Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Similar documents
Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

Monetary Policy Rules in the Presence of an Occasionally Binding Borrowing Constraint

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Household Leverage, Housing Markets, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Household Leverage, Housing Markets, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

CAPITAL FLOWS AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY IN EMERGING ASIAN ECONOMIES: A DSGE APPROACH α. Nur M. Adhi Purwanto

Structural Reforms in a Debt Overhang

High Leverage and a Great Recession

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

THE ZERO LOWER BOUND, THE DUAL MANDATE,

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

High Leverage and a Great Recession

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Benjamin D. Keen. University of Oklahoma. Alexander W. Richter. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Nathaniel A. Throckmorton. College of William & Mary

Capital Flows, Financial Intermediation and Macroprudential Policies

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

The Interaction between the Basel Regulations and Monetary Policy: Fostering Economic and Financial Stability

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

On the (in)effectiveness of LTV regulation in a multiconstraint framework

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Spillovers, Capital Flows and Prudential Regulation in Small Open Economies

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

Forward Guidance Under Uncertainty

The New Financial Regulation in Basel III and Monetary Policy: A. Macroprudential Approach

Unemployment benets, precautionary savings and demand

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Fiscal Multipliers and Financial Crises

Money and Capital in a persistent Liquidity Trap

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

Does a Currency Union Need a Capital Market Union?

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Basel I, II, and III: A Welfare Analysis using a DSGE Model

Principles of Banking (III): Macroeconomics of Banking (1) Introduction

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

The Real Business Cycle Model

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

The science of monetary policy

Escaping the Great Recession 1

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Housing Market Heterogeneity in a Monetary Union

Credit Booms, Financial Crises and Macroprudential Policy

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

Discussion of Capital Injection to Banks versus Debt Relief to Households

Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions. Enrique G. Mendoza

Household Leverage and the Recession Appendix (not for publication)

Consumption Dynamics, Housing Collateral and Stabilisation Policy

Spillovers: The Role of Prudential Regulation and Monetary Policy in Small Open Economies

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

Land-Price Dynamics and Macroeconomic Fluctuations

The New Keynesian Approach to Monetary Policy Analysis: Lessons and New Directions

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

The Risk of Hitting the Zero Lower Bound and the Optimal Inflation Target

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Inflation Target and its Impact on Macroeconomy in the Zero Lower Bound Environment: the case of the Czech economy

Monetary Policy and the Great Recession

The Zero Lower Bound

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

The Expansionary Lower Bound: A Theory of Contractionary Monetary Easing *

The new Kenesian model

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Leaning Against the Credit Cycle

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

and over the Business Cycle

Asset-price driven business cycle and monetary policy

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Transcription:

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Margarita Rubio 1 Fang Yao 2 1 University of Nottingham 2 Reserve Bank of New Zealand. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand.

Introduction In the post GFC world, there are new challenges to the conduct of macro-financial stabilization policies One of the major changes in this new environment is a significant decline in the neutral interest rate Low neutral rates limit the scope of conventional monetary policy in stabilizing the economy, especially when it hits the ZLB Low interest rates raise concerns about financial imbalances and risks to financial stability

The neutral/natural rate of interest The neutral rate is the interest rate consistent with full employment, trend growth, and stable prices An economy in this state presumably would not need to be stimulated or slowed by monetary policy

Evidence

Macroprudential Policy in a Low Interest-Rate Environment In a low interest-rate environment, the case for using macroprudential policies becomes even stronger Greater financial instability due to low interest rates calls for macroprudential policies to contain financial risks Macropru may also be one of the natural candidates to complement monetary policy in those times in which the instrument of the central bank is restricted

Research Questions Without an active role for macroprudential policy, what are the consequences of a steady-state interest rate falling from 4% to 2% for business and financial cycles? Can macroprudential policy contribute to both financial and macroeconomic stability in the low interest-rate environment?

Overview of the model DSGE with collateral constraints on borrowers and an occasionally binding ZLB for the interest rate Monetary policy in the model is described by a standard Taylor rule, which is subject to an occasionally binding ZLB Macroprudential policy is characterized by a rule on the loan-to-value ratio (LTV) that responds to credit and output We calibrate the model to match a low interest-rate environment by setting the steady-state interest rate equal to 2% We solve the model using the "occbin" toolkit proposed by Guerrieri and Iacoviello (2015)

Summary The economy features patient and impatient households (savers and borrowers) Households work and consume both consumption goods and housing Borrowers are credit constrained and need collateral to obtain loans. The representative firm converts household labor into the final good The central bank follows a Taylor rule for the setting of the interest rate, which is constrained by a lower bound The macroprudential regulator uses the LTV as an instrument for macroprudential policy.

