Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Similar documents
Insurers call the change in behavior that occurs when a person becomes

Health Insurance Part 2. Health Policy Eric Jacobson

Insurance and the Demand for Medical Care

Arrow s theorem of the deductible: moral hazard and stop-loss in health insurance

Arrow s theorem of the deductible: moral hazard and stop-loss in health insurance

THE ECONOMICS Or MO~RA.L HAZARD-~ FURTHIER COr N. Joseph P. NewtLause sind Vincent D. Taylor. April 1969 I MA I. aulo~ ' 4f,,n -- 1L064

RISK POOLING IN THE PRESENCE OF MORAL HAZARD

The Influence of Premium Subsidies on Moral Hazard in Insurance Contracts

RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS

Moral Hazard. Question for this section. Quick review of demand curves. ECON Fall 2007

SEPARATION OF THE REDISTRIBUTIVE AND ALLOCATIVE FUNCTIONS OF GOVERNMENT. A public choice perspective

Optimal Risk Adjustment. Jacob Glazer Professor Tel Aviv University. Thomas G. McGuire Professor Harvard University. Contact information:

Moral Hazard and Health Insurance when Treatment is Preventive

Public spending on health care: how are different criteria related? a second opinion

Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft Excel/SPSS Chapter 6 The Normal Distribution And Other Continuous Distributions

The Duration Derby: A Comparison of Duration Based Strategies in Asset Liability Management

KEY WORDS: Microsimulation, Validation, Health Care Reform, Expenditures

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998

A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

The duration derby : a comparison of duration based strategies in asset liability management

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SOCIAL VERSUS THE PRIVATE INCENTIVE TO BRING SUIT IN A COSTLY LEGAL SYSTEM. Steven Shavell. Working Paper No.

Summary An issue in the development of the new health care reform plan is the effect on small business. One concern is the effect of a pay or play man

CASH FLOWS OF INVESTMENT PROJECTS A MANAGERIAL APPROACH

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Perfect competition and intra-industry trade

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. (2) the individual market for health insurance does a poor job of pooling risk ;

Copenhagen Consensus 2008 Perspective Paper. Global Warming

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States

This essay on the topic of risk-neutral pricing is the first of two essays that

The Economics of Public Policy 11. Tax Incidence and the Excess Burden of Taxation

On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Spurious Deadweight Gains

Kevin Dowd, Measuring Market Risk, 2nd Edition

Adverse Selection and Switching Costs in Health Insurance Markets. by Benjamin Handel

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

The relevance and the limits of the Arrow-Lind Theorem. Luc Baumstark University of Lyon. Christian Gollier Toulouse School of Economics.

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

Seeking ALPHA - (C) 2007 Kingdom Venture Partners by Sherman Muller, MBA

Econ 230B Spring FINAL EXAM: Solutions

Policy Considerations in Annuitizing Individual Pension Accounts

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Education Finance and Imperfections in Information

Public Good Provision Rules and Income Distribution: Some General Equilibrium Calculations

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Public Sector Discount Rates for Cost Benefit Analysis

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Balancing the Goals of Health Care Provision

Patient Cost Sharing in Low Income Populations

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

Running Head: The Value of Human Life 1. The Value of Human Life William Dare The University of Akron

Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Limited

How Does The Employer Contribution For The Federal Employees Health Benefits Program Influence Plan Selection?

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

A SIMPLE SOLUTION TO CHINA S PENSION CRISIS David D. Li and Ling Li

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY SCHREYER HONORS COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE

Interest Rate Risk in a Negative Yielding World

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

Lecture 3 ( 3): April 20 and 22, 2004 Demand, Supply, and Price Stiglitz: pp

Should Households Establish Emergency Funds?

