PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

Similar documents
PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

Housing Subsidies and Homeowners: What Role for Government-Sponsored Enterprises?

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

May 17, Housing Sector Overview

Implementing Small Area Fair Market Rents (SAFMRs) Implementation Guidebook

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

November 5, Dear Sir or Madam:

HUD Seeks Significant Improvements to Moving to Work Demonstration, But Additional Changes Needed

Comment to the President s Advisory Panel on Tax Reform Submitted by The Enterprise Foundation/Enterprise Social Investment Corporation June 10, 2005

Rural Development. Connecting the Dots to Homeownership on Indian Reservations

Saving, wealth and consumption

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are tax expenditures and how are they structured?

The study expands and delves deeper into an earlier presentation in Ekonomisk Debatt 2015, nos. 7 and 8. 7

Ric Battellino: Housing affordability in Australia

AUGUST THE DUNNING REPORT: DIMENSIONS OF CORE HOUSING NEED IN CANADA Second Edition

Household Debt and Defaults from 2000 to 2010: The Credit Supply View Online Appendix

MISSISSIPPI REGIONAL HOUSING AUTHORITY IV ANNUAL REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS

WORLD BANK STANDARDIZED DATABASE FOR EASTERN EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA ECAPOV DATABASE

CHAPTER 2: GENERAL PROGRAM RULES

Distribution of Federal Housing Benefits: Rebalancing the Federal Role in Housing Finance

Demographics. Housing Security in the Washington Region. Fairfax County, Fairfax City and Falls Church Cities

Demographics. Housing Security in the Washington Region. District of Columbia

Demographics. Housing Security in the Washington Region. Arlington County

An Analysis of Potential Tax Incentives to Increase Charitable Giving in Puerto Rico

Housing and Neoliberalism: Growing inequality in Australia

A Targeted Property Tax Relief Program for Georgia Acknowledgments

Testimony of Dean Baker. Before the Subcommittee on Housing and Community Opportunity of the House Financial Services Committee

Funding Bill and Carryover Funding Should Enable Agencies to Issue More Housing Vouchers in 2019

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

BOCA RATON HOUSING AUTHORITY

Texas Housing on Bumpy Road After Stimulus Effects Fade By D Ann Petersen and Adam Swadley

TAX-PREFERRED ASSETS AND DEBT, AND THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 1986: SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM ERIC M. ENGEN * & WILLIAM G.

Ensuring NAHMA Members Receive the Latest News and Analysis of Breaking Issues in Affordable Housing

ADMINISTRATIVE PLAN FOR THE HOMEOWNERSHIP PROGRAM. Housing Authority of the County of Riverside

The Section 8 Homeownership Program. Section 8 Families: Are You Ready for Homeownership? Introducing the Section 8 Homeownership Program

FIGURE 8: $1.8 Billion Was Cut from HUD Programs, 2004 to 2008

THE COSTS AND BENEFITS OF GROWTH: LAWRENCE, KS,

Prepared for: Pennsylvania Utility Law Project (PULP) Harry Geller, Executive Director

OPTION: Add a Property Tax Surcharge on Vacant Residential Property

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

Houston Housing Authority HOMEOWNERSHIP PROGRAM PLAN

SOURCES AND METHODS USED TO ESTIMATE COMPONENTS OF CHANGES IN SECTION 8 EXPENDITURES FROM 1996 TO 2003 by Will Fischer and Barbara Sard

Reforming and Rationalizing Tax Expenditures: Developing and Testing a Framework

HISTORY CONT. HISTORY HOW IT WORKS CONT. HOW IT WORKS HOW IT WORKS CONT. HOW IT WORK CONT. How To Report See Handout

Housing Markets and Structural Policies in OECD Countries

Could a housing benefit help tackle our affordable housing challenge?

INCREASING INVESTMENT IN SOCIAL HOUSING Analysis of public sector expenditure on housing in England and social housebuilding scenarios

Determinants of Federal and State Community Development Spending:

SECTION 8 ADMINISTRATIVE PLAN APPENDIX E VOUCHER HOMEOWNERSHIP OPTION

Florida s Assisted Housing Tenants:

U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development Community Planning and Development IX. FIELD OFFICE REVIEW OF RESALE/RECAPTURE PROVISIONS...

