EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Similar documents
EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

ECON/MGEC 333 Game Theory And Strategy Problem Set 9 Solutions. Levent Koçkesen January 6, 2011

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies:

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Repeated Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Repeated Games 1 / 48

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games

In reality; some cases of prisoner s dilemma end in cooperation. Game Theory Dr. F. Fatemi Page 219

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Repeated games. Felix Munoz-Garcia. Strategy and Game Theory - Washington State University

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2018

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Warm Up Finitely Repeated Games Infinitely Repeated Games Bayesian Games. Repeated Games

Prisoner s dilemma with T = 1

Solution Problem Set 2

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Eco AS , J. Sandford, spring 2019 March 9, Midterm answers

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30)

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

REPEATED GAMES. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Repeated Games. Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic.

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Game Theory Fall 2003

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Infinitely Repeated Games

Repeated Games. EC202 Lectures IX & X. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures IX & X Jan / 16

Economics 171: Final Exam

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

ECONS STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY QUIZ #3 (SIGNALING GAMES) ANSWER KEY

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Game Theory. Important Instructions

1 Solutions to Homework 4

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

Not 0,4 2,1. i. Show there is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium where player A chooses to play, player A chooses L, and player B chooses L.

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization

Exercise Chapter 10

I. Introduction and definitions

Discounted Stochastic Games with Voluntary Transfers

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Does structure dominate regulation? The case of an input monopolist 1

14.12 Game Theory Midterm II 11/15/ Compute all the subgame perfect equilibria in pure strategies for the following game:

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Econ 711 Final Solutions

Answers to Problem Set 4

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Endogenous Cartel Formation with Differentiated Products and Price Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

MIDTERM ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 395

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Module 3: "Dynamic games of complete information" Lecture 23: "Bertrand Paradox in an Infinitely repeated game" The Lecture Contains:

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Game Theory Fall 2006

Strategic Production Game 1

Economics 431 Infinitely repeated games

Outline for Dynamic Games of Complete Information

Early PD experiments

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Economics 209A Theory and Application of Non-Cooperative Games (Fall 2013) Repeated games OR 8 and 9, and FT 5

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HOMEWORK #7 ANSWER KEY

Solutions to Homework 3

ECON402: Practice Final Exam Solutions

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Transcription:

EconS 44 Strategy and Game Theory Homework #5 Answer Key Exercise #1 Collusion among N doctors Consider an infinitely repeated game, in which there are nn 3 doctors, who have created a partnership. In each period, each doctor decides how hard to work. Let ee tt ii be the effort chosen by doctor i in period t, and ee tt ii = 1,,, 10. Doctor i s discount factor is δδ ii. Total profit for the partnership: (ee tt 1 + ee tt + ee tt 3 + + ee tt nn ) A doctor i s payoff: 1 nn (ee 1 tt + ee tt + ee 3 tt + + ee nn tt ) ee ii tt a. Assume that the history of the game is common knowledge. Derive a subgame perfect NE in which each player chooses effort ee > 1. To begin, note that doctor s payoff can be rearranged to: nn (ee 1 + ee + + ee ii 1 + ee ii+1 + + ee nn ) nn nn ee ii Since a doctor s payoff is strictly decreasing in her own effort, she wants to minimize it. ee ii = 1 is then a strictly dominant strategy for doctor i and therefore there is a unique stage game Nash equilibrium in which each doctor chooses the minimal effort level of 1. Next, note that each doctor s payoff from choosing a common effort level of e is: 1 nn (ee + ee + + ee) ee = 1 nnnn ee = ee nn To determine a doctor s best deviation, we must take a partial derivative with respect to ee ii of their payoff function when all other (n-1) players select e, yielding uu ii = nn ee ii nn which is clearly negative given that nn >. This suggests a corner solution where doctor i wants to minimize effort by playing the lowest possible effort, i.e., e i=1. We can now describe a grim-trigger strategy. When conditions are met and the strategy is played symmetrically, that will guarantee cooperation at an effort level e>1. 1

Consider the symmetric grim-trigger strategy: o o In period 1: choose ee 1 ii = ee In period t : choose ee tt ii = ee when ee ττ jj = ee for all j, for all ττ tt 1; and choose 1 otherwise. This is a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium if and only if ee 1 δδ ii nn 1 nn ee nn nn 1 + δδ ii 1 δδ ii ffffff aaaaaa ii. That is to say, the equilibrium will only hold so long as the payoff from remaining in the equilibrium is greater than or equal to the one period payoff from deviating plus the payoff from the punishment equilibrium played every period thereafter. Solving for δδ ii yields: δδ ii nn (nn 1) The following figure depicts this cutoff of δδ ii, shading the region of discount factors above δδ ii which would support collusion. It is now possible to see how the equilibrium responds to changes in n. Differentiating the about cutoff of δδ ii with respect to n, we obtain