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

OVERHEAD COST IN CONSTRUCTION INDUSTRY

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

Econ 698s: Lecture Notes Introduction to the Economic Analysis of Social Insurance Professor John Rust

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

Chapter 16. Universal Service

1 The Terrace, PO Box 3724, Wellington 6140 Tel: (04)

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

ECONOMICS INTERACTIONS WITH OTHER DISCIPLINES Vol. I - Sources of Health Care Funding Throughout the Globe - Stephen P. Neun

Module 10. Lecture 37

OBAMACARE S TAX ON MEDICAL DEVICES:

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

What s wrong with infinity A note on Weitzman s dismal theorem

Microeconomics : Policy. Reading assignment Nov 7

Article from. In the Public Interest. January 2016 Issue 12

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate

The Zero Lower Bound

Modelling catastrophic risk in international equity markets: An extreme value approach. JOHN COTTER University College Dublin

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

14.41 Final Exam Jonathan Gruber. True/False/Uncertain (95% of credit based on explanation; 5 minutes each)

Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan Independent Study Project Report

Slide 3: What are Policy Analysis and Policy Options Analysis?

HEALTH. CHARLES E. PHELPS University of Rochester PEARSON

Management Options, Control, and Liquidity

Covered California s Review of CMS s Analysis of the 2018 Open-Enrollment Period

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

$1,000 1 ( ) $2,500 2,500 $2,000 (1 ) (1 + r) 2,000

Bonus-malus systems 6.1 INTRODUCTION

Transcription:

Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman Åke Blomqvist Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario, London, ON, Canada N6A 5C2 Received 1 April 2000; accepted 3 May 2000 Keywords: Moral hazard; Health insurance; Degree of insurance coverage; Optimal degree of insurance In a recent paper, John Nyman (Nyman, 1999b) revisits an issue that has been central to much of the literature in health economics in recent years, namely the trade-off between the gains from insurance, on the one hand, and the efficiency losses from the moral hazard effect that arises as a result of the implicit subsidy to health services utilization under conventional insurance plans, on the other. Specifically, he argues that in the existing literature, the significance of the latter has been exaggerated, while conventional approaches tend to understate the importance of the former. The result, according to Nyman, has been a tendency in the health policy debate to put too much emphasis on insurance plan features such as consumer cost sharing and provisions to control utilization in managed-care plans. Although several of Nyman s criticisms of conventional methodology are correct and valid, in this comment, I will attempt to show that they are largely irrelevant to the question that has been the focus of the literature on health insurance ever since the seminal paper by Zeckhauser (1970), namely that of the optimal degree of demand-side cost sharing. The reason is that, implicitly, Nyman s paper addresses the issues of what would happen if conventional approaches would be applied to the problem of estimating the net gains from insurance against the alternative of no insurance at all. Most of the recent literature in this area, in contrast, has concerned a question at the margin: For a Tel.: +1-519-661-2111, ext. 85204; fax: +1-519-661-3666. E-mail address: akeb@julian.uwo.ca (Å. Blomqvist). 0167-6296/01/$ see front matter 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0167-6296(00)00058-8

284 Å. Blomqvist / Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 given degree of insurance protection, would consumers be better off with a somewhat higher (or lower) degree of insurance? By extension, what is the optimal degree of insurance protection? As I will show below, the potential biases that Nyman points to in existing approaches are not of major significance to the recent literature on these issues. The distinction between the total and marginal gains from insurance is analogous to that which is made in the public finance literature between the aggregate and marginal excess burden of a system of distortionary taxation. Earlier literature tried to estimate the total (or average) excess burden. More recently, however, the focus has been on the marginal excess burden: Since every society requires at least some government spending, and since non-distortionary taxation is not feasible, the relevant issue is the balance between the benefits of public spending and the real cost of public funds at the margin. The logic with respect to health insurance is similar. For example, if access to certain kinds of very costly but vitally necessary health services can be guaranteed through payment of a small insurance premium, it obviously makes sense for a risk-averse individual to have a contract that accomplishes this. However, for less serious illness and less costly health services (which the individual could afford to pay for even if their insurance did not cover them), and for which the insurance premium would be relatively high because they are used frequently, the issue is less clear. It is the question where to draw the line in this regard that has been the focus of the post-zeckhauser literature. One of the principal points in Nyman s paper is that the conventional approach underestimates the gains from insurance because it fails to take into account what can be termed the affordability effect: that certain interventions are so costly that, in the absence of insurance, the individual would have to go without them, even if they potentially would have very large health benefits (in the limit, they may be necessary for the individual s survival). To what extent is this argument relevant to the question of what constitutes an optimal degree of insurance coverage? The answer depends in part on how the latter concept is defined. In Zeckhauser s paper (Zeckhauser, 1970), the degree of insurance coverage was defined by a single, constant, co-insurance parameter specifying what fraction of total health care costs would be paid by the patient out of pocket. If insurance is defined in this way, the affordability motive may have considerable relevance in the sense that the optimal choice of co-insurance parameter might depend heavily on the benefits from not precluding access to certain very costly but vitally necessary services. 1 However, it has long been recognized that insurance coverage through a constant coinsurance parameter is highly inefficient in comparison with plans that provide a higher level of coverage (a lower co-insurance rate) for large expenditures. This was implicitly allowed for in the design of the Rand Health Insurance Study, the results of which have provided by far the most important empirical basis for the contemporary debate about optimal insurance. While the central component of the study was a comparison of health care spending among individuals and families in insurance plans with different co-insurance rates, all families were subject to a maximum annual expenditure limit which was the lesser of a specified 1 Nyman has explored this issue at length in another paper (Nyman, 1999a).

