The Black Model and the Pricing of Options on Assets, Futures and Interest Rates. Richard Stapleton, Guenter Franke

Similar documents
The Libor Market Model: A Recombining Binomial Tree Methodology. Sandra Derrick, Daniel J. Stapleton and Richard C. Stapleton

1 Interest Based Instruments

Martingale Methods in Financial Modelling

Martingale Methods in Financial Modelling

Market interest-rate models

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Term Structure Lattice Models

Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates. Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles

Things You Have To Have Heard About (In Double-Quick Time) The LIBOR market model: Björk 27. Swaption pricing too.

Vanilla interest rate options

Interest Rate Modeling

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

************************

L 2 -theoretical study of the relation between the LIBOR market model and the HJM model Takashi Yasuoka

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

European call option with inflation-linked strike

A NOVEL BINOMIAL TREE APPROACH TO CALCULATE COLLATERAL AMOUNT FOR AN OPTION WITH CREDIT RISK

INTEREST RATES AND FX MODELS

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Crashcourse Interest Rate Models

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

Fixed Income and Risk Management

Asset Allocation Given Non-Market Wealth and Rollover Risks.

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

Abstract The Term Structure of Interest-Rate Futures Prices We derive general properties of two-factor models of the term structure of interest rates

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

The Pricing of Bermudan Swaptions by Simulation

Abstract The Valuation of Caps, Floors and Swaptions in a Multi-Factor Spot-Rate Model. We build a multi-factor, no-arbitrage model of the term struct

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Pricing Interest Rate Options with the Black Futures Option Model

Managing the Risk of Variable Annuities: a Decomposition Methodology Presentation to the Q Group. Thomas S. Y. Ho Blessing Mudavanhu.

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

INTEREST RATES AND FX MODELS

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Fixed Income Modelling

M339W/389W Financial Mathematics for Actuarial Applications University of Texas at Austin Sample In-Term Exam I Instructor: Milica Čudina

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Libor Market Model Version 1.0

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Chapter 24 Interest Rate Models

FIXED INCOME SECURITIES

FINANCIAL DERIVATIVE. INVESTMENTS An Introduction to Structured Products. Richard D. Bateson. Imperial College Press. University College London, UK

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING

In this appendix, we look at how to measure and forecast yield volatility.

Swaptions. Product nature

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff

Valuation of Caps and Swaptions under a Stochastic String Model

Amortizing and Accreting Caps and Floors Vaulation

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

INTEREST RATES AND FX MODELS

Pricing and Hedging Interest Rate Options: Evidence from Cap-Floor Markets

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

UNIFORM BOUNDS FOR BLACK SCHOLES IMPLIED VOLATILITY

Where would the EUR/CHF exchange rate be without the SNB s minimum exchange rate policy?

Background Risk and Trading in a Full-Information Rational Expectations Economy

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Abstract The Valuation of American-style Swaptions in a Two-factor Spot-Futures Model. We build a no-arbitrage model of the term structure of interest

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

The Black-Scholes Model

SYLLABUS. IEOR E4728 Topics in Quantitative Finance: Inflation Derivatives

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS

Yield to maturity modelling and a Monte Carlo Technique for pricing Derivatives on Constant Maturity Treasury (CMT) and Derivatives on forward Bonds

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE 2 (2) TRUE FALSE. MULTIPLE CHOICE 1 (5) a b c d e 3 (2) TRUE FALSE 4 (2) TRUE FALSE. 2 (5) a b c d e 5 (2) TRUE FALSE

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Financial Derivatives Section 5

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Quantitative Finance and Investment Core Exam

M339W/M389W Financial Mathematics for Actuarial Applications University of Texas at Austin In-Term Exam I Instructor: Milica Čudina

Callable Libor exotic products. Ismail Laachir. March 1, 2012

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

25. Interest rates models. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Interest Rate Floors and Vaulation

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Minimax Asset Price Bounds in Incomplete Markets

Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Math 623 (IOE 623), Winter 2008: Final exam

INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS. Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Interest Rate Caps and Vaulation

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

King s College London

Transcription:

The Black Model and the Pricing of Options on Assets, Futures and Interest Rates Richard Stapleton, Guenter Franke September 23, 2005

Abstract The Black Model and the Pricing of Options We establish a general necessary and sufficient for the Black model to correctly price, to underprice, or to overprice European-style options. The condition for the Black model to hold is that the product of the asset price probability distribution and the pricing kernel is lognormal. This condition is applied to value stock options in particular cases where the pricing kernel exhibits declining or increasing elasticity, options on bonds where bond prices are lognormal, and options on interest rates where interest rates follow a Miltersen, Sandmann and Sondermann (1997)-Brace, Gatarek and Musiela (1997) process. We show that the Libor Market Model is just a special case of this class of Black models.