δδ ii = 1 (nn 1) This partial is positive, indicating that as the group size n increases, δδ ii has to increase to maintain the cooperative equilibrium. So it is more difficult to support cooperation as the group size increases. b. Assume that the history of the game is not common knowledge, i.e., in each period, only the total effort is observed. Find a subgame perfect NE in which each player chooses effort ee > 1. Consider the strategy profile in part (a), except that it now conditions on total effort. Let ee tt denote total effort for period t. In period 1: choose ee ii 1 = ee In period t : choose ee ii tt = ee when ee ττ = nnee for all j, for all ττ tt 1; and choose 1 otherwise. This is a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium under the exact same conditions as in part (a). Exercise # - Collusion when firms compete in quantities Consider two firms competing as Cournot oligopolists in a market with demand: pp(qq 1, qq ) = aa bbqq 1 bbqq Both firms have total costs, TTTT(qq ii ) = ccqq ii where c > 0 is the marginal cost of production. a. Considering that firms only interact once (playing an unrepeated Cournot game), find the equilibrium output for every firm, the market price, and the equilibrium profits for every firm. Firm 1 chooses q 1 to solve maxq1 ππ ii = pp(aa bbqq 1 bbqq ) ccqq 1 Taking first order conditions with respect to q1, we find ππ 1 qq 1 = aa bbqq 1 bbqq cc = 0 and solving for q1 we obtain firm 1 s best response function qq 1 (qq ) = bb 1 qq 3

and similarly for firm, since firms are symmetric, qq (qq 1 ) = bb 1 qq 1 Plugging qq (qq 1 ) into qq 1 (qq ), we find firm 1 s equilibrium output: qq 1 = aa bb aa bbqq 1 cc cc bb bb Similarly, firm s equilibrium output is cc aa bb aa cc qq = 3bb = aa bb bb Therefore, the market price is = aa bb aa bbqq 1 cc cc aa + cc = = bb 3bb 3bb cc cc 3aa aa + cc 3cc aa = = 6bb bb 6bb 3bb cc pp = aa bb bb aa 3bb 3bb = 3aa aa + cc aa + cc 3 and the equilibrium profits of each firm are = aa + cc 3 ππ cccccccccccccc 1 = ππ cccccccccccccc aa + cc cc () = cc aa = 3 3bb 3bb 9bb b. Now assume that they could form a cartel. Which is the output that every firm should produce in order to maximize the profits of the cartel? Find the market price, and profits of every firm. Are their profits higher when they form a cartel than when they compete as Cournot oligopolists? Since the cartel seeks to maximize their joint profits, they choose output levels q 1 and q that solve max ππ 1 + ππ = (aa bbqq 1 bbqq )qq 1 ccqq 1 + (aa bbqq 1 bbqq )qq ccqq which simplifies to max (aa bbqq 1 bbqq )(qq 1 + qq ) cc(qq 1 + qq ) Notice that this maximization problem can be further reduced to the choice of aggregate output Q=qq 1 + qq that solves max (aa bbbb)qq cccc 4

Interestingly, this maximization problem coincides with that of a regular monopolist. In other words, the overall production of the cartel of two symmetric firms coincides with that of a standard monopoly. Indeed, taking first order conditions with respect to Q, we obtain aa bbbb cc 0 And solving for Q, we find QQ = aa cc, which is an interior solution given that a>c by definition. bb Therefore, ach firm s output level in the cartel is qq 1 = qq = QQ = bb = And the market price is Therefore, each firm s profits in the cartel are pp = aa bbbb = aa bb bb = aa + cc aa + cc cc cc () ππ 1 = ppqq 1 TTTT(qq 1 ) = aa cc aa = ππ 1 cccccccccccc = ππ cccccccccccc = () Comparing the profits that every firm makes in the cartel, (aa cc), against those under Cournot competition, (aa cc), we can conclude that 9bb ππ 1 cccccccccccc = ππ cccccccccccc > ππ 1 cccccccccccccc = ππ cccccccccccccc c. Can the cartel agreement be supported as the (cooperative) outcome of the infinitely repeated game? 1. First, we find the discounted sum of the infinite stream of profits when firms cooperate in the cartel agreement (they do not deviate). Payoff of cartel when they cooperate is (aa cc) As a consequence, the discounted sum of the infinite stream of profits from cooperating in the cartel is 5