Å. Blomqvist / Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 285 percentage of the family s income (5%, 10%, or 15%), or US$1000 (equivalent to about US$2500 in 1995 dollars). Since this kind of limit certainly would be lower than what most people would consider a reasonable definition of affordability for urgently needed health services, the potential bias introduced by neglecting the affordability motive is unlikely to be of major significance in comparison with the relative efficiency of the plans in this set, or plans with lower deductibles. 2 With respect to the efficiency loss from moral hazard, Nyman makes an important point regarding the difference between the compensated and Marshallian demand curve when the magnitude of the loss is estimated as an area above a demand curve for (implicitly) subsidized health services. Since empirical estimates typically yield Marshallian demand curves while it is the compensated one that should be the basis for welfare loss estimates, it is important to have an accurate method for accounting for the income effects that give rise to the difference between them when estimating the compensated one from the Marshallian one. According to Nyman, the conventional method for doing this is likely to yield misleading results for the case of health services because of the highly skewed distribution of health expenditures across the population. His point can be simply illustrated by considering a market in which all potential buyers have the same income and in which, on average, consumers spend 5% of their income on the good traded in it. Suppose, however, that the average conceals a very skewed distribution of purchases, so that, for example, 80% of consumers spend nothing on the good, while the remaining 20% spend 1/4 of their income on it. Suppose further that the elasticity of the Marshallian demand curve has been estimated at 0.5, while the income elasticity has been estimated at +1.0. The conventional formula to obtain the elasticity of the individual s compensated demand curve is ε c =ε m +η y s where ε c, ε m, η y and s are the elasticities of the compensated and Marshallian demand curves with respect to price, the income elasticity of demand, and the share of the consumer s budget spent on the commodity in question, respectively. If one wants to apply this formula to the market demand curve, the relevant budget share clearly is that of the 20% minority of the population which purchases health care, not the average share for the population as a whole, so that in the example, the compensated elasticity is 0.5 + 0.25 = 0.25; erroneously using the average budget share of 5% would yield a compensated elasticity of 0.5 + 0.05 = 0.45. Clearly, the logic in this example is applicable to the case of health care. For example, in the Rand study, a substantial proportion of families had no medical expenditure at all in each given year, and for those with some expenditures, the distribution of spending was highly skewed. In calculations based on the price elasticity of demand estimated from the Rand study, Nyman suggests that the true welfare losses from the moral hazard effect may be only a third of the values that result from calculations that do not properly correct for income effects (Nyman 1999b, p. 818). However, while the point is correct in general, it is of limited relevance to the comparison of the relative moral hazard losses in the different plans in the Rand study that have been 2 Manning et al. (1987) are explicit on this point. They note that the results from the Rand study cannot be directly compared with estimates of the welfare loss based on models that represent cost-sharing as a constant co-insurance rate, but make no apologies for this intentional non-comparability; a constant co-insurance rate,..., is not an insurance policy that theory suggests would be optimal.