Savers Savers maximize their utility function by choosing consumption, housing and labor hours: max C s,t,h s,t,n s,t E 0 t=0 β t s [log C s,t + j log H s,t (N s,t) η subject to the following budget constraint: η ], C s,t + b t + q t (H s,t H s,t 1 ) = R t 1b t 1 π t + w s,t N s,t + F t

Borrowers Borrowers solve the following optimization problem: max C b,t,h b,t,n b,t E 0 t=0 β t b [log C b,t + j log H b,t (N b,t) η ] where β b (0, 1) is the discount factor for the borrower (β b < β s ), subject to the following budget and collateral constraints: η C b,t + R t 1b t 1 π t + q t (H b,t H b,t 1 ) = b t + W b,t N b,t E t R t π t+1 b t = k t E t q t+1 H b,t

Firms The intermediate goods market is monopolistically competitive: Y t (z) = A t N s,t (z) α N b,t (z) (1 α) A t represents technology and it follows the following autoregressive process: log (A t ) = ρ A log (A t 1 ) + u At Solving the firm s problem we can obtain a standard forward-looking New Keynesian Phillips curve: π t = βe t π t+1 ψ x t + u πt

Equilibrium The market clearing conditions are as follows: Y t = C s,t + C b,t The total supply of housing is fixed and it is normalized to unity: H s,t + H b,t = 1

Monetary Policy We consider a standard Taylor rule which responds to inflation and output, with interest-rate smoothing: ( ( ) ρ Rt TR = Rt 1 TR (π t ) (1+φR π) ( ) ) φ R 1 ρ Yt y R Y We impose a ZLB constraint on the interest rate so that it cannot reach negative values: ( ) R t = max Rt TR, 1

Macroprudential Policy A macroprudential rule for the LTV: k t = k SS ( bt b extended to include an output term. ) φb ( ) φy Yt, Y

Calibration Parameter Values β s 0.99/0.995 Discount Factor for Savers β b 0.98/0.985 Discount Factor for Borrowers j 0.1 Weight of Housing in Utility Function η 2 Parameter associated with labor elasticity k SS 0.9 Loan-to-value ratio α 0.64 Labor share for Savers X 1.2 Steady-state markup θ 0.75 Probability of not changing prices ρ 0 Smoothing parameter in Taylor rule φ R π 0.5 Inflation parameter in Taylor rule φ R y 0.5 Output parameter in Taylor rule

The occasionally binding ZLB Standard solution methods for DSGE models did not take into account the possibility of having the interest rate constrained at the ZLB Even absent of large shocks, we have seen, in many economies across the world, interest rates hitting their lower bounds We consider an occasionally binding ZLB and use the solution method proposed by Guerrieri and Iacoviello (2015): "occbin"

A nnualized Level, PPt % from S.S. % from S.S. % from S.S. % from S.S. % from S.S. Model dynamics with occbin (1) 10 Policy rate 0 Output 0 10 10 20 20 5 10 15 20 30 5 10 15 20 1 Inflation 2 Real interest r ate 0 0 2 1 4 2 5 10 15 20 6 5 10 15 20 0 House Pr ice 50 Debt 5 0 10 50 15 5 10 15 20 100 5 10 15 20 ZLB (occbin) No ZLB Figure: Impulse responses to a negative productivity shock

Model dynamics with occbin (2) With occasionally binding constraints for the interest rate, the policy rate reaches the zero lower bound and stays there for a couple of periods before converging to the Taylor rule interest rate The non-constrained interest rate, however, becomes negative. Both output and inflation respond in a much stronger manner in the world in which the interest rate is constrained. The negative impact of the productivity shock is amplified by the collateral channel of borrowers, even without a ZLB. When the interest rate is restricted by the ZLB, the latter provides an additional amplification of the shock: The combination of deflation and the binding ZLB of the nominal interest rate pushes up the real cost of borrowing, which further depresses house prices and credit, triggering the collateral effect on the real economy.

A low interest-rate environment The decline in the long-term interest rate, especially in the post-crisis period, may have implications both for financial stability and the implementation of monetary policy. We explore the consequences of a low steady-state interest rate, when an occasionally binding ZLB is explicitly considered We simulate our model with the same productivity shock process under two levels of steady-state interest rates (4% and 2%) Given the same size of shocks, we show that, in a low interest-rate environment, the interest rate is more likely to hit the ZLB and the economy is more volatile than the economy with a high interest rate.

% from S.S. Annualized Level, PPt % from S.S. % from S.S. Simulations 15 Policy rate 200 Output 10 100 5 0 0 100 5 0 100 200 300 400 House Price 100 200 1500 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 Debt 50 0 50 1000 500 0 500 100 0 100 200 300 400 Low interest rate 1000 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 normal time Figure: Simulated economy for productivity shocks. "Normal times" (4% SS interest rate) vs. "Low interest rate" (2% SS interest rate).

Simulations (2) In "normal times" the economy never hits the ZLB, while in the "low interest-rate" setting, the constraint binds several times and for extensive periods. Monetary policy becomes less effective, because it loses its ability to further stimulate the economy. In "normal times" the economy is less volatile than in a "low interest-rate" environment. Amplified financial cycles More volatile macroeconomy. Economies with financial frictions and low interest rates are particularly vulnerable when the conventional monetary policy is subject to the ZLB constraint This circumstance calls for the need of other policies to stabilize the economy.