The Black Model 1 1 Introduction The Black model is used in many different forms in option pricing. It is used in different forms for pricing and hedging stock options, index futures options, foreign exchange options and interest-rate options of various kinds. This is in spite of the fact that the assumptions normally used to establish the model: that the price of the underlying security follows a geometric Brownian motion and interest rates are non-stochastic are somewhat strong and hard to justify, and in some cases mutually inconsistent 1. In this paper, we establish a necessary and sufficient condition for the Black model to correctly price European-style options. We then derive a new set of sufficient conditions under which the Black model holds. In the important special case of interest-rate options, we show conditions under which the Black model will correctly price options on bonds, interest rates and interest rate futures. Although our main concern is to analyse the conditions for the Black model to hold in the case of individual options, a related question is when will the Black model price a series of options with different maturities. This is the question addressed by Brace, Gatarek and Musiela (1997) (BGM) and Miltersen, Sandmann and Sondermann (1997) (MSS). The MSS-BGM Libor Market Model is a model of the stochastic evolution of interest rates in which interest-rate options of all maturities are priced by the Black model. The conditions for the Black model to hold in this sense are more demanding because the interest rate plays a dual role: in the payoff function of the option and also as a discount factor, discounting option payoffs back from the maturity of the option to the valuation date. The outline of this paper is as follows. In section 2 we derive the necessary and sufficient conditions for the Black model to hold for the forward price of an option. The product of the probability distribution function and the (asset specific) pricing kernel has to be lognormal. In section 3, by way of example we illustrate the point that neither the asset or the pring kernel need be lognormal. In section 4, we extend the analysis by considering option valuation given stochastic interest rates. This allows us to analyse the Black model in the context of futures prices of options and also to find conditions for the Black model to price bond options and interest-rate options. These are analysed in section 5. In section 6, we look in detail at the Libor Market Model and show that the model is consistent with the Black model for the pricing of interesst-rate caps and floors. 1 For example, Hull s proof of the Black model in the case of interest-rate futures options assumes that interest rates are non-stochastic.

The Black Model 2 2 Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for the Black Model We consider the valuation of European-style options, with maturity date T, paying c(x T ), which depend on an underlying security whose payoff is x T. The security could be an asset with price x T, or a foreign exchange rate, a futures price or an interest rate. We assume a no-arbitrage economy in which there exists a positive stochastic discount factor, ψ t,t, that prices all claims. The spot price of the option, at time t, is For convenience, we now define a variable φ t,t (x T ): c t = E[c(x T )ψ t,t ]. (1) φ t,t (x T ) E t [ψ t,t x T ]/B t,t, where B t,t is the price of a risk-free zero-coupon bond paying $1 at date T. We refer to this security specific pricing function φ t,t (x T ) simply as the pricing kernel. φ t,t (x T ) has the property E[φ t,t (x T )] = 1. Using this pricing kernel, the forward price of the option is given by F (c) =E t [c(x T )φ t,t (x T )]. (2) If the option is a call option with strike price k, we denote its forward price as F [c(k)]. In this case, (2) becomes The Black model for such a call option is F (x) ln F [c(k)] = F (x)n k σ x T t F [c(k)] = E t [max(x T k, 0)φ t,t (x T )]. (3) + σ2 x (T t) 2 kn ln F (x) k σ2 x (T t) 2 σ x T t, (4) where F (x) is the forward price of x T, σ x is the volatility of x T, and T t is the maturity of the option in years. Now, let f(x T ) be the probability distribution function of x T. We establish the following: Lemma 1 [A Necessary and Sufficient Condition for the Black Model] The Black model holds for the valuation of European-style options on x T if and only if the risk adjusted probability distribution of x T : ˆf(x T )=f(x T )φ t,t (x T ) is lognormal.