286 Å. Blomqvist / Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 undertaken in the literature. First, the relevant budget share for the correction would be the share of each family s out-of-pocket spending on health care, not total spending. Under the design of the Rand experiment, the former was never more than the upper limit referred to above. Because the limit was defined as the lesser of 5%, 10%, or 15% of family income or US$1000, it was less than 10% of family income on average 3 and for most families with positive spending it was of course less than the limit. 4 In the example below, I will conservatively set the share variable at 8% of family income. Moreover, Nyman uses an estimate of the income elasticity of demand for health services of 0.38, a number derived from a study based on data for individual tax filers 55 years of age or older. 5 The income elasticities estimated from the Rand experiment itself were generally lower, ranging from + 0.2 to + 0.4 (Newhouse et al., 1993, p. 47). Using the mid-point of +0.3 and an uncompensated price elasticity of demand of 0.186 (corresponding to the arc elasticity of demand in the example used by Manning et al. (1987, p. 270), produces an estimated elasticity of compensated demand of 0.162, or 87% of the uncompensated one (rather than 33%, as in Nyman s example). Moreover, the relation between the elasticities used in Nyman s calculation is based on point elasticities, whereas the price elasticity estimated from the Rand study is an arc elasticity. Taking this into account further reduces the significance of the income effect. To see this, consider the example in Manning et al., (1987, p. 270). In this example, the average annual medical (and dental) expenditure under the free plan (with 0 cost-sharing) are US$1038, while they are US$713 under the 95% cost-sharing plan. The arc elasticity based on these two expenditure levels, at prices of 0 and 0.95, respectively, is 0.186. Taking the free plan as the reference case, how large is the income effect of moving to a 95% plan? Assuming that US$713 represents 8% of the consumer s income, the compensation necessary to leave the consumer as well off as under the free plan would be 0.95 8=7.6% of the consumer s income. With an income elasticity of +0.3, this would lead to an increase in medical expenditure of about 2.3% of US$713, or US$16.4. The welfare loss associated with a price decrease from 0.95 to 0 in using the uncompensated demand curve is US$170.6, (1038 713)(1 (0.95/2)), assuming the demand curve is linear. Accounting for the income effect requires replacing 713 by 730; with this value the welfare loss becomes US$161.7, or 95% of the estimate based on the uncompensated demand curve, again well above the 33% figure that Nyman suggests. 3 Approximately equal number of families were assigned to each percentage limit category, and median income of those enrolled was in the range US$6400 11,800 in 1969 dollars (Newhouse et al., 1993 pp. 16 and 415). By the time the data were collected in second half of the 1970s, these income figures had risen substantially (by more than 80%), reducing the value of the US$1000 limit (which was constant in nominal terms) as a share of income. 4 According to Newhouse et al. (1993, p. 358), 65% of families in the 95% cost-sharing plan (see below) had expenditures less than the upper limit in any given year. 5 The study is done by Feenberg and Skinner (1995). As the authors note, a major item of health care spending for this group is nursing home care, an item for which the income elasticity of demand is likely to be higher than for the kinds of medical expenditure incurred by those in the Rand study (which excluded the elderly). Another reason for the large income effect correction in Nyman s calculation is that as his share parameter he uses the percentage of medical care in personal consumption expenditure (16% in 1997). But this share presumably includes health insurance premiums, an item that is irrelevant to estimating the income effect of changing an insurance plan s co-insurance rate.