() () + δδ + = 1 () 1 δδ. Second, we need to find the optimal deviation that, conditional on firm choosing the cartel output, maximizes firm 1 s profits. That is, which is the output that maximizes firm 1 s profits, and which are its corresponding profits from deviating? Since firm sticks to cooperation (i.e., produces the cartel output qq = aa cc ), if firm 1 seeks to maximize its current profits (optimal deviation), we only need to plug qq = aa cc response function, as follows qq dddddd 1 qq 1 = bb 1 3() = into firm 1 s best which provides us with firm 1 s optimal deviation, given that firm is still respecting the cartel agreement. In this context, firm 1 s profit is while that of firm is 3() cc) ππ 1 = aa bb bb cc 3(aa cc) = 3 3(aa = 8 9() 6 3() cc ππ = aa bb bb cc aa cc 3() = 3 aa = 8 3bb Hence, firm 1 has incentives to unilaterally deviate since its current profits are larger by deviating (while firm respects the cartel agreement) than by cooperating. That is, ππ 1 dddddddddddddd = 9() 6 > ππ 1 cccccccccccc = () 3. Finally, we can now compare the profits that firms obtain from cooperating in the cartel agreement (part i) with respect to the profits they obtain from choosing an optimal deviation (part ii) plus the profits they would obtain from being punished thereafter (discounted profits in the Cournot oligopoly). In particular, for cooperation to be sustained we need Firm 1: 6

Solving for discount factor δ, we obtain 1 () 9() > + δδ () 1 δδ 6 1 δδ 9bb 1 > 9 + δδ 9, which implies δδ > 8(1 δδ) 64 9(1 δδ) 17 Hence, firms need to assign a sufficiently high value to future payoffs, δδ 9, 1, for the cartel agreement to be sustained. Finally, note that firm has incentives to carry out the punishment. Indeed, if it does not revers to the NE of the stage game (producing the Cournot equilibrium output), firm obtains profits of 3(aa cc) 3bb, since firm 1 keeps producing its optimal deviation of qq 1 dddddd = 3(aa cc) 17 while firm produces the cartel output qq cccccccccccc = aa cc aa cc. If, instead, firm practices the punishment, producing the Cournot output, 3bb its profits are (aa cc) 3(aa cc), which exceed for all parameter values. Hence, upon observing that firm 9bb 3bb 1 deviates, firm prefers to revert to the production of its Cournot output level than being the only firm that produces the cartel output. Exercise #3 Collusion among N firms Consider n firms producing homogenous goods and choosing quantities in each period for an infinite number of periods. Demand in the industry is given by, Q being the sum of individual outputs. All firms in the industry are identical: they have the same constant marginal costs, and the same discount factor. Consider the following trigger strategy: Each firm sets the output that maximizes joint profits at the beginning of the game, and continues to do so unless one or more firms deviate. After a deviation, each firm sets the quantity, which is the Nash equilibrium of the one-shot Cournot game. (a) Find the condition on the discount factor that allows for collusion to be sustained in this industry. First find the quantities that maximize joint profits π = (1 Q) Q cq. It is easily checked 1 c that this output level isq =, yielding profits of 7

ππ = 1 1 cc 1 cc 1 cc (1 cc) cc = 4 for the cartel. m 11 c Therefore, at the symmetric equilibrium individual quantities are q = and n m 1 (1 c) individual profits under the collusive strategy are π =. n 4 As for the deviation profits, the optimal deviation by a firm is given by d m m q ( q ) = argmax q 1 ( n 1) q q q cq. m 11 c where note that all other n-1 firms are still producing their cartel output q =. n It can be checked that the value of q that maximizes the above expression is (1 ) q d ( q m ) = ( n+ 1) c, and that the profits that a firm obtains by deviating from the 4n collusive output are, hence, 11 1 1 1 d 1 ( 1) c ( 1) c n n ( n 1) c π = + cn ( 1) c n 4n + +, 4n 4n which simplifies to d (1 c) ( n+ 1) π = 16n Therefore, collusion can be sustained in equilibrium if 1 m d δ cn π π + π, 1 δ 1 δ (1 + n) which after solving for the discount factor, δ, yieldsδ. For compactness, we 1 + 6n + n (1 + n) cn denote this ratio as δ. 1+ 6n+ n Hence, under punishment strategies that involve a reversion to Cournot equilibrium forever after a deviation takes place, tacit collusion arises if and only if firms are sufficiently patient. cn The following figure depicts cutoff δ, as a function of the number of firms, n, shading the region of δ that exceeds such a cutoff. 8

(b) Indicate how the number of firms in the industry affects the possibility of reaching the tacit collusive outcome. By carrying out a simple exercise of comparative statics using the critical threshold for the discount factor, one concludes that (This could be anticipated from our previous figure, where the critical discount factor increases in n.) Intuition: Other things being equal, as the number of firms in the agreement increases, the more difficult it is to reach and sustain tacit collusion. Since firms are assumed to be symmetric, an increase in the number of firms is equivalent to a lower degree of market concentration. Therefore, lower levels of market concentration are associated ceteris paribus with less likely collusion.. 9