The Black Model 3 Proof: For sufficiency, see Poon and Stapleton, pp. 47-49. Necessity follows from the fact that all call options (for all k) have to be priced by Black. This can only be true if the risk-neutral distribution is lognormal. [A more formal proof is required here] The significance of the lemma is that it shows that neither f(x T ) lognormal or φ t,t (x T ) lognormal is necessary for Black. Only the product of f(x T ) and φ t,t (x T ) has to be lognormal. Of course, in many treatments, f(x T ) lognormal is assumed, so that φ t,t (x T ) lognormal is necessary. This is the case in Brennan (1979) and Poon and Stapleton, ch. 3. 3 An Example: the Generalized Lognormal Distribution In this section we simplify the notation, using x x T example, assume a distribution of the form and φ(x) φ t,t (x T ). By way of f(x) =a(q 1,q 2 )g 2 (x)e q 1 ln x+q 2 k 2 (x), (5) where g 2 (x) is not dependent on q 1 and q 2 and q 2 0 and where k(x) is declining in x. This generalization of the lognormal distribution was used by Franke, Huang and Stapleton (2005)(FHS) who show that a two-dimensional risk-neutral valuation relationship holds in this case if the pricing kernel is of the form: φ(x) =b(γ 1,γ 2 )e γ 1 ln x+γ 2 k 2 (x). (6) They also show that a one-dimensional risk-neutral valuation relationship does not hold in this case. However, as noted above, this does not imply that the Black model does not hold as the following Proposition shows: Proposition 1 Assume the probability distribution function is given by (5) and the pricing kernel has the form (6). Then the Black model underprices (correctly prices) [overprices] European-style options if and only if γ 2 < (=)[>] q 2 Proof: ˆf(x) = φ(x)f(x) = a(q 1,q 2 )b(γ 1,γ 2 )g 2 (x)e (γ 1+q 1 )lnx+(γ 2 +q 2 )k 2 (x) = â(q 1 + γ 1,q 2 + γ 2 )g 2 (x)e (γ 1+q 1 )lnx+(γ 2 +q 2 )k 2 (x). (7)

The Black Model 4 If q 2 +γ 2 =0, ˆf(x) is lognormal and by Lemma 1, the Black model holds. If q 2 +γ 2 > 0, the risk-neutral density has declining elasticity and by FSS (1999) all options are underpriced by the Black model. Conversly, if q 2 + γ 2 < 0, the risk-neutral density has increasing elasticity and all options are overpriced by the Black model. Note that, although the Black model holds, a one-dimensional risk-neutral valuation relationship does not hold in this case, since under risk neutrality, ˆf(x) is given by (5) and Black does not hold, if q 2 0. An Example Suppose that k 2 (x) =1/x, which implies that the pricing kernel has declining elasticity. We have φ(x) =be γ 1 ln x e 1 x, assuming γ 2 = 1. Then the Black model holds if q 2 = 1, that is if f(x) =ag 2 (x)e q 1 ln x e 1 x. 4 Option Pricing Under Stochastic Interest Rates So far, we have analysed the conditions for the Black model using the forward pricing kernel, φ t,t (x T ). However, using φ t,t (x T ) tends to obscure two effects, that of risk aversion and of stochastic interest rates, on option pricing. Distinguishing these effects is particularly important for the pricing of interest-rate options. It is also crucial when considering the futures prices of options. In order to analyse the valuation of options under stochastic interest rates, divide the interval from t to T into δ-length sub-periods, with end periods t +1, t + 2,..., T. Let the one-period Libor interest rate be i τ, for τ = t, t +1,t+2,..., T 1, with the one-period zero-coupon bond price 1 B τ =. 1+δi τ From no-arbitrage, there exist pricing functions, γ τ, such that the price of an option at time τ is c τ = E τ [γ τ+1 c τ+1 ]B τ Using these pricing functions, the value of the option at time t is, from successive substitution, c t = E t [γ t,t g t,t c(x T )]B t,τ, (8)