Å. Blomqvist / Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 287 The calculations above pertain to what Manning et al. refer to as their minimum estimate of the welfare loss. Their maximum estimate (US$274.6 rather than US$161.7 on average) is derived by assuming that the marginal value of the last unit of health services used under the 95% plan is US$0.31 rather than US$0.95 as assumed in the minimum estimate. The uncertainty regarding which is the correct one arises because some individuals (those that have exceeded their spending limits) under the 95% plan continue to face an effective marginal price of 0 (rather than 0.95) for health services and will therefore utilize services beyond the point where their marginal value corresponds to 0.95. In the minimum estimate, it is implicitly assumed that all individuals who reduce their service use when going from the free plan to the 95% plan do so until the last unit they use has a marginal benefit of 0.95. But this assumption is unlikely to be valid. From the numbers, it is clear that correcting for this effect is likely to be more important quantitatively than correcting for the income effect. The paper by Manning et al. does not directly address the issue, first raised by Feldstein (1973), of the welfare loss from excess health insurance since they do not try to quantify the gains from risk reduction. However, their work is extended by Feldman and Dowd (1991) who incorporate both the moral hazard loss and the gains from risk reduction. They conclude that the Rand study 95% co-insurance plan is superior, from an efficiency point of view, to a free care plan: The estimated gain from the higher degree of insurance under the free care plan is not large enough to offset the increase in the estimated moral hazard loss. Although neither of these papers addresses the question of what would constitute an optimal degree of insurance, given the evidence from the Rand study, that question is explicitly addressed in two other works: Manning and Marquis (1996), and in Newhouse et al. (1993, Chap. 4, pp. 137 139). An interesting issue is why, in the latter study, the conclusion is that the optimal plan involves a higher degree of insurance, both in the form of a lower co-insurance rate and in the form of a lower maximum out-of-pocket cost stop-loss provision, than in the Rand 95% co-insurance plan, in spite of the result in Feldman and Dowd that the reduction in the moral-hazard effect when moving from free care to a 95% co-insurance plan is greater than the estimated cost of increased risk-bearing. The explanation appears to lie in the non-linearity of the estimated demand curve for health services as a function of the co-insurance rate. Although it is based on the same data, the Manning and Marquis paper arrives at a substantially different optimal plan, with both a higher co-insurance rate and a higher maximum expenditure limit. Further analysis of what causes this difference would clearly be of interest. Nyman concludes his paper by suggesting that the moral-hazard loss associated with the implicit subsidy to services utilization under conventional health insurance plans should be regarded as a transactions cost similar to the administration cost of any insurance plan. Implicitly, this is precisely the way that the moral hazard effect has been treated in the papers discussed above: In estimates of the optimal degree of insurance, the marginal moral hazard loss plays a role quite similar to that of administration costs in the conventional analysis of insurance. A well-established result in the insurance literature is that when there are positive administration costs so that actual premiums exceed the actuarially fair levels by some load factor, it is not optimal, even when individuals are risk-averse, to be fully insured against a given loss (see, e.g. Folland et al., 1997, pp. 235 241). The result that the

288 Å. Blomqvist / Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 optimal degree of insurance against the cost of health care should depend on the marginal moral hazard loss is exactly analogous. Nyman is correct in observing that the affordability issue, and the special nature of the income effect in the choice of health insurance, may be important if the purpose is to estimate the gains from some insurance as against the alternative of no insurance at all. However, the results in the recent literature on the issue of the optimal degree of patient cost sharing have been much less affected by the potential biases that may arise from these factors than Nyman s paper suggests. References Feenberg, D., Skinner, J., 1995. The risk and duration of catastrophic health care expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 633 647. Feldman, R., Dowd, B., 1991. A new estimate of the welfare loss of excess health insurance. American Economic Review 81, 297 301. Feldstein, M., 1973. The welfare loss of excess health insurance. Journal of Political Economy 81, 251 280. Folland, S., Goodman, A., Stano, M., 1997. The Economics of Health and Health Care. 2nd edition, Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ. Manning, W., Newhouse, J., Duan, N., Keeler, E., Leibowitz, A., Marquis, S., 1987. Health insurance and the demand for medical care: evidence from a randomized experiment. American Economic Review 77, 251 277. Manning, W., Marquis, S., 1996. Health insurance: the tradeoff between risk pooling and moral hazard. Journal of Health Economics 15, 609 640. Newhouse, J.P., et al. 1993. Free for All? Lessons from the Rand Health Insurance Experiment. Harvard Univ. Press, Cambridge, MA. Nyman, J., 1999a. The value of health insurance: the access motive. Journal of Health Economics 18, 141 152. Nyman, J., 1999b. The economics of moral hazard revisited. Journal of Health Economics 18, 811 824. Zeckhauser, R.J., 1970. Medical insurance: a case study of the tradeoff between risk spreading and appropriate incentives. Journal of Economics Theory 2, 10 26.