would happen when we apply Dupire s formula to option prices generated from model with jumps? In practice, there is no clue that whether the

price process is continuous or not, so given the market call option price surface as a function of maturity and strike C(T, K), people apply Dupire s formula (1.) to recover the local volatility surface σ(t, K), and expect that the corresponding local volatility model to reproduce the market price, but is it always feasible? In this paper, we show that there exists no common solution to (1.1) and (1.3), which means the sets of possible call option prices generated by the two different kinds of models, i.e., the local volatility model and the jump diffusion model, don t overlap with each other. It turns out that the appearance of the non-local structure in (1.3), i.e., the integral term, brings significant difference to the equation from the local PDE, and we can show the recovered local volatility surface from model with jumps blows up in the short time maturities. The following of the paper is organized as follows. In Section we make assumptions about the parameters appeared in the equations and present some technical lemmas, then we prove the main theorem in Section 3. Assumptions and lemmas We first make assumptions about the parameters appeared in (1.1) and (1.3). Assumption 1. r(t), σ(t, K) are bounded deterministic functions, σ is bounded from below by some positive constant, and σ(t, K) σ(s, K) M t s α, (.1) Kσ K (t, K) + K σ KK (t, K) + K 3 σ KKK (t, K) M (.) for some uniform constant M and Hölder-exponent α (, 1). Assumption. ν so there exists x such that φ(x ) > and The following are two technical lemmas. 1 e y ν(dy) <. (.3) Lemma.1. φ(x) is continuous, 1 1 φ(x)dx <, and φ(x) is bounded when x 1. Proof. By Fubini s theorem, 1 φ(x)dx = 1 (e z e + 1)ν(dz) + 1 (e z z e z + 1)ν(dz) <. In the same way, we can show 1 φ(x)dx <. In addition, φ(x) is finite, and increases in (, ) while decreases in (, ), therefore, φ(x) is bounded when x 1. To prove the continuity, take x > for example. Assume y > x, we have: φ(x) φ(y) = [(e z e x )1 z>x (e z e y )1 z y ] ν(dz) = (I) + (II) + (III), 3

where (I) = (II) = (III) = e z 1 x<z<y ν(dz), (e y e x )1 z>x ν(dz), e y 1 x<z<y ν(dz). We see that (I) + (II) + (III) as y x, which completes the proof. Lemma.. Let S t satisfy ds t = S t (r(t)dt + σ(t, S t )dw t ), (.4) and S t = S exp(x t ) for some X t. Assume the density function of X t is G t (x), we have: for some positive constant M. Proof. First X t solves G t (x) M t exp( x Mt ) (.5) dx t = (r(t) 1 σ (t, S e Xt ))dt + σ(t, S e Xt )dw t (.6) with X =. Then we have G t (x) = Γ(t,, x) where Γ(t,, x) is the solution to the PDE t Γ = 1 xx ( σ (t, S e x )Γ ) + 1 x ( σ (t, S e x )Γ ) r(t) x Γ (.7) with initial condition Γ(,, x) = δ(x). By the classical results of parabolic PDE [13, Page 4, (6.1)], we have for some positive constant M. The proof is completed. Γ(t,, x) M t exp( x Mt ) (.8) 3 Results and conclusions In this section, we state and prove our main result. Without loss of generality, we assume t = and denote C t (T, K) as C(T, K). The following is the main theorem. Theorem 3.1. There exists no common solution to (1.1) and (1.3). Proof. Suppose C(T, K) is the solution to (1.1), we have T C(T, K) = exp( r(t)dt)e{(s T K) + }, 4

where S t satisfies ds t = S t (r(t)dt + σ(t, S t )dw t ). If we denote the density of S t as p t (x), we have: So T C(T, K) = exp( r(t)dt) K (y K)p T (y)dy. T C KK (T, K) = exp( r(t)dt)p T (K). If C(T, K) is also a solution to (1.3), then we have: 1 σ(t, K) K C KK (T, K) = 1 σ(t, K) K C KK (T, K) + Let x = ln(k/s ), by change of variable z = ln(y/s ), we have: This leads to 1 [ σ(t, S e x ) σ(t, S e x ) ] T S e x exp( r(t)dt)p T (S e x ) T = exp( r(t)dt) S e z p T (S e z )φ(x z)s e z dz. yc KK (T, y)φ(ln( K ))dy. (3.1) y 1 [ σ(t, S e x ) σ(t, S e x ) ] e x p T (S e x ) = e z p T (S e z )φ(x z)dz. (3.) Let S T = S exp(x T ) and the density of X T be G T (x), by elementary computation, we have: Now (3.) becomes p T (x) = 1 x G T (ln( x S )). 1 [ σ(t, S e x ) σ(t, S e x ) ] e x G T (x) = e z G T (z)φ(x z)dz. (3.3) By assumption, φ is positive at some x. Let x = x in (3.3), and when T, by Lemma. we have LHS = 1 [ σ(t, S e x ) σ(t, S e x ) ] e x G T (x ) Next, we show in (3.3) 1 σ(t, S e x ) σ(t, S e x ) e x M T exp( x MT ). RHS = which produces contradiction and completes the proof. e z G T (z)φ(x z)dz φ(x ), 5

