Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Similar documents
Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Risk Neutral Measures

Lévy models in finance

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

King s College London

1 The continuous time limit

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

The Black-Scholes Model

King s College London

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Probability in Options Pricing

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser

The Black-Scholes Model

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Non-semimartingales in finance

Risk Neutral Valuation

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Homework Assignments

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science

Importance Sampling for Option Pricing. Steven R. Dunbar. Put Options. Monte Carlo Method. Importance. Sampling. Examples.

CRANK-NICOLSON SCHEME FOR ASIAN OPTION

Derivative Securities

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

4 Risk-neutral pricing

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Stochastic Volatility

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Hedging under Arbitrage

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Monte Carlo Simulations

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Homework Assignments

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

The stochastic calculus

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

and K = 10 The volatility a in our model describes the amount of random noise in the stock price. Y{x,t) = -J-{t,x) = xy/t- t<pn{d+{t-t,x))

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Lecture on Interest Rates

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Interest rate models in continuous time

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Martingale Measure TA

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Transcription:

Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous time. Then, we developed the risk-neutral asset pricing theory in discrete time. We can use our discrete techniques to see what form our results must take in the continuous world. It is easy to believe that we should be able to use a discrete model with very small time periods to approximate a continuous model. The Black-Scholes model is based in the lognormal model (geometric Brownian motion). With this in mind, we choose our approximation to have constant growth rate and constant noise. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. The cash bond has the form B t = e rt, which does not depend on the interval size. The stock price process follows the nodes of a binomial tree. If the current value of the stock is s, then over the next time period it moves to the new value { s exp(vδt + σ δt), if up, s exp(vδt σ δt), if down, Suppose our belief is that the jumps are equally likely to be up or down. So under the market measure, P [up jump] = /2 = P [down jump] at each time step. For a fixed time t, set N to be the number of time periods until time t, that is N = t/δt. Then S t = S exp(vt + σ t( 2X N N N )) where X N is the total number of the N separate jumps which were up jumps. To see what happens as δt (or equivalently N ) we call on the Central limit Theorem. Theorem (Central Limit Theorem) Let ξ, ξ 2,... be a sequence of independent identically distributed random variables under the probability measure P with finite mean µ and finite non-zero variance σ 2 and let S n = ξ +... + ξ n. Then S n nµ nσ 2 converges in distribution to an N(, ) random variable as n. Now X N is the sum of N independent random variables {ξ i } i N taking the value + with probability /2 and otherwise. This means E[ξ i ] = /2 and var[ξ i ] = /4 so that by the Central Limit Theorem, the distribution of the random variable (2X N N)/ N converges to that of a

normal random variable with mean zero and variance one. In other words, as δt gets smaller (and so N gets larger), the distribution of S t converges to that of a lognormal distribution. More precisely, in the limit, log S t is normally distributed with mean log S + vt and variance σ 2 t. This is what happens under the original measure P. What happens under the martingale measure, Q, that we use for pricing? Under the martingale measure, the probability of an up jump is q = exp(rδt) exp(vδt σ δt) exp(vδt + σ δt) exp(vδt σ δt) which is approximately 2 ( δt( v + 2 σ2 r )). σ So under the martingale measure, Q, X N is still binomially distributed, but now has mean Nq and variance Nq( q). Thus, under Q, (2X N N)/ N has mean that tends to t(v + 2 σ2 r)/σ and variance that approaches one as δt tends to zero. Again using the Central Limit Theorem the random variable (2X N N)/ N converges to a normally distributed random variable, with mean t(v+ 2 σ2 r)/σ and variance one. Under Q then, S t is lognormally distributed with mean log S + (r 2 σ2 )t and variance σ 2 t. This can be written S t = exp(σ tz + (r 2 σ2 )t). where, under Q, the random variable Z is normally distributed with mean zero and variance one. If our discrete theory carries over to the continuous limit, then in our continuous model the price at time zero of a European call option with strike price K at time T will be the discounted expected value of the claim under the martingale measure, that is E Q [e rt (S T K) + ] where r is the riskless rate. Substituting, we obtain E Q [(S exp(σ T Z 2 σ2 T ) Kexp( rt )) + ]. We ll derive this pricing formula rigorously later and we will also show that this equation can be evaluated as S Φ( log S K + (r + 2 σ2 )T σ ) Ke rt Φ( log S K + (r 2 σ2 )T T σ ) T where Φ is the standard normal distribution function, Φ(z) = Q[Z z] = 2 z 2π e x2 /2 dx