National Housing Trust Fund Allocation Plan

Allegheny County Housing Authority

Economic Implications Cont

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Wisconsin Tax Incidence Study: An Overview of Methodology

Analysis of Affordability of Cost Recovery: Communal and Network Energy Services. September 30, By Clare T. Romanik The Urban Institute

Exhibit A DRAFT Measure A1 Implementation Policies Rental Housing Development Fund & Innovation and Opportunity Fund

Country note: housing finance in Switzerland

Statement by. David M. Lilly Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Before the

Detailed Description of Reconciling NIPA Aggregate Household Sector Data to Micro Concepts

PLEASANTVILLE HOUSING AUTHORITY FINANCIAL STATEMENTS AND SUPPLEMENTAL INFORMATION YEAR ENDED MARCH 31, 2016

WikiLeaks Document Release

HOUSING AUTHORITY OF THE CITY AND COUNTY OF SAN FRANCISCO, CALIFORNIA. Annual Financial and Compliance Report. For the Year Ended September 30, 2016

Sec. 42. Low-income housing credit

1102 Longworth House Office Building 1102 Longworth House Office Building Washington, DC Washington, DC April 4, 2013

La Follette School of Public Affairs at the University of Wisconsin-Madison

Chapter 14 FEDERAL HOUSING SUBSIDIES

OPTION: Add a Property Tax Surcharge on Vacant Residential Property

Incidence of Taxation

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries:

Milestones Program Stabilize housing, through a monthly rental subsidy, of chronically homeless individuals with serious mental illness.

Quincy Housing Authority Section 8 Housing Choice Voucher Homeownership Program Administrative Plan Amendment June 2006

Public Housing: Fact Sheet on the New Operating Fund Formula

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada:

Lars Nyberg: Developments in the property market

A CASE FOR HOMEOWNERSHip: Why california REALTORS OPPOSE CONGRESSIONAL TAX REFORM PROPOSAL

Costs and Benefits of Housing Tax Subsidies

THE HOUSING AUTHORITY OF THE CITY OF GARY, INDIANA INDEPENDENT AUDITORS REPORT, BASIC FINANCIAL STATEMENTS AND SUPPLEMENTAL INFORMATION, INCLUDING

Update on Homeownership Wealth Trajectories Through the Housing Boom and Bust

CHAPTER 11 (CORRECTED COPY 2)

City of Clarksville FIRST-TIME HOMEBUYER PROGRAM

CRS Report for Congress

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE CBO MARCH 2011 Shutterstock, LLC Reducing the Deficit: Spending and Revenue Options

by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson

The Coalition s Record on Housing: Policy, Spending and Outcomes

HOUSING AUTHORITY OF THE CITY OF DANBURY FINANCIAL STATEMENTS AND SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION FOR THE YEAR ENDED DECEMBER 31, 2016

Replacing references to Chapter 201G, Hawaii Revised Statutes with Chapter 356D, Hawaii Revised Statutes;

DEPARTMENT OF HOUSING AND URBAN DEVELOPMENT

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

2015/ /2017 AND 2017/2018

COMMUNITY LINK, PROGRAMS OF TRAVELERS AID SOCIETY OF CENTRAL CAROLINAS, INC. AND SUBSIDIARY

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

THE NSP SUBSTANTIAL AMENDMENT

DETROIT HOUSING COMMISSION Basic Financial Statements and Supplemental Information. Year ended June 30, 2008

Internal Revenue Code 42 Low-income housing credit.

Development from Inside Out The Making of National Housing. Finance Policy

Transcription:

Institute of Business and Economic Research Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY WORKING PAPER SERIES WORKING PAPER NO. W06-001B HOUSING POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES (REVIEW ESSAY FOR THE NEW PALGRAVE) By John M. Quigley May 2008 These papers are preliminary in nature: their purpose is to stimulate discussion and comment. Therefore, they are not to be cited or quoted in any publication without the express permission of the author. UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY

The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online housing policy in the United States John M. Quigley From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, 2008 Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume Abstract The most significant and most expensive housing policy in the United States is the treatment of owner-occupied housing for tax purposes. This treatment of housing under the tax code is analogous to that in many other countries (for example, Sweden), but certainly not in all developed countries (for example, Canada). Federal subsidies to US renter households are much smaller. Policy has evolved from programmes in which the government built, owned, and managed dwellings to programmes emphasizing housing demand through vouchers and rent certificates awarded to eligible households. Keywords Great Depression; homeownership; housing; housing costs; housing expenditures; housing externalities; housing finance; housing policy in the United States; housing subsidies; housing tax credit; income tax; inflation; interest rates; Internal Revenue Service (IRS); land-use regulation; rent control; social capital; tax expenditures; taxation of capital income Article Public concern over housing arises from three sources. First, housing is the single largest expenditure item in the budgets of families and individuals in most modern economies. The average household in western Europe and the United States devotes more than one quarter of its income to housing expenditures. Thus, increased efficiency in the provision of housing services or reduced occupancy costs can have a large impact on non-housing consumption and household well-being. Second, consumers housing and location choices condition many other aspects of the quality of urban life. For example, the transport, schooling, and neighbourhood opportunities of urban households are themselves greatly affected by the housing opportunities available to them. Third, it is widely presumed that there are significant externalities in housing consumption. These external effects range all the way from the consequences of the social and physical isolation of those living in low-income residential neighbourhoods to the presumed benefits of the social capital and the increased political participation of households who own their homes. In the United States, important policies providing subsidies to housing consumers are made by the central ( federal ) government. Other policies governing housing the regulation of house-building, service provision, and occupancy are determined by local governments. At the national level, subsidies provided to selected housing consumers and producers are implemented by two government agencies: the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) and the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). The policies administered by the IRS are clearly more important quantitatively, and they have large welfare effects. The federal tax code The IRS administers two housing subsidy programmes: the tax expenditures to owner-occupants for housing consumption specified in the personal income tax code, and the tax expenditures for builders of rental housing under the Low Income Housing Tax Credit programme specified in the Tax Reform Act of 1986. This latter programme is small, having originated in the Tax Reform Act of 1986. The former programme is large, and has existed in its current form since the personal income tax was established in 1915. Indeed, the benefits to homeowners under these tax policies are among the most generous in the developed world. (But the form of these subsidies is certainly not unique to the United States. See Englund, 2003, for a comparative discussion.) Consider an individual who chooses between an investment in owner-occupied housing and an equivalent investment in some other asset common stocks, say. The investment in owner-occupied housing offers three distinct tax advantages. First, under the US Internal Revenue Code, the returns on the investment in owner-occupied housing are untaxed (these returns are in the form of the housing services consumed in any year). In contrast, the dividends yielded by common stock are reported as income and are taxed in the year accrued. Second, capital gains arising from the housing investment can be deferred indefinitely. Moreover, a large capital gains exclusion is available to those over the age of 55. In contrast, capital gains in the stock market are taxed in the year they are realized. Third, some of the expenses associated with homeownership, notably property taxes and mortgage interest payments, can be itemized as deductions in computing federal tax liability under the personal income tax. No other interest payments are deductible as personal expenses under the Internal Revenue Code. This favourable treatment also extends to personal income taxation under the