The Black Model 5 where and γ t,t = g t,t = T 1 τ=t T 1 γ τ+1 τ=t B τ /B t,t. Comparing the pricing equations (8) and (1) it follows that the stochastic discount factor in (1) is ψ t,t = γ t,t g t,t B t,t. (9) (9) is merely a decomposition of the discount factor, which reveals the effects of risk aversion and stochastic interest rates. For example, if interest rates are non-stochastic, g t,t B t,t =1 and ψ t,t = γ t,t. Alternatively, if investors are (locally) risk neutral, γ t,t = 1 and ψ t,t = g t,t B t,t. Using the definition of the pricing kernel, φ t,t (x T )=E t [γ t,t g t,t x T ]. Hence, from Lemma 1, the Black model holds for the forward price of the option if and only if ˆf(x) =f(x)e t [γ t,t g t,t x T ] is lognormal. If interest rates are non-stochastic, g t,t = 1 and the condition becomes ˆf(x) =f(x)e t [γ t,t x T ] is lognormal. On the other hand, if investors are (locally) risk neutral, γ t,t = 1 and the condition is ˆf(x) =f(x)e t [g t,t x T ] is lognormal. We can now distinguish the forward price and the futures price of an option. We have: Lemma 2 [Option Prices under Stochastic Interest Rates] The no-arbitrage forward price of an option paying c(x T ) under stochastic interest rates is F (c) =E t [c(x T )γ t,t g t,t ]. The no-arbitrage futures price of the option is H(c) =E t [c(x T )γ t,t ]. Proof The forward price was established above. The futures price, assuming that the futures is marked to market at δ intervals, is just the risk adjusted expectation of the option payoff, see for example Poon and Stapleton, ch 6.

The Black Model 6 The Black model for the futures price of a call option is H(x) ln H[c(k)] = H(x)N k + σ2 x (T t) 2 kn σ x T t ln H(x) k σ2 x (T t) 2 σ x T t where H(x) is the futures price of x T. It now follows, by analogy with Lemma 1:, (10) Lemma 3 [A Necessary and Sufficient Condition for the Black Model (Futures)] The Black model holds for the futures value of European-style options on x T if and only if the probability distribution of x T : is lognormal. ˆf(x T )=f(x T )E t [γ t,t x T ] Proof: 5 The Pricing of Interest-Rate Related Options One of the most important applications of the Black model is in the area of interest-rate options. The Black model has been employed to price bond options, swaptions, Eurodolar futures options, and interest-rate caps and floors. In this section we apply the results derived in the previous section to find the conditions under which the Black model applies to these options. We work under the assumption of (local) risk neutrality. We have:

The Black Model 7 Proposition 2 [The Black model for Interest-Rate Options, under (local) Risk-Neutrality] Consider the pricing of options paying c(x T ) assuming γ t,t =1. Then 1. Bond Options: x T = B c T,T+n (a) The Black model holds for the futures price of the option iff the bond price distribution f(bt,t+n c ) is lognormal. (b) The Black model holds for the forward price of the option iff the bond price distribution ˆf(BT,T+n c )=f(bc T,T+n )E t[g t,t x T ] is lognormal. 2. Interest-Rate Options: x T = i T (a) The Black model holds for the futures price of the option iff the interest-rate distribution f(i T ) is lognormal. (b) The Black model holds for the forward price of the option iff the interest-rate distribution ˆf(i T )=f(i T )E t [g t,t x T ] is lognormal. is lognormal. Proof: 1. (a) From Lemma 2 the futures price of the option is H(c) =E t [c(x T )γ t,t ]. With x T = BT,T+n c and γ t,t = 1, the result follows using Lemma 3. (b) Similarly, again using Lemma 2, the forward price of the option is F (c) =E t [c(x T )γ t,t g t,t ]. With x T = BT,T+n c and γ t,t = 1, the result follows using Lemma 1. 2. (a) From Lemma 2 the futures price of the option is H(c) =E t [c(x T )γ t,t ]. With x T = i T and γ t,t = 1, the result follows using Lemma 3. (b) Similarly, again using Lemma 2, the forward price of the option is F (c) =E t [c(x T )γ t,t g t,t ]. With x T = i T and γ t,t = 1, the result follows using Lemma 1.