The Girsanov Theorem In order to price and hedge in the Black-Scholes framework we shall need two fundamental results. The first will allow us to change probability measure so that the discounted asset prices are martingales. Recall that in our discrete time world, once we had such a martingale measure, the pricing of options was reduced to calculating expectations under that measure. In the continuous world it will no longer be possible to find the martingale measure by linear algebra. Nonetheless, before stating the continuous time result, we revert to our binomial trees for guidance. Suppose that, under the probability measure P, if the value of an asset at time iδt is known to be S i then its value at time (i + )δt is S i u with probability p and it is S i d with probability p. As we saw before, if we let Q be the probability measure under which the probability of an up jump is q = ( d)/(u d) and of a down jump is (u )(u d), then the process {S i } i N is a Q martingale. We can regard the measure Q as a reweighting of the measure P. For example, consider a path S, S,..., S i through the tree. Its probability under P is p N(i) ( p) i N(i), where N(i) is the number of up jumps that the path makes. Under Q its probability is L i p N(i) ( p) i N(i) where L i = ( q p )N(i) ( q p )i N(i). Evidently L i depends on the path that the stochastic process takes through the tree and can itself be thought of as a stochastic process adapted to the filtration {F i } i N. Moreover, L i /L i is q/p if S i /S i = u and is ( q)/( p) if S i /S i = d, so that E P [L i F i ] = L i (p q p + ( p) q p ) = L i. In other words, {L i } i N is a (P, {F i } i N ) martingale with E[L i ] = L =. If we wish to calculate the expected value of a claim in the Q-measure, it is given by E Q [C] = E P [L N C]. Notation: We have obtained the Radon-Nikodym derivative of Q with respect to P. It is customary to write L i = dq dp F i. We have shown that the process of changing to the martingale measure can be viewed as a reweighting of the probabilities of paths under our original measure P according to a positive, mean one, P-martingale. This procedure of reweighting according to a positive martingale can be extended to the continuous setting. Our aim now is to investigate the effect of such a reweighting on the distribution of the P-Brownian motion. Later this will enable us to choose the right reweighting so that under the new measure obtained in this way the discounted stock price is a martingale. 3

Theorem(Girsanov s Theorem) Suppose that {W t } t is a P Brownian motion with the natural filtration {F t } t and that {θ t } t is an {F t } t -adapted process such that. E[exp( 2 T θ 2 t dt)] < Define L t = exp( θ s dw s 2 and let P (L) be the probability measure defined by P (L) [A] = L t (ω)p(dω). A θ 2 sds) Then under the probability measure P (L), the process {W (L) t } t T, defined by is a standard Brownian motion. W (L) t = W t + θ s ds, Notation: We write dp (L) dp F i = L t. (L t is the Radon-Nikodym derivative of P (L) with respect to P.) Remark. The condition E[exp( 2 T θ 2 t dt)] <, known as Novikov s condition, is enough to guarantee that {L t } t is a (P, {F t } t )-martingale. Since L t is clearly positive and has expectation one, P (L) really does define a probability measure. 2. Just as in the discrete world, two probability measures are equivalent if they have the same sets of probability zero. Evidently P and P (L) are equivalent. 3. If we wish to calculate an expectation with respect to P (L) we have E P(L) [φ t ] = E[φ t L t ]. Moreover generally, E P(L) [φ t F s ] = E P [φ t L t L s F s ]. 4

This will e fundamental in option pricing. Example Let {X t } t be the drifting Brownian motion process X t = σw t + µt, where {W t } t is a P-Brownian motion and σ and µ are constants. Find a measure under which {X t } t is a martingale. 5