laws of all of the 50 states. The net effect of these provisions of the US tax law is to reduce the price of homeownership, relative to renting, by a sizeable amount. Moreover, as a result of these policies, the relative price of homeownership varies by income level and the level of inflation. It is useful to think of the price of homeownership as the cost of using the stock of residential capital. The rent R for using a unit of capital V is merely R! iv" (1) where i is the real interest rate. i is simply the price of using a unit of capital V for a year. Housing is subject to local property tax at effective rate t. Annual expenditures of 100d per cent are required to maintain the property and to offset depreciation. The owner can expect real capital gains at a rate g. Let! be the rate of inflation. For housing, the user cost relationship is thus R #! $%i & '( ) t ) d ) %g & '(* V" (2) where the term in square brackets is the user cost of residential capital. Note that, in the absence of tax considerations, the user cost is insensitive to the level of inflation!. Now suppose nominal capital gains are untaxed and that mortgage interest payments and property taxes are deductible from gross income. Suppose net income is taxed at the rate of T per cent. Under these circumstances the user cost relationship is R +! %$i & '*$I ) T* & t $I ) T* & d ) $g & '*(V" (3) or (4) R +! R # ) T %i & ' & t( V, The system of taxes leads to a reduction in the net price of housing capital by the amount of the second term. Note that the after-tax cost of homeownership declines with the value of the house, the real interest rate, the property tax rate, and the marginal income tax rate. If federal tax rates increase with income or if higher-income households live in jurisdictions with higher property tax rates, the cost of homeownership declines with income. More important, as long as housing is a normal good with a positive income elasticity, the net cost of homeownership declines with income. Furthermore, a given level of inflation in the economy reduces the user cost more for higher-income than for lower-income homeowners. More generally, the analysis shows that the costs of homeownership are sensitive to macroeconomic stabilization policies and to the structure of income tax rates. The marginal tax rates of the highest-income US households fell from 70 per cent to 30 per cent and then rose to 40 per cent during the 1980s and 1990s, before falling again in 2001. At the same time, the inflation rate plummeted from 15 per cent to less than three per cent. These changes have meant that the implicit policy toward housing and homeownership varied substantially. For example, at reasonable values of the variables in eq. 4 (say, i! g! -., t! d! +., T! -/.), then as inflation declines from six per cent to 1 per cent, the after-tax user cost of residential capital roughly doubles. Similarly, at reasonable values of the variables (for example, '! -. and, as before, i! g! -., t! d! +. ), then, as income tax rates decrease from 40 per cent to 20 per cent, the after-tax cost of owner occupancy increases by more than one-third. These are substantial price changes induced entirely by taxation and macroeconomic considerations which may be completely unrelated to any objective of housing policy. These reductions in the user cost of housing capital may be expected to increase housing consumption; reductions in the price of owning relative to renting may be expected to increase homeownership. But econometric research suggests that the demand for housing is moderately price-inelastic. It also appears, at least for the United States, that the elasticity of homeownership with respect of the relative price of homeownership is quite small. Thus, the effects of these large subsidies on housing outcomes are quite small. In contrast, the magnitude of the implicit subsidy arising from the personal income tax code is large and extremely regressive. The subsidy is available only to owners, who are typically more affluent than renters, and only to those who find it advantageous to itemize their deductions in computing their tax liabilities. (Under US tax law, households may claim a standard deduction for expenses or they may list deductions separately. The propensity to itemize deductions separately increases with income.) Finally, as noted above, for those owners who do itemize deductions, the magnitude of the subsidy increases with income. The second programme administered by the IRS, the low-income housing tax credit, was established in 1986 and expanded in 2001. Under this programme, tax credits are remitted to each state in proportion to population. These credits are awarded by states to developers who propose new construction of housing reserved for low-income tenants who pay 30 per cent of their incomes in rent. The credits, in turn, are sold to firms and high-income individuals, and the proceeds are invested in the designated projects. The IRS monitors the compliance of these projects with the tax law requiring occupancy by low-income tenants for a 15-year period after construction. The revenues forgone by the federal treasury as a result of these programmes are routinely estimated by the Joint Committee on Taxation of the Congress. The revenue costs of these subsidies are large. In 2005, for example, it is estimated that tax expenditures for owner-occupied housing totalled about $147 billion $69 billion for the mortgage interest deduction, $33 billion for the capital