How can macroprudential policy help? A natural candidate that could help monetary policy in this situation is macroprudential policy. In a low interest-rate world, the case for using macroprudential policies is even stronger: It can be used to deal with financial instability, which is an important problem in this case It can act as a complement to monetary policy when it hits the ZLB to stabilize the real economy

Simulations (1) We first compare the impulse responses of the model with and without an active LTV rule, taking the monetary policy rule as given As a starting point, we study a simple LTV rule that responds only to credit: ( ) φb bt k t = k SS, b where we tentatively set the reaction parameter φ b to 0.2.

% from S.S. % from S.S. Annualized Level, PPt % from S.S. Level in PPt % from S.S. Simulations (2) 6 Policy rate 100 LTV Ratio 4 95 2 90 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 85 5 10 15 20 25 30 0 Output 2 Inflation 5 10 15 1 0 20 5 10 15 20 25 30 1 5 10 15 20 25 30 1 Real interest rate 50 Debt 0.5 0 0.5 0 50 1 5 10 15 20 25 30 100 5 10 15 20 25 30 N o LTV LTV Rule

Simulations (3) Without an active LTV policy, the interest rate immediately drops to the ZLB and stays there for a few periods The economy suffers a deep recession, where both output and inflation fall The effect of a negative productivity shock is amplified by the collateral channel and the rising real interest rate due to the binding ZLB When a countercyclical LTV rule can be used to help the economy, it relaxes the LTV by about 10 percentage points. The provision of credit is supported by the LTV loosening Inflation increases instead of falling, which lifts the interest rate out of the ZLB more quickly The real interest rate falls, providing the real economy with the kind of support that would have been achieved by monetary policy

Optimal simple rules for the LTV We assess the optimal combination of parameters in the LTV rule, which minimizes a loss function of the macroprudential authority, taking monetary policy as given We assume that the macroprudential authority cares about the variability of credit, as a proxy for financial stability, and the variability of the instrument: L = σ 2 b + Λσ2 LTV Searching over a grid of parameters, the solution of this problem is represented by the following expression: ( φ b, φ ) y = arg min L (φb, φ y )

The rule as a complement for monetary policy As a first approach, we consider a rule in which the macroprudential regulator only responds to credit deviations from the steady state, that is, we impose φ y = 0 Then, we extend the rule to allow the macroprudential instrument to also respond to output. When the economy reaches the ZLB, monetary policy loses its effectiveness to stabilize the economy Thus, we study whether macroprudential policies could be used as a complement to monetary policy for macroeconomic stabilization.

Results Optimized Parameters φ b φ y σb 2 σy 2 Loss Benchmark (No LTV) Normal times - - 31.16 2.4 1.2899 Low interest rate - - 85.46 8.11 4.3749 LTV Rule with Credit Normal times 0.55-3.85 1.93 0.1699 Low interest rate 0.69-11.51 6.76 0.8347 Extended LTV Rule Normal times 0.55 0 3.85 1.93 0.1699 Low interest rate 0.11 0.8 9.46 5.13 0.5905

LTV rule with credit When we introduce an active LTV rule responding to credit only, financial stability is improved dramatically without compromising macroeconomic stability In normal times, the macroprudential policy delivers a much lower variability of credit and it also helps with macroeconomic stability In the 2% interest-rate world, however, the optimized LTV rule has to respond to credit more aggressively, and it dampens mostly the volatility of credit, When monetary policy is restricted by the occasionally binding ZLB, purely credit-focused macroprudential policy might be less helpful for the real economy This finding points to a more active role for macroprudential policy in stabilizing the real economy.

Extended LTV rule In normal times, since monetary policy already does its job properly, there is no need for the LTV rule to respond to output directly The so-called "Tinbergen principle" applies When the economy is closer to the ZLB, however, the optimized rule responds more strongly to output than to credit Monetary policy is often constrained by the binding ZLB In this case, macroprudential policy has to lend a helping hand to monetary policy, to assist macroeconomic stabilization As a result, the whole economy improves in terms of the volatilities in both the macroeconomic and the financial sector

Conclusion (1) We build a DSGE model in which interest rates are permanently low and monetary policy is constrained by the ZLB We study the implementation of macroprudential policies, represented by an LTV rule In particular we answer the following research questions: Are macroprudential policies more relevant in a low interest-rate environment? Can macroprudential policies complement monetary policy when the latter binds at the ZLB occasionally?

Conclusion (2) We find that when interest rates are persistently low, the ZLB occurs frequently, leading to greater macroeconomic volatility and financial instability In this context, the economy calls for the use of active macroprudential policies to promote financial stability and to act as a complement to the less effective monetary policy. We find that in a low interest-rate environment, macroprudential policies need to be more aggressive in responding to credit. Furthermore, when the LTV is allowed to respond to output, it will respond to output more strongly than to credit Macroprudential policies can act as a complement to monetary policy.