The Black Model 8 Applications 1. Options on Eurodollar Futures These are traded in London on a futures (marked-to-market) basis. Although they are American-style, their value can be approximated by assuming that they pay off on a European-style basis. Assuming also that the maturity of the underlying futures is the same as the option maturity, the payoff on a put option is Amax(K H T,T, 0) = A max(i T k, 0) Here, the Black model applies, if f(i T ) is lognormal. Note that this is the case in the Black-Karasinski model. 2. Interest-Rate Caps and Floors: Bond Prices Lognormal An interest-rate cap (floor) can be decomposed into a series of caplets (floorlets) each of which is equivalent to a put option at par on a particular coupon bond 2. The payoff on a caplet is ( caplet T = max 1 1+δk ) 1+δi T In this case, the Black model can be applied if the bond price B c T,T+δ = 1+δk 1+δi T is lognormal and the discount factor g t,t is also lognormal. Note that this is the case in the Ho-Lee and Hull-White models. 3. Interest-Rate Caps and Floors: Interest Rates Lognormal Let x T = i T. The Black model (forward version) holds for the valuation of a caplet if ˆf(i T ) is lognormal. This is the case in the MSS-BGM model. Note this must be the case, but it needs a proof. 2 See Stapleton and Subrahmanyam (1991) for a detailed analysis of caps and floors. MSS (1997) also use this characterization of these products.

The Black Model 9 6 The Black Model in a Multi-Period Economy Lemma 4 [The Black Model for a Series of Options] Consider an n-period economy where each period is length δ. Assume local risk neutrality. Suppose there exist options on an underlying security with payoffs c(x t+jδ ) for j =1, 2,..., n. Then, the Black model holds: 1. For the forward price of c(x t+δ ) iff f(i t+δ ) is lognormal. 2. For the forward price of c(x t+2δ ) iff f(i t+δ )E t (g t,t+2δ x T ) is lognormal. 3. For the forward price of c(x t+jδ ) iff f(i t+δ )E t (g t,t+jδ x T ) is lognormal. Proof Follows directly from Lemma 1. Proposition 3 [The Libor Market Model in a Two-Period Economy] Let x t+δ = i t+δ, and x t+2δ = i t+2δ. Then the Black (forward) model holds simultaneously for options paying c(i t+δ ) and c(i t+2δ ) iff both 1. f(i t+δ ) is lognormal, and 2. [ ] 1 B t,t+δ ˆf(i t+2δ )=f(i t+2δ ) 1+δi t+δ B t,t+δ is lognormal. Proof: 1. follows directly from Lemma 4 above. The term in brackets is the stochastic discount factor, g t,t+2δ. In the case of an interest-rate process the value of this is known given i T, hence 2. follows.

The Black Model 10 References Bernardo, A.F. and O. Ledoit, (2000) Gain, Loss and Asset Pricing, Journal of Political Economy, 108, 144-172. Brennan, M. J., (1979) The Pricing of Contingent Claims in Discrete Time Models, Journal of Finance 34, 53-68. Black, F., and M. Scholes, (1973) The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637-654. Cochrane, J.H. and J. Saa-Requejo, (2000) Beyond Arbitrage: Good-Deal Asset Price Bounds in Incomplete Markets, Journal of Political Economy, 108, 79-119. Huang, J., Franke, G. and R. C. Stapleton, (2005) Two-Dimensional Risk-Neutral Valuation Relationships for the Pricing of Options., working paper Franke, G., R. C. Stapleton, and M. G. Subrahmanyam, (1999) When are options overpriced?: The Black-Scholes Model and Alternative Characterisations of the Pricing Kernel, European Finance Review, 3, 79-102. Heston, S. L., (1993) Invisible Parameters in Option Prices, Journal of Finance 48, 933-947. Brace, A., D. Gatarek, and M. Musiela, (1997), The Market Model of Interest Rate Dynamics, Mathematical Finance, 7, 127 155. Ho, T.S.Y., and S.B. Lee (1986), Term Structure Movements and Pricing of Interest Rate Claims, Journal of Finance, 41, December, 1011 1029. Hull J., Options, Futures and Other Derivative Securities, 5th Edition, 2003 Hull, J., and A. White (1994), Numerical Procedures for Implementing Term Structure Models II: Two-Factor Models, Journal of Derivatives, 2, 37 48. Hull, J., and A. White (2000), Forward Rate Volatilities, Swap Rate Volatilities and the Implementation of the Libor Market Model, Working Paper, University of Toronto. Miltersen, K.R., K. Sandmann and D. Sondermann (1997), Closed Form Solutions for Term Structure Derivatives with Log-Normal Interest Rates, Journal of Finance, 1, 409 430.