gains exclusion on home sales, $28.6 billion for the exclusion of imputed rent, and $16.6 billion for the property tax deduction. It is estimated that more than half of the benefits of the tax expenditures for homeowners accrue to the top 15 per cent of the income distribution. In contrast, in 2005 the tax expenditures arising from the low-income housing tax credit were about $4.8 billion (in present value terms). Presumably much of this benefit accrues to low-income renters. A more relevant benchmark for the costs of these tax expenditures may be a comparison with the housing programmes managed by HUD, whose principal beneficiaries are low-income households. Direct expenditures under these programmes are currently $41 billion, or about 28 per cent of the tax expenditures on behalf of owner occupants. Subsidies for renters Federal housing policies for renters administered by HUD provide subsidies to about a third of low-income households. These programmes have evolved from those providing housing owned and managed by government to those providing direct cash assistance for deserving renters. The Public Housing Program was established in 1937 to subsidize local governments in building housing for those temporarily unemployed and also in providing construction jobs for unemployed urban labour during the Great Depression. Until the end of the 1970s, the programme subsidized virtually all of the capital costs of designated public housing dwellings and none of the operating costs. Since rent rolls were fixed at 25 30 per cent of tenant income, project managers who chose to serve households with the lowest incomes faced severe budgetary problems. Changes in the subsidy formulas helped local managers avoid this Hobson's choice, but the legacy of the original subsidy formula, the overcapitalization of projects to economize on maintenance expenses, is still manifest in the long-lived capital produced by the Public Housing Program. The private sector was first induced to build, manage and provide rental dwellings for low-income tenants in the 1960s, through generous depreciation allowances provided to limited dividend corporations (under programmes such as Section 235 of the Housing Act of 1968). But it was not until 1974 that the subsidy provided to deserving tenants was divorced from the cost of supplying newly constructed housing. The innovation in Section 8 of the Housing Act of 1974 was a programme of project-based housing assistance based upon long-term contracts in which the federal government guaranteed that participating landlords would receive the average rent in the local housing market (rather than the cost of building new housing). Low-income households pay 30 per cent of their incomes to a participating landlord and the difference, up to the fair market rent in the housing market, is supplied under federal contract. The radical departure to subsidize directly the demanders of low-income housing rather than the builders and suppliers of that housing was thoroughly tested by the Housing Allowance Experiments of the 1970s and 1980s, the most expensive social experiment in history, and the results were incorporated over time into the current Housing Choice Voucher Program which allocates vouchers or certificates to local authorities for distribution to low-income households. Under this programme, a qualifying household receives a voucher which pays the difference between 30 per cent of tenant income and the fair market rent. This programme is administered by Local Housing Authorities, who screen applicants and certify eligibility. Under current practice, households with incomes below 80 per cent of the area median income are eligible for vouchers, but three-quarters of the vouchers are reserved for very low-income households, those whose incomes are below 30 per cent of the area median income. In principle, the voucher is completely portable. It can be used anywhere by a recipient to enter into a rental contract within 90 days of issue. Vouchers offer several clear advantages over the alternative supply oriented housing subsidy programmes. First, they are considerably cheaper per household served than programmes linking subsidies to construction costs, including the Public Housing Program, but also the Low Income Housing Tax Credit Program. Second, they remove questions about the location of dwellings occupied by low-income subsidized households from the local political process. Third, they preserve the anonymity of the low-income recipients of these subsidies. Fourth, they foster the spatial decentralization of the low-income population, reducing the concentration of disadvantaged households in particular neighbourhoods. Fifth, they better facilitate the operation of the labour market by encouraging recipients to live closer to actual or potential worksites. Although new commitments by HUD for subsidies to low-income renters are concentrated in the voucher programme, the legacy of past programmes will remain for a considerable period. For example, in the last year for which complete data are available (1998), 1.3 million units of government-owned public housing were used to provide housing subsidies, as were 1.0 million units of Section 8 project-based housing and 750,000 units of housing produced by other supply-oriented programmes. In contrast, 1.4 million households were subsidized by tenant-based voucher programmes. Local housing regulations impose a potentially serious impediment to the efficiency of vouchers as a vehicle for housing subsidies. With local property taxes as the basis for local service provision, it is often in the fiscal interests of individual governments to limit the construction of new housing and to restrict the construction of high-density housing. The land-use regulations of individual jurisdictions are not well coordinated regionally in the United States, and the resulting regulatory pattern may make the housing supply relatively inelastic. This may lead to higher housing prices in response to increases in demand throughout the market, and it may mean that housing may be less available to voucher recipients in some metropolitan areas. Despite these real concerns, the most important factor keeping the rent-to-income ratio of the poor high is the limited availability of housing subsidies. In 2001, it was estimated that almost 14.5 million renter households paid more than 30 per cent of their incomes on rent, and more than 7 million paid more than half of their incomes on rent. In contrast, only about 5 million renter households received subsidies from all federal government housing programmes. See Also

housing supply local public finance markets urban economics urban housing demand rent control residential real estate and finance Bibliography Englund, P. 2003. Taxing residential housing capital. Urban Studies 40, 937 52. Gabriel, S. 1996. Urban housing policy in the 1990s. Housing Policy Debate 7, 673 93. Quigley, J. 2000. A decent home: housing policy in perspective. Brookings Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs 1(1), 53 100. Quigley, J. and Raphael, S. 2004. Is housing unaffordable? Why isn't it more affordable? Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(1), 191 214. How to cite this article Quigley, John M. "housing policy in the United States." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Second Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, 2008. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. 30 May 2008 <http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_h000098> doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0752(available via http://dx.doi.org/)