Consider e z G T (z)φ(x z)dz = R R G T (z)(e z φ(x z) φ(x ))dz + φ(x ), by Lemma.1, e z φ(x z) as a function of z is continuous at, so ε >, there exists δ >, such that when z < δ, we have: e z φ(x z) φ(x ) < ε. Therefore R G T (z) e z φ(x z) φ(x ) dz G T (z)εdz + φ(x ) G T (z)dz + z <δ :=(I) + (II) + (III). z δ z δ G T (z)e z φ(x z) dz We see that (I) ε, (II) as T by Lemma.. For (III), we have: (III) M exp( MT 4 ) M exp( MT 4 ) +M exp( MT 4 ) M exp( MT 4 ) z δ/ T exp( 1 M (z M T z δ/ T, x T z 1 z δ/ T, x T z <1 z δ/ T exp( 1 M (z M T ) ) φ(x T z) dz exp( 1 M (z M T exp( 1 M (z M T +M exp( MT 4 ) 1 exp( 1 T M ( δ M T ) ) T ) )dz z <1 ) ) φ(x T z) dz ) ) φ(x T z) dz φ(z) dz, where we used M for possibly different constants. completed. First, let T, then ε, the proof is Remark 3.. From the beginning, we can assume the compensator includes some inhomogeneous local speed function, i.e., Ñ(dtdy) = N(dtdy) a(t, S t )ν(dy)dt for some function a(t, z), then the double exponential tail becomes φ = φ(t, x) = { x (ez e x )a(t, z)ν(dz) if x >, x (ex e z )a(t, z)ν(dz) if x <. (3.4) As long as we assume a(t, z) is bounded and continuous, and there exists x such that φ(, x ) >, our proof of Lemma.1 and Theorem 3.1 still applies. 6

Recall (3.1), we rewrite it as σ(t, K) = σ(t, K) K C KK (T, K) + yc KK (T, y)φ(ln(k/y))dy K, (3.5) C KK (T, K) and this is the local volatility surface recovered by Dupire s formula from the option prices generated in the jump diffusion model. If we assume Lemma. also holds for S t from a jump diffusion model, then by the same proof, choosing the strike K S such that φ(ln(k/s )) > and letting T, the numerator in (3.5) converges to some positive number while the denominator converges to zero, so σ(t, K). Therefore we see the blow up of local volatility surface in the short time maturities when applying Dupire s formula to model with jumps. Remark 3.3. The exponential decay of the tail of density function of ln(s t /S ) is not necessary. We only need proper decay to pass to the limit. In summary, we proved that two classes of equations share no common solutions, which indicates models with jumps and models with continuous price dynamics lead to disjoint sets of call price surfaces. It further sheds light on model calibration in the sense that Dupire s formula does not necessarily apply to models with jumps. Furthermore, we show that under appropriate conditions, the recovered local volatility surface from models with jumps explodes in the short time maturities. References [1] Y. Achdou and O. Pironneau, Computational methods for option pricing, vol. 3, Society for Industrial Mathematics, 5. 1 [] L. Andersen and J. Andreasen, Jump diffusion models: Volatility smile fitting and numerical methods for pricing, Review of Derivatives Research, 4 (), pp. 31 6. 1, [3] F. Black and M. Scholes, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, 3 (1973), p. 637654. 1 [4] P. Carr, H. Geman, D. B. Madan, and M. Yor, From local volatility to local Lévy models, Quant. Finance, 4 (4), pp. 581 588. [5] P. Carr and A. Hirsa, Why be backward? Forward equations for American options, RISK, (3). [6] R. Cont, Model calibration, in Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance, Wiley, Chichester, 1, pp. 11 119. [7] R. Cont and A. Bentata, Forward equations for option prices in semimartingale models, Finance and Stochastics, to appear (9). [8] R. Cont and I. Savescu, Forward equations for portfolio credit derivatives, Frontiers in Quantitative Finance, (8), pp. 69 93. [9] R. Cont and E. Voltchkova, Integro-differential equations for option prices in exponential lévy models, Finance and Stochastics, 9 (5), pp. 99 35. 1 7

[1] B. Dupire, Pricing with a smile, Risk, 7 (1994), pp. 18. 1 [11], Pricing and hedging with smiles, in Mathematics of Derivative Securities, M. Dempster and S. Pliska, eds., Cambridge University Press, 1997, pp. 13 111. 1, [1], A unified theory of volatility, tech. report, Working paper, Banque Paribas, 1997. [13] A. Friedman, Partial differential equations of parabolic type, vol. 38, Prentice-Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1964. 4 [14] B. Jourdain, Stochastic flow approach to dupires formula, Finance and Stochastics, 11 (7), pp. 51 535. [15] F. Klebaner, Option price when the stock is a semimartingale, Electronic Communications in Probability, 7 (), pp. 79 83. [16] R. Merton, Theory of rational option pricing, Bell Journal of Economics, 4 (1973), pp. 141 183